-
♪ [music] ♪
-
- [Narrator] Welcome
to Nobel Conversations.
-
In this episode, Josh Angrist
and Guido Imbens,
-
sit down with Isaiah Andrews
-
to discuss how their research
was initially received
-
and how they responded
to criticism.
-
- [Isaiah] At the time,
did you feel like
-
you were on to something,
-
you felt this was the beginning
of a whole line of work
-
that you felt like was going
to be important or...?
-
- [Guido] Not so much
that it was a whole line of work,
-
but certainly I felt like,
"Wow, this--"
-
- [Josh] We've proved something
we didn't know before,
-
that it was worth knowing.
-
- Yeah, going back to the...
-
compared to my job market
paper or something--
-
No, I felt this was actually
a very clear, crisp result.
-
- But there was definitely
a mixed reception
-
and I don't think anybody
said that,
-
"Oh, well, this is
already something
-
which is the nightmare scenario
for a researcher
-
where you think
you've discovered something
-
and then somebody else says,
"Oh, I knew that."
-
But there definitely was
a need to convince people
-
that this was worth knowing,
that instrumental variables
-
estimates a causal effect
for compliers.
-
- Yeah, but even though
it took a long time
-
to convince a bigger audience,
-
sometimes even fairly quickly,
the reception was pretty good
-
among a small group of people.
-
Gary clearly liked it a lot
from the beginning,
-
and I remember...
-
because at that point
Josh had left for Israel,
-
but I remember explaining it
to Don Rubin,
-
and he was like, "You know,
this really is something here."
-
- Not right away though.
-
Don took some convincing.
-
By the time you got to Don,
-
there have been
some back and forth with him
-
and in correspondence, actually.
-
- But I remember at some point
getting a call or email from him
-
saying that he was sitting
at the airport in Rome
-
and looking at the paper
and thinking,
-
"Yeah, no actually,
you guys are onto something."
-
- We were happy about that.
-
But that took longer
than I think you remember.
-
It wasn't right away.
-
[laughter]
-
Because I know
that I was back in Israel
-
by the time that happened.
-
I'd left for Israel
in the summer of--
-
I was only at Harvard
for two years.
-
We had that one year.
-
It is remarkable, I mean, that
one year was so fateful for us.
-
- [Guido] Yes.
-
I think we understood there was
something good happening,
-
but maybe we didn't think it was
life-changing, only in retrospect.
-
♪ [music] ♪
-
- [Isaiah] As you said, it sounds
like a small group of people
-
were initially quite receptive,
-
perhaps took some time
for a broader group of people
-
to come around to seeing
the LATE framework
-
as a valuable way to look
at the world.
-
I guess, in over
the course of that,
-
were their periods
where you thought,
-
maybe the people saying
this wasn't a useful way
-
to look at the world were right?
-
Did you get discouraged?
How did you think about?
-
- I don't think I was discouraged,
-
but the people who were saying
that we're smart people,
-
well-informed econometricians,
-
sophisticated readers,
-
and I think the substance
of the comment
-
was this is not what
econometrics is about.
-
Econometrics being transmitted
at that time was about structure.
-
There was this idea that
there's structure in the economy,
-
and it's our job to discover it,
-
and what makes its structure
is it's essentially invariant.
-
And so we're saying,
in the LATE theorem,
-
that every instrument produces
its own causal effect,
-
which is in contradiction to that
to some extent,
-
and so that was
where the tension was.
-
People didn't want
to give up that idea.
-
- Yeah, I remember once
people were started
-
arguing more vocally against that,
-
that never really
bothered me that much.
-
It seemed clear that
we had a result there,
-
and it became somewhat
controversial,
-
but controversial in a good way.
-
It was clear that people felt
-
they had to come out
against it because--
-
- Well, I think we think
it's good now.
-
We might not have loved it
at the time.
-
I remember being
somewhat more upset--
-
there was some dinner
where someone said,
-
"No, no, no,
that paper with Josh --
-
that was doing a disservice
to the profession."
-
- We definitely had
reactions like that.
-
- At some level, that may be
indicative of the culture
-
in general in economics
at the time.
-
I thought back later,
what if that happened now?
-
If I was a senior person
sitting in that conversation,
-
I would call that out because
it really was not appropriate--
-
- [Josh] It wasn't so bad.
-
I think the criticism is...
-
It wasn't completely misguided.
-
It was maybe wrong.
-
No, no, but you can say
that paper is wrong,
-
but it's saying that
-
it's a disservice
to the profession --
-
- that's not really--
- [Isaiah] It's a bit personal.
-
- Yes, and doing that not to me
-
but in front of
my senior colleagues.
-
- But nobody was saying
the result was wrong,
-
and I remember also,
-
some of the comments
were thought-provoking.
-
So we had some negative reviews,
-
I think, on the average
causal response paper.
-
Somebody said, "These compliers,
you can't figure out who they are."
-
It's one thing to say
you're estimating
-
the effect of treatment
on the treated
-
or something like that.
-
You can tell me who's treated
-
people in the CPS,
you can't tell me who's a complier.
-
So that was a legitimate challenge.
-
- That's certainly fair,
and I can see why
-
that part made people
a little uneasy and uncomfortable.
-
But at the same time,
-
because it showed that you couldn't
really go beyond that,
-
it was a very useful thing
to realize.
-
I remember on the day
we got to the key result
-
that I was thinking,
"Wow, this is as good as it gets.
-
Here we actually have
an insight, but it clearly--"
-
- And we had to sell it
at some point.
-
For quite a few years,
we had to sell it,
-
and it's proven to be quite useful.
-
I don't think we understood that
it would be so useful at the time.
-
- No.
-
- I did feel early on
this was a substantial insight.
-
- [Josh] Yeah we'd done something.
-
- But I did not think
goals were there.
-
- I don't think we were aiming
for the Nobel.
-
[laughter]
-
We were very happy to get
that note in Econometrica.
-
♪ [music] ♪
-
- [Isaiah] Are there factors
or are ways of approaching problems
-
that lead people to be better
at recognizing the good stuff
-
and taking the time to do it
as opposed to dismissing it?
-
- [Josh] Sometimes
I think it's helpful.
-
If you're trying to
convince somebody
-
that you have something
useful to say
-
and maybe they don't
speak your language,
-
you might need
to learn their language.
-
- Yes, yes, exactly.
-
- That's what we did with Don,
we figured out how to--
-
I remember we had a very hard time
-
explaining the exclusion
restriction to Don,
-
maybe rightfully so,
-
I think Guido and I
eventually figured out
-
that it wasn't formulated
very clearly,
-
and we came up
with a way to do that
-
in the potential outcomes framework
-
that I think worked
for the three of us.
-
- [Guido] Yeah.
-
Well, it worked
for the bigger literature,
-
but I think what you're saying
there is exactly right,
-
you need to figure out
how not just say,
-
"Okay, I've got this language,
and this this works great,
-
and I've got to convince
someone else to use the language.
-
You could first figure out
what language they're using,
-
and then, only then,
can you try to say,
-
"Well, but here you're thinking
of it this way."
-
But that's actually
a pretty hard thing to do.
-
You get someone
from a different discipline,
-
convincing them, two junior faculty
in a different department
-
actually have something
to say to you
-
that takes a fair amount of effort.
-
- Yeah, I wrote Don
a number of times,
-
in fairly long letters.
-
I remember thinking
this is worth doing,
-
that if I could convince Don,
-
that would validate
the framework to some extent.
-
- I think both you and Don
-
were a little bit more confident
that you were right.
-
- Well, we used to argue a lot,
-
and you would sometimes
referee those.
-
[laughter]
-
That was fun.
-
It wasn't hurtful.
-
- I remember it getting
a little testy once.
-
We had lunch in The Faculty Club,
-
and we were talking about
the draft lottery paper.
-
We were talking about "never takes"
-
as people wouldn't serve
in the military
-
irrespective of whether
they were getting drafted,
-
and you or Don said something
-
about shooting yourself
in the foot...
-
[laughter]
-
...as a way of getting out
of the military
-
and that may be
the exclusion restriction
-
for never takes wasn't working,
-
and then the other one was going,
-
"Well, yes, you could do that,
-
but why would you want
to shoot yourself in the foot?"
-
[laughter]
-
It got a little there...
-
- I usually go for moving
to Canada for my example,
-
when I'm teaching that.
-
[laughter]
-
But things are tricky,
-
I get students coming
from Computer Science,
-
and they want to do things
on causal inference,
-
and it takes a huge amount
of effort to figure out
-
how they're actually thinking
about a problem
-
and whether
there's something there.
-
And so, now over the years,
-
I've got a little more appreciation
for the fact
-
that Don was actually willing to--
-
It took him a while,
but he did engage first with Josh
-
and then with both of us,
-
rather than dismissing and saying,
-
"Okay, well, I can't figure out
what these guys are doing,
-
and it's probably just
not really that interesting."
-
- Everybody always wants
to figure out quickly.
-
You want to save time,
-
and you want to save
your brain cells
-
for other things.
-
The fastest route to that
is to figure out
-
why you should dismiss something.
-
- Yes.
-
- I don't need
to spend time on this.
-
♪ [music] ♪
-
- [Narrator] If you'd like
to watch more Nobel Conversations,
-
click here,
-
or if you'd like to learn
more about econometrics,
-
check out Josh's
Mastering Econometrics series.
-
If you'd like to learn more
about Guido, Josh, and Isaiah,
-
check out the links
in the description.
-
♪ [music] ♪