Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve
-
0:00 - 0:03♪ [music] ♪
-
0:09 - 0:11- [Alex] Now that we know
how to find the profit -
0:11 - 0:14maximization point,
we're going to show -
0:14 - 0:19the amount of profit on the diagram
using the average cost curve. -
0:24 - 0:26So as I said in the last lecture,
-
0:26 - 0:28average cost is the cost
per unit of output. -
0:28 - 0:33That is, average cost is
total cost divided by Q. -
0:33 - 0:36Now remember also
that total cost can be broken down -
0:36 - 0:39into fixed costs plus
variable costs. -
0:39 - 0:43So we can also write average cost
in a slightly longer format. -
0:43 - 0:46Average cost is equal
to fixed cost divided by Q -
0:46 - 0:50plus the variable cost divided
by Q, the units of output. -
0:50 - 0:54That's a little bit useful
because we're able to see, -
0:54 - 0:58get some intuition, for the shape
of a typical average cost curve. -
0:58 - 1:02Notice that the fixed costs
don't change with Q. -
1:02 - 1:04That's why they're fixed.
-
1:04 - 1:07So when Q is small -- this number,
-
1:07 - 1:09suppose fixed cost is 100,
-
1:09 - 1:12and Q is small -- then this number
is going to be big -
1:12 - 1:15like 100 divided by 1.
-
1:15 - 1:18As Q gets larger, however,
this number -- -
1:18 - 1:21fixed cost divided by Q --
is going to get smaller, -
1:21 - 1:26So when Q is 10, this number
100 divided by 10 becomes 10. -
1:26 - 1:29So it goes from 100,
and it goes down, down, down, down, -
1:29 - 1:32get's lower and lower and lower
all the time as you divide -
1:32 - 1:33by a bigger quantity.
-
1:33 - 1:38On the other hand, the variable
costs increase with quantity. -
1:38 - 1:42Moreover, what we saw
with the marginal cost curve -
1:42 - 1:45is that at some point,
your variable costs are going -
1:45 - 1:47to increase faster than quantity.
-
1:47 - 1:50So what's going to happen is
that this number at some point -- -
1:50 - 1:53variable cost divided by quantity --
is going to get bigger -
1:53 - 1:54and bigger and bigger.
-
1:54 - 2:00So you have two things, one force
is driving average cost down. -
2:00 - 2:03That's going to be particularly
strong at the beginning. -
2:03 - 2:07Eventually, however,
the second force here is going -
2:07 - 2:09to drive average cost up.
-
2:09 - 2:12So that's going to be our typical
shape of an average cost curve -- -
2:12 - 2:15falling, reaches a minimum,
and then rising. -
2:15 - 2:17So let's draw it like that.
-
2:17 - 2:19Okay, here's our typical
marginal cost curve, -
2:19 - 2:23and here is our marginal
revenue curve, equal to price. -
2:23 - 2:26We know that the profit maximizing
point is where marginal revenue -
2:26 - 2:28is equal to marginal cost.
-
2:28 - 2:32Here is our average cost curve
and notice it has the shape -
2:32 - 2:35which I described --
it starts off high, it falls, -
2:35 - 2:38reaches a minimum,
and then goes right back up again. -
2:38 - 2:44Couple of other points to notice
is that the minimum point, -
2:44 - 2:46the marginal cost curve goes
through the minimum point -
2:46 - 2:49of the average cost curve.
-
2:49 - 2:54Now that's just a mathematical fact,
but let me give you some intuition. -
2:54 - 3:00Instead of cost I want to talk
about average grade and marginal
grade. So suppose that your average grade -
3:00 - 3:06is 80%. You're doing really pretty good.
But then on your next test you only get -
3:06 - 3:1260% - lower. What is that going to do to
your average? Well, it's going to drive -
3:12 - 3:19your average down. Indeed whenever your
marginal is below your average, the average -
3:19 - 3:25must be falling. On the other hand,
suppose that you're getting, uh, 80% and on -
3:25 - 3:31your next test you get 90%. Great, but what
does that do to your average? It drives your -
3:31 - 3:37average up. Indeed whenever your marginal
is above the average, the average must be -
3:37 - 3:42rising. Now suppose what happens when
you're getting let's say 80%, and on your -
3:43 - 3:50next test you also get 80%. Well then your
marginal is equal to your average grade -
3:50 - 3:56and your average grade is flat - it doesn't
change, it's flat. But what is true for -
3:56 - 4:01average and marginal grades is also true
for average cost and marginal cost. -
4:01 - 4:09Whenever the marginal cost is below the
average, the average is falling. Whenever -
4:09 - 4:15the marginal cost is above the average, the
average is rising. And where marginal is -
4:15 - 4:21just equal to average, the average is flat.
In other words we are at the minimum point -
4:21 - 4:27of the average cost curve. Okay, now I
said we could use the average cost curve -
4:27 - 4:31to figure out profit - show profit on the
diagram. We can do that with just a little -
4:31 - 4:36bit of rearranging. Remember that profit
is equal to total revenue minus total cost -
4:37 - 4:42and total revenue is price times quantity -
P times Q. We also know that average cost -
4:42 - 4:47is equal to total cost divided by
quantity. Let's just rearrange that to -
4:47 - 4:52tell us that total cost is equal to
average cost times quantity. So just take -
4:52 - 4:58this one and multiply both sides by Q.
So, let's now make these substitutions into -
4:59 - 5:04our profit equation. If we do that, then
profit is equal to total revenue - price -
5:04 - 5:11times quantity - minus total cost - average
cost times quantity. Now let's take Q out -
5:11 - 5:17of both parts of this equation and we find
that profit can also be written as price -
5:17 - 5:23minus average cost, all of that times
quantity. That's nice because we can find -
5:23 - 5:31all of these elements on our diagram.
Here's the price. Here's the average cost -
5:31 - 5:36at the profit maximizing quantity. Let's
just show that. There's the price. There's -
5:37 - 5:42the average cost at the profit maximizing
quantity. So profit at the profit -
5:42 - 5:51maximizing quantity is this green area
right here. Price minus average cost times -
5:51 - 5:56quantity. So now we have a nice way of
showing in a diagram exactly how much -
5:56 - 6:02profit is. Let's use this tool some more.
Here's another example of the average cost -
6:02 - 6:07curve in action. Remember I said that
profit maximization doesn't necessarily -
6:07 - 6:11mean the firm is making a positive profit.
Sometimes the best you can do is to -
6:12 - 6:17minimize your losses. You may have to take
a loss. For example, suppose that the -
6:17 - 6:23price is below $17. That is, here's the market
price, which is equal to the firm's marginal -
6:23 - 6:28revenue curve. How does the firm profit
maximize? It chooses the quantity where -
6:28 - 6:33marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost.
In that case, this quantity is one. Now -
6:34 - 6:40what's the profit for the firm? Well, as
usual we measure profit as price minus -
6:40 - 6:48average cost times quantity. But notice
that price is below the average cost at -
6:48 - 6:55the profit maximizing quantity of one.
Since price is below average cost, this is -
6:55 - 7:04a loss. It's a negative quantity. It is a
loss. In fact, notice that the breakeven -
7:04 - 7:11price is $17, which is the minimum of the
average cost curve. In order to make a -
7:11 - 7:18profit, the firm at least has to meet the
minimum of it's average cost curve. So at -
7:18 - 7:23any price below $17 we'll be profit
maximizing at a point where price is equal -
7:23 - 7:29to marginal cost, and notice that all of
these prices are below average cost. So -
7:29 - 7:35all of this area down here, even the
profit maximizing quantity, will mean a -
7:36 - 7:42loss. On the other hand, once we get above
$17, above the minimum of the average cost -
7:42 - 7:48curve, then we can price equal to marginal
cost. We can chose the quantities such the -
7:48 - 7:53price is equal to marginal cost. That price
will be above average cost so we'll be -
7:53 - 8:00taking a profit. Therefore, $17, the minimum
of the average cost curve, is the -
8:01 - 8:04breakeven point.
If the price is less than the minimum of -
8:04 - 8:09the average cost curve, we're going to be
taking a loss. If the price is bigger than -
8:09 - 8:13the minimum of the average cost curve, then
we can make a profit. So when should a -
8:14 - 8:19firm enter or exit an industry? In the
long run, the firms will enter when price -
8:20 - 8:24is above average cost. If price is
somewhere above the average cost curve -
8:24 - 8:28then the firm can make a profit by
entering and that's what firms want to do. -
8:28 - 8:31They want to find profit, so they will
want to enter wherever a profit is -
8:32 - 8:37possible. Firms will exit the industry
when the price is below the average cost -
8:37 - 8:41curve. Then they're going to be taking a
loss and they're going to want to exit. So -
8:42 - 8:46finally, when the price is equal to the
minimum of the average cost - it's just -
8:46 - 8:51equal to the bottom of the average cost
curve, profits are zero and there's no -
8:51 - 8:56incentive to either exit or enter the
industry. Now you might ask, why would -
8:56 - 9:02firms remain in an industry if profits are
zero? Zero profits, this is just a matter -
9:03 - 9:07of terminology, means that at the market
price the firm is covering all of its -
9:08 - 9:13costs including enough to pay labor and
capital, their ordinary opportunity cost. -
9:14 - 9:18So zero profits means everyone
is being paid, enough to make -
9:18 - 9:25them satisfied. Zero profits, in other
words, is what normal people mean by normal -
9:25 - 9:30profits. So when an economist says zero
profits just substitute normal profits. -
9:31 - 9:35One more point about entry and exit. It
doesn't always make sense to exit an -
9:35 - 9:41industry immediately when price falls
below average cost. Or to enter immediately -
9:41 - 9:48when price is above average cost. Why not?
Well, there are also entry and exit costs. -
9:48 - 9:53For example, suppose that that the price
of oil is currently above the average cost -
9:54 - 9:59of pumping oil, if you've already got a
well. Should you enter the industry? Well, -
9:59 - 10:05maybe not necessarily. Because entry
requires you to drill an oil well, and -
10:05 - 10:09drilling an oil well is a sunk cost -
literally in this case. -
10:09 - 10:16A sunk cost is a cost that once incurred
can never be recovered. So if you enter -
10:16 - 10:21the industry and drill the oil well, you
don't get that money back when you later -
10:21 - 10:28exit the industry. What this means is you
don't want to enter unless you expect the -
10:28 - 10:36price of oil to stay above the minimum of
the average cost curve long enough so -
10:36 - 10:42that you can also recover your entry
costs. So just because the price goes -
10:42 - 10:46above the average cost a little bit, you
don't immediately want to jump into that -
10:46 - 10:52industry. You have to expect that that
price is going to stay above average cost -
10:52 - 10:59long enough for you to recover your entry
costs. For the same reasons, if there are -
10:59 - 11:03exit costs, for example, if you have to
shutter up the well or fill the well with -
11:04 - 11:08cement when you exit the industry as you
do in the United States, then when price -
11:08 - 11:13falls below average cost, it may be best to
weather the storm at least for sometime -
11:14 - 11:21before you exit. Only if you expect the
price of oil to stay below your minimum of -
11:21 - 11:27average cost for an extended period of
time will you want to exit the industry. -
11:27 - 11:32After all, if the price of oil falls below
the average cost just for a little bit, and -
11:32 - 11:37then it goes back up, the lifetime
profits can still be possible. So, entry -
11:38 - 11:41and exit could be quite complicated
because you've got to be thinking about -
11:41 - 11:47the lifetime profits, not just your
immediate profits. However, the bottom -
11:47 - 11:53line is pretty simple. Firms seek profits
and they want to avoid losses. As a -
11:53 - 11:58result, firms will enter industries when
the price is above the average cost and -
11:58 - 12:02they can make a profit, and they will exit
when the price is below the average cost. -
12:02 - 12:04Thanks.
-
12:04 - 12:09- [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,
click, "Practice Questions," or if you're -
12:10 - 12:12ready to move on,
just click, "Next Video." -
12:12 - 12:15♪ [music] ♪
- Title:
- Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve
- Description:
-
Being able to predict your company’s profit is a very useful tool. In this video, we introduce the third concept you need to maximize profit — average cost. When looked at in conjunction with the marginal revenue and marginal cost, the average cost curve will show you how to accurately predict how much profit you can make!
The usefulness of these tools does not stop there. Sometimes, you can’t make a profit. You’ll have to take a loss. These tools can also show you how to minimize losses, and make decisions on whether a company should enter or exit an industry.
We also define terms such as zero profits and sunk costs in this video.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomicsAsk a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/profit-maximization-average-cost#QandA
Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/supply-curve-increasing-cost-industry
- Video Language:
- English
- Team:
Marginal Revolution University
- Project:
- Micro
- Duration:
- 12:18
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve | |
![]() |
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve |