< Return to Video

The Demand Curve Shifts

  • 0:02 - 0:04
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:12 - 0:14
    - [Tyler] In previous videos,
  • 0:14 - 0:16
    we've covered the basics
    of the demand curve.
  • 0:16 - 0:20
    Now let's discuss what happens
    when the demand curve shifts,
  • 0:20 - 0:23
    due to increases or decreases
    in market demand.
  • 0:23 - 0:26
    First, let's look at
    an increase in demand.
  • 0:27 - 0:28
    An increase in demand
  • 0:28 - 0:32
    means that the demand curve
    shifts up and to the right.
  • 0:32 - 0:35
    Take the market
    for houseplants, for instance.
  • 0:35 - 0:38
    On the old demand curve at $20,
  • 0:38 - 0:41
    the quantity demanded
    was five plants,
  • 0:42 - 0:45
    but on the new demand curve
    at, again, $20,
  • 0:45 - 0:47
    the quantity demanded
    is eight plants.
  • 0:48 - 0:52
    At $16, we go from six plants
    to nine plants.
  • 0:54 - 0:58
    At $12, we go from seven
    to ten plants, and so on.
  • 0:58 - 0:59
    An increase in demand
  • 0:59 - 1:02
    is a greater quantity
    demanded at every price.
  • 1:03 - 1:05
    We can also read
    an increase in demand
  • 1:05 - 1:08
    using what is called
    the vertical method.
  • 1:08 - 1:10
    What that means
    is that for every quantity,
  • 1:10 - 1:13
    there's a greater willingness
    to pay for that quantity.
  • 1:14 - 1:16
    For instance, for the fifth unit,
  • 1:16 - 1:19
    people had been willing
    to pay $20 for that unit.
  • 1:19 - 1:21
    Now with the new demand curve,
  • 1:21 - 1:24
    people are willing to pay
    $32 for that unit.
  • 1:25 - 1:28
    In summary, an increase in demand
  • 1:28 - 1:30
    means an increase
    in the quantity demanded
  • 1:30 - 1:32
    at every market price.
  • 1:32 - 1:35
    Or equivalently,
    it means an increase
  • 1:35 - 1:38
    in the maximum willingness
    to pay for a given quantity.
  • 1:39 - 1:41
    A decrease in demand --
  • 1:41 - 1:43
    well, that's just the opposite
    of an increase in demand.
  • 1:44 - 1:46
    It's a shift down and to the left.
  • 1:47 - 1:50
    There's a decrease in quantity
    demanded at every price.
  • 1:51 - 1:55
    Now at $20, people only want
    to buy two houseplants.
  • 1:56 - 2:00
    At $16, we go from six
    to three houseplants and so on.
  • 2:01 - 2:04
    Similarly, this means a decrease
  • 2:04 - 2:06
    in the willingness to pay
    for the same quantity.
  • 2:07 - 2:08
    For the fifth unit,
  • 2:08 - 2:11
    people were willing to pay
    $20 for that unit,
  • 2:11 - 2:14
    but now they're only going
    to fork over $8
  • 2:14 - 2:15
    for that houseplant.
  • 2:16 - 2:19
    So what can cause
    a shift in demand?
  • 2:20 - 2:23
    What would make consumers
    buy more or less of a good
  • 2:23 - 2:24
    at every price?
  • 2:25 - 2:27
    Take a moment
    to jot down some guesses.
  • 2:30 - 2:32
    We'll go through these
    with a few examples.
  • 2:32 - 2:35
    But the real goal
    is not to memorize this list
  • 2:35 - 2:37
    but rather to understand
  • 2:37 - 2:40
    what an increase
    or decrease in demand means
  • 2:40 - 2:42
    so that you can recreate
    this list on your own.
  • 2:43 - 2:45
    Let's now go through five factors
  • 2:45 - 2:48
    that can increase
    or decrease market demand,
  • 2:48 - 2:52
    namely income, population, tastes,
  • 2:52 - 2:54
    the price of related goods,
  • 2:54 - 2:56
    and finally, expectations.
  • 2:57 - 2:59
    Let's start with changes in income.
  • 3:00 - 3:02
    The effect of a change
    in income on demand
  • 3:02 - 3:05
    depends on the nature
    of the good in question.
  • 3:06 - 3:08
    For most goods,
    as your income goes up,
  • 3:08 - 3:10
    you demand more of the good.
  • 3:10 - 3:12
    Think, for instance, fine dining.
  • 3:12 - 3:14
    You need to be able
    to afford it, right?
  • 3:15 - 3:18
    The demand curve then shifts up
    and to the right.
  • 3:18 - 3:20
    These goods are called normal goods
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    because the demand for them
    goes up when incomes go up,
  • 3:24 - 3:26
    and indeed most goods
    are normal goods --
  • 3:26 - 3:28
    that's why we call them normal.
  • 3:28 - 3:30
    And these same goods --
  • 3:30 - 3:34
    the demand for them goes down
    when incomes go down.
  • 3:35 - 3:36
    There are also goods, however,
  • 3:37 - 3:39
    for which,
    when your income goes up,
  • 3:39 - 3:41
    your demand for them
    actually goes down.
  • 3:42 - 3:43
    These are exceptions.
  • 3:43 - 3:45
    We call them inferior goods.
  • 3:45 - 3:48
    So an example
    of such an inferior good
  • 3:48 - 3:50
    might be instant ramen --
  • 3:50 - 3:51
    it's very cheap.
  • 3:52 - 3:55
    As you make more money,
    you might buy, say,
  • 3:55 - 3:59
    more caviar, more steak,
    and less instant ramen.
  • 3:59 - 4:00
    - [voice] No, thanks!
  • 4:00 - 4:02
    - [Tyler] Thus, the demand curve
    for instant ramen
  • 4:02 - 4:06
    will shift down into the left
    as your income increases.
  • 4:07 - 4:10
    Now let's move on
    to changes in population.
  • 4:11 - 4:13
    If the population
    of an economy changes,
  • 4:14 - 4:18
    the number of potential buyers
    of a good changes also.
  • 4:19 - 4:21
    What would happen
    to the demand for hearing aids
  • 4:21 - 4:24
    if the elderly population
    in your country increased?
  • 4:25 - 4:28
    Well, very likely, demand
    for hearing aids would increase.
  • 4:28 - 4:30
    At any price
    for those hearing aids,
  • 4:30 - 4:33
    there would be
    a higher quantity demanded.
  • 4:39 - 4:42
    Can you think of a good
    that would decrease in demand
  • 4:42 - 4:44
    if the birth rates
    in your country decreased?
  • 4:45 - 4:48
    Now, we'll move on
    to changes in tastes.
  • 4:48 - 4:51
    Tastes are subjective,
    and they're changing all the time.
  • 4:51 - 4:56
    New information, fashions, and fads
    all can impact tastes.
  • 4:56 - 4:57
    To give an example,
  • 4:58 - 5:00
    what happens to the demand
    for hamburgers
  • 5:00 - 5:02
    if low-carb diets,
  • 5:02 - 5:04
    like the keto diet
    or the caveman diet
  • 5:04 - 5:06
    become more popular?
  • 5:06 - 5:10
    Well, people would want to go out
    and buy and eat more hamburgers,
  • 5:10 - 5:13
    and so the demand for hamburgers
    would increase.
  • 5:14 - 5:18
    Alternatively,
    what if a controversy surfaced
  • 5:18 - 5:21
    that questioned the ethics
    of hamburger production?
  • 5:21 - 5:24
    People might then feel bad
    about buying hamburgers,
  • 5:24 - 5:26
    and then they would buy
    fewer hamburgers
  • 5:26 - 5:28
    or maybe stop
    buying them altogether.
  • 5:29 - 5:32
    The demand for hamburgers
    then would go down.
  • 5:33 - 5:37
    Next, let's consider how the price
    of a related good
  • 5:37 - 5:39
    can affect demand,
  • 5:39 - 5:41
    starting with substitute goods.
  • 5:41 - 5:45
    Now substitutes are two goods
    that are roughly interchangeable.
  • 5:45 - 5:46
    They're not the same,
  • 5:46 - 5:49
    but they can serve
    broadly similar functions.
  • 5:49 - 5:52
    Take, for instance,
    hot dogs and hamburgers --
  • 5:52 - 5:54
    they're both something
    you might have for dinner.
  • 5:54 - 5:56
    Now in the setting,
  • 5:56 - 5:58
    suppose the price
    of hot dogs goes up.
  • 5:58 - 6:01
    What happens to the demand
    for hamburgers --
  • 6:01 - 6:02
    a substitute for hot dogs?
  • 6:03 - 6:05
    People will opt to buy
  • 6:05 - 6:08
    the relatively less expensive
    hamburgers,
  • 6:08 - 6:11
    instead of the now
    more expensive hot dogs.
  • 6:13 - 6:16
    That means the demand
    for hamburgers increases.
  • 6:17 - 6:19
    Or consider
    the opposite occurrence.
  • 6:20 - 6:22
    What if the price
    of hot dogs decreases,
  • 6:22 - 6:24
    instead of going up?
  • 6:24 - 6:26
    What happens then
    to the demand for hamburgers?
  • 6:27 - 6:29
    Well, that's just the opposite
    of the first scenario.
  • 6:30 - 6:31
    Hot dogs are now cheaper,
  • 6:31 - 6:34
    and the demand
    for hamburgers decreases
  • 6:34 - 6:37
    because it now costs less
    to buy hot dogs instead.
  • 6:38 - 6:41
    Technically,
    two goods are substitutes
  • 6:41 - 6:43
    if an increase
    in the price of one good
  • 6:43 - 6:47
    leads to an increase in demand
    for the other good and vice versa.
  • 6:48 - 6:50
    Another kind of related good
  • 6:50 - 6:52
    is what economists
    call complements.
  • 6:53 - 6:56
    Complements are two goods
    which are often used together
  • 6:56 - 6:58
    and make each other more valuable.
  • 6:58 - 7:01
    Suppose the price
    of hamburgers increases.
  • 7:02 - 7:05
    What happens to the demand
    for hamburger buns --
  • 7:05 - 7:07
    a complement
    to hamburgers [proper]?
  • 7:08 - 7:11
    Well, fewer people
    will buy hamburgers,
  • 7:11 - 7:14
    and so fewer people
    will buy hamburger buns.
  • 7:14 - 7:18
    The demand
    for hamburger buns decreases.
  • 7:19 - 7:21
    And to consider
    the opposite situation,
  • 7:22 - 7:24
    if the price
    of hamburger decreases,
  • 7:24 - 7:27
    demand for hamburger buns
    will increase --
  • 7:27 - 7:30
    that is, more people
    buying hamburger
  • 7:30 - 7:32
    means more people
    buying hamburger buns as well
  • 7:32 - 7:35
    because again, you're putting
    the hamburger and the bun together.
  • 7:36 - 7:38
    Technically, two goods
    are complements
  • 7:38 - 7:41
    if an increase
    in the price of one good
  • 7:41 - 7:43
    leads to a decrease
    in the demand for the other,
  • 7:43 - 7:45
    and vice versa.
  • 7:45 - 7:47
    So in sum, hamburger producers
  • 7:47 - 7:50
    want the price
    of hot dogs to go up,
  • 7:50 - 7:52
    the price of hamburger buns
    to go down,
  • 7:52 - 7:55
    and low-carb diets to go viral.
  • 7:55 - 7:57
    Finally, let's look
    at expectations.
  • 7:58 - 8:01
    These can be expectations
    of market prices
  • 8:01 - 8:02
    or of market events.
  • 8:02 - 8:04
    Consider video game consoles.
  • 8:04 - 8:06
    If it's November,
  • 8:06 - 8:09
    and people expect the price
    of a gaming console to go down
  • 8:09 - 8:11
    in a December holiday sale,
  • 8:11 - 8:14
    they might wait a few weeks
    before buying the console.
  • 8:15 - 8:18
    Demand for that console
    decreases today
  • 8:18 - 8:20
    because it's going
    to increase later on.
  • 8:21 - 8:23
    Or take batteries.
  • 8:23 - 8:26
    Suppose you hear there's going
    to be a big hurricane in your area.
  • 8:27 - 8:28
    If a hurricane hits,
  • 8:28 - 8:31
    you might expect the price
    of batteries is going to go up,
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    or maybe it will be really hard
    to get any batteries at all.
  • 8:35 - 8:36
    - [voice] Oh no!
  • 8:36 - 8:39
    - [Tyler] That means a higher
    demand for batteries today,
  • 8:39 - 8:40
    and so the expectation
  • 8:40 - 8:42
    of this future event
    of the hurricane
  • 8:42 - 8:45
    can change the demand
    for batteries today.
  • 8:46 - 8:48
    If people expect
    the price of a good
  • 8:48 - 8:49
    to be higher in the future --
  • 8:50 - 8:52
    that typically increases
    demand today.
  • 8:53 - 8:55
    Consumers adjust
    their current spending
  • 8:55 - 8:57
    anticipating the future prices
  • 8:57 - 9:00
    to obtain
    the lowest price possible.
  • 9:00 - 9:02
    And that's it
    for our list of shifters.
  • 9:03 - 9:06
    Now that you understand
    what a shift in demand means,
  • 9:06 - 9:09
    practice recreating
    this list of shifters on your own.
  • 9:10 - 9:12
    What would cause
    a higher quantity demanded
  • 9:12 - 9:13
    at every price?
  • 9:14 - 9:15
    More people? Wealthier people?
  • 9:16 - 9:18
    It's the hotter in-item and so on.
  • 9:18 - 9:21
    Conversely, what would cause
    less of a good
  • 9:21 - 9:24
    to be demanded at every price?
  • 9:24 - 9:25
    Once you can do that,
  • 9:25 - 9:28
    you'll be able to identify
    demand shifters
  • 9:28 - 9:31
    without the need
    to memorize any list.
  • 9:33 - 9:34
    - [Narrator] If you're a teacher,
  • 9:34 - 9:37
    you should check out
    our supply and demand unit plan
  • 9:37 - 9:38
    that incorporates this video.
  • 9:38 - 9:39
    If you're a learner,
  • 9:39 - 9:41
    make sure this video sticks
  • 9:41 - 9:43
    by answering a few quick
    practice questions.
  • 9:44 - 9:46
    Or if you're ready
    for more microeconomics,
  • 9:46 - 9:47
    click for the next video.
  • 9:49 - 9:51
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
The Demand Curve Shifts
ASR Confidence:
0.87
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
09:54

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions