< Return to Video

Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:11
    - Now that we know
    how to find the profit
  • 0:11 - 0:14
    maximization point,
    we're going to show
  • 0:14 - 0:19
    the amount of profit on the diagram
    using the average cost curve.
  • 0:24 - 0:29
    - So as I said in the last lecture, average
    cost is the cost per unit of output. That
  • 0:29 - 0:35
    is, average cost is total cost divided by
    Q. Now remember also that total cost can
  • 0:35 - 0:40
    be broken down into fixed costs plus
    variable costs. So we can also write
  • 0:40 - 0:43
    average cost in a
    slightly longer format.
  • 0:43 - 0:46
    Average cost is equal to
    fixed cost divided by Q plus the
  • 0:46 - 0:53
    variable cost divided by Q - the units of
    output. That's a little bit useful because
  • 0:53 - 0:58
    we're able to see, get some intuition, for
    the shape of a typical average cost curve.
  • 0:58 - 1:05
    Notice that the fixed costs don't change
    with Q. That's why they're fixed. So when Q
  • 1:05 - 1:11
    is small, this number, suppose fixed cost
    is a hundred and Q is small, then this
  • 1:11 - 1:18
    number is going to be big like 100 divided
    by 1. As Q gets larger, however, this number -
  • 1:18 - 1:23
    fixed cost divided Q - is going to get
    smaller, so when Q is 10 this number 100
  • 1:23 - 1:29
    divided by 10 becomes 10. So it goes from
    100 and it goes down, down, down, down,
  • 1:29 - 1:32
    get's lower and lower and lower all the
    time as you divide by a bigger
  • 1:33 - 1:39
    quantity. On the other hand, the variable
    costs increase with quantity. Moreover,
  • 1:39 - 1:44
    what we saw with the marginal cost curve
    is that at some point your variable costs
  • 1:44 - 1:49
    are going to increase faster than
    quantity. So what's going to happen is
  • 1:49 - 1:53
    that this number at some point - variable
    cost divided by quantity - is going to get
  • 1:53 - 1:58
    bigger and bigger and bigger. So you have
    two things one force is driving average
  • 1:58 - 2:03
    cost down. That's going to be
    particularly strong at the beginning.
  • 2:03 - 2:10
    Eventually however, the second force here
    is going to drive average cost, uh, up. So
  • 2:10 - 2:13
    that's going to be our typical shape of an
    average cost curve - falling reaches a
  • 2:13 - 2:18
    minimum and then rising. So let's draw it
    like that. Okay here's our typical
  • 2:18 - 2:23
    marginal cost curve and here is our
    marginal revenue curve equal to price. We
  • 2:23 - 2:27
    know that the profit maximizing point is
    where marginal revenue is equal to
  • 2:27 - 2:32
    marginal cost. Here is our average cost
    curve and notice it has the shape, which I
  • 2:32 - 2:37
    described, it starts off high, it falls,
    reaches a minimum, and then goes right back
  • 2:37 - 2:44
    up again. Couple of other points to notice
    is that the minimum point, the marginal
  • 2:44 - 2:49
    cost curve goes through the minimum point
    of the average cost curve. Now that's just
  • 2:49 - 2:54
    a mathematical fact, but let me give you
    some intuition. Instead of cost I want to
  • 2:54 - 3:00
    talk about average grade and marginal
    grade. So suppose that your average grade
  • 3:00 - 3:06
    is 80%. You're doing really pretty good.
    But then on your next test you only get
  • 3:06 - 3:12
    60% - lower. What is that going to do to
    your average? Well, it's going to drive
  • 3:12 - 3:19
    your average down. Indeed whenever your
    marginal is below your average, the average
  • 3:19 - 3:25
    must be falling. On the other hand,
    suppose that you're getting, uh, 80% and on
  • 3:25 - 3:31
    your next test you get 90%. Great, but what
    does that do to your average? It drives your
  • 3:31 - 3:37
    average up. Indeed whenever your marginal
    is above the average, the average must be
  • 3:37 - 3:42
    rising. Now suppose what happens when
    you're getting let's say 80%, and on your
  • 3:43 - 3:50
    next test you also get 80%. Well then your
    marginal is equal to your average grade
  • 3:50 - 3:56
    and your average grade is flat - it doesn't
    change, it's flat. But what is true for
  • 3:56 - 4:01
    average and marginal grades is also true
    for average cost and marginal cost.
  • 4:01 - 4:09
    Whenever the marginal cost is below the
    average, the average is falling. Whenever
  • 4:09 - 4:15
    the marginal cost is above the average, the
    average is rising. And where marginal is
  • 4:15 - 4:21
    just equal to average, the average is flat.
    In other words we are at the minimum point
  • 4:21 - 4:27
    of the average cost curve. Okay, now I
    said we could use the average cost curve
  • 4:27 - 4:31
    to figure out profit - show profit on the
    diagram. We can do that with just a little
  • 4:31 - 4:36
    bit of rearranging. Remember that profit
    is equal to total revenue minus total cost
  • 4:37 - 4:42
    and total revenue is price times quantity -
    P times Q. We also know that average cost
  • 4:42 - 4:47
    is equal to total cost divided by
    quantity. Let's just rearrange that to
  • 4:47 - 4:52
    tell us that total cost is equal to
    average cost times quantity. So just take
  • 4:52 - 4:58
    this one and multiply both sides by Q.
    So, let's now make these substitutions into
  • 4:59 - 5:04
    our profit equation. If we do that, then
    profit is equal to total revenue - price
  • 5:04 - 5:11
    times quantity - minus total cost - average
    cost times quantity. Now let's take Q out
  • 5:11 - 5:17
    of both parts of this equation and we find
    that profit can also be written as price
  • 5:17 - 5:23
    minus average cost, all of that times
    quantity. That's nice because we can find
  • 5:23 - 5:31
    all of these elements on our diagram.
    Here's the price. Here's the average cost
  • 5:31 - 5:36
    at the profit maximizing quantity. Let's
    just show that. There's the price. There's
  • 5:37 - 5:42
    the average cost at the profit maximizing
    quantity. So profit at the profit
  • 5:42 - 5:51
    maximizing quantity is this green area
    right here. Price minus average cost times
  • 5:51 - 5:56
    quantity. So now we have a nice way of
    showing in a diagram exactly how much
  • 5:56 - 6:02
    profit is. Let's use this tool some more.
    Here's another example of the average cost
  • 6:02 - 6:07
    curve in action. Remember I said that
    profit maximization doesn't necessarily
  • 6:07 - 6:11
    mean the firm is making a positive profit.
    Sometimes the best you can do is to
  • 6:12 - 6:17
    minimize your losses. You may have to take
    a loss. For example, suppose that the
  • 6:17 - 6:23
    price is below $17. That is, here's the market
    price, which is equal to the firm's marginal
  • 6:23 - 6:28
    revenue curve. How does the firm profit
    maximize? It chooses the quantity where
  • 6:28 - 6:33
    marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost.
    In that case, this quantity is one. Now
  • 6:34 - 6:40
    what's the profit for the firm? Well, as
    usual we measure profit as price minus
  • 6:40 - 6:48
    average cost times quantity. But notice
    that price is below the average cost at
  • 6:48 - 6:55
    the profit maximizing quantity of one.
    Since price is below average cost, this is
  • 6:55 - 7:04
    a loss. It's a negative quantity. It is a
    loss. In fact, notice that the breakeven
  • 7:04 - 7:11
    price is $17, which is the minimum of the
    average cost curve. In order to make a
  • 7:11 - 7:18
    profit, the firm at least has to meet the
    minimum of it's average cost curve. So at
  • 7:18 - 7:23
    any price below $17 we'll be profit
    maximizing at a point where price is equal
  • 7:23 - 7:29
    to marginal cost, and notice that all of
    these prices are below average cost. So
  • 7:29 - 7:35
    all of this area down here, even the
    profit maximizing quantity, will mean a
  • 7:36 - 7:42
    loss. On the other hand, once we get above
    $17, above the minimum of the average cost
  • 7:42 - 7:48
    curve, then we can price equal to marginal
    cost. We can chose the quantities such the
  • 7:48 - 7:53
    price is equal to marginal cost. That price
    will be above average cost so we'll be
  • 7:53 - 8:00
    taking a profit. Therefore, $17, the minimum
    of the average cost curve, is the
  • 8:01 - 8:04
    breakeven point.
    If the price is less than the minimum of
  • 8:04 - 8:09
    the average cost curve, we're going to be
    taking a loss. If the price is bigger than
  • 8:09 - 8:13
    the minimum of the average cost curve, then
    we can make a profit. So when should a
  • 8:14 - 8:19
    firm enter or exit an industry? In the
    long run, the firms will enter when price
  • 8:20 - 8:24
    is above average cost. If price is
    somewhere above the average cost curve
  • 8:24 - 8:28
    then the firm can make a profit by
    entering and that's what firms want to do.
  • 8:28 - 8:31
    They want to find profit, so they will
    want to enter wherever a profit is
  • 8:32 - 8:37
    possible. Firms will exit the industry
    when the price is below the average cost
  • 8:37 - 8:41
    curve. Then they're going to be taking a
    loss and they're going to want to exit. So
  • 8:42 - 8:46
    finally, when the price is equal to the
    minimum of the average cost - it's just
  • 8:46 - 8:51
    equal to the bottom of the average cost
    curve, profits are zero and there's no
  • 8:51 - 8:56
    incentive to either exit or enter the
    industry. Now you might ask, why would
  • 8:56 - 9:02
    firms remain in an industry if profits are
    zero? Zero profits, this is just a matter
  • 9:03 - 9:07
    of terminology, means that at the market
    price the firm is covering all of its
  • 9:08 - 9:13
    costs including enough to pay labor and
    capital, their ordinary opportunity cost.
  • 9:14 - 9:18
    So zero profits means everyone
    is being paid, enough to make
  • 9:18 - 9:25
    them satisfied. Zero profits, in other
    words, is what normal people mean by normal
  • 9:25 - 9:30
    profits. So when an economist says zero
    profits just substitute normal profits.
  • 9:31 - 9:35
    One more point about entry and exit. It
    doesn't always make sense to exit an
  • 9:35 - 9:41
    industry immediately when price falls
    below average cost. Or to enter immediately
  • 9:41 - 9:48
    when price is above average cost. Why not?
    Well, there are also entry and exit costs.
  • 9:48 - 9:53
    For example, suppose that that the price
    of oil is currently above the average cost
  • 9:54 - 9:59
    of pumping oil, if you've already got a
    well. Should you enter the industry? Well,
  • 9:59 - 10:05
    maybe not necessarily. Because entry
    requires you to drill an oil well, and
  • 10:05 - 10:09
    drilling an oil well is a sunk cost -
    literally in this case.
  • 10:09 - 10:16
    A sunk cost is a cost that once incurred
    can never be recovered. So if you enter
  • 10:16 - 10:21
    the industry and drill the oil well, you
    don't get that money back when you later
  • 10:21 - 10:28
    exit the industry. What this means is you
    don't want to enter unless you expect the
  • 10:28 - 10:36
    price of oil to stay above the minimum of
    the average cost curve long enough so
  • 10:36 - 10:42
    that you can also recover your entry
    costs. So just because the price goes
  • 10:42 - 10:46
    above the average cost a little bit, you
    don't immediately want to jump into that
  • 10:46 - 10:52
    industry. You have to expect that that
    price is going to stay above average cost
  • 10:52 - 10:59
    long enough for you to recover your entry
    costs. For the same reasons, if there are
  • 10:59 - 11:03
    exit costs, for example, if you have to
    shutter up the well or fill the well with
  • 11:04 - 11:08
    cement when you exit the industry as you
    do in the United States, then when price
  • 11:08 - 11:13
    falls below average cost, it may be best to
    weather the storm at least for sometime
  • 11:14 - 11:21
    before you exit. Only if you expect the
    price of oil to stay below your minimum of
  • 11:21 - 11:27
    average cost for an extended period of
    time will you want to exit the industry.
  • 11:27 - 11:32
    After all, if the price of oil falls below
    the average cost just for a little bit, and
  • 11:32 - 11:37
    then it goes back up, the lifetime
    profits can still be possible. So, entry
  • 11:38 - 11:41
    and exit could be quite complicated
    because you've got to be thinking about
  • 11:41 - 11:47
    the lifetime profits, not just your
    immediate profits. However, the bottom
  • 11:47 - 11:53
    line is pretty simple. Firms seek profits
    and they want to avoid losses. As a
  • 11:53 - 11:58
    result, firms will enter industries when
    the price is above the average cost and
  • 11:58 - 12:02
    they can make a profit, and they will exit
    when the price is below the average cost.
  • 12:02 - 12:04
    Thanks.
  • 12:04 - 12:09
    - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,
    click, "Practice Questions," or if you're
  • 12:10 - 12:12
    ready to move on,
    just click, "Next Video."
  • 12:12 - 12:15
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve
Description:

Being able to predict your company’s profit is a very useful tool. In this video, we introduce the third concept you need to maximize profit — average cost. When looked at in conjunction with the marginal revenue and marginal cost, the average cost curve will show you how to accurately predict how much profit you can make!
The usefulness of these tools does not stop there. Sometimes, you can’t make a profit. You’ll have to take a loss. These tools can also show you how to minimize losses, and make decisions on whether a company should enter or exit an industry.
We also define terms such as zero profits and sunk costs in this video.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/profit-maximization-average-cost#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/supply-curve-increasing-cost-industry

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
12:18

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions