< Return to Video

How Is Econometrics Changing? (Josh Angrist, Guido Imbens, Isaiah Andrews)

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:04 - 0:06
    - [Narrator] Welcome
    to Nobel Conversations.
  • 0:07 - 0:08
    In this episode,
  • 0:08 - 0:12
    Josh Angrist and Guido Imbens
    sit down with Isaiah Andrews
  • 0:12 - 0:15
    to discuss how the field
    of econometrics is evolving.
  • 0:16 - 0:19
    - [Isaiah] So, Guido and Josh,
    you're both pioneers
  • 0:19 - 0:22
    in developing tools for
    empirical research in economics.
  • 0:22 - 0:23
    And so I'd like to explore
  • 0:23 - 0:25
    where you feel like
    the field is heading --
  • 0:26 - 0:28
    economics, econometrics,
    the whole thing.
  • 0:29 - 0:31
    To start, I'd be interested to hear
  • 0:32 - 0:35
    about whether you feel
    the way in which
  • 0:35 - 0:39
    the local average treatment
    effects framework took hold
  • 0:39 - 0:42
    has any lessons for how
    new empirical methods in economics
  • 0:42 - 0:44
    develop and spread
    or how they should.
  • 0:45 - 0:46
    - [Josh] That's a good question.
  • 0:47 - 0:48
    You go first.
  • 0:48 - 0:49
    [laughter]
  • 0:50 - 0:53
    - [Guido] Yeah, so I think
    the important thing
  • 0:53 - 0:59
    is to come up
    with good convincing cases
  • 0:59 - 1:02
    where the questions are clear
  • 1:02 - 1:06
    and where the methods
    apply in general.
  • 1:06 - 1:08
    One thing I...
  • 1:08 - 1:12
    Looking back
    at the subsequent literature.
  • 1:12 - 1:17
    I really like the regression
    discontinuity literature
  • 1:17 - 1:20
    where there were clearly a bunch
    of really convincing examples
  • 1:20 - 1:23
    and that allowed people
    to think more clearly,
  • 1:23 - 1:27
    look harder
    at the methodological questions.
  • 1:27 - 1:29
    Do clear applications
  • 1:29 - 1:31
    that then allow you
    to kind of think about,
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    "Wow, do these type of assumptions
    seem reasonable here?
  • 1:34 - 1:38
    What kind of things do we not like
    in the early papers?
  • 1:38 - 1:40
    How can we improve things?"
  • 1:40 - 1:44
    So having clear applications
    motivating these literatures
  • 1:44 - 1:46
    I think is very helpful.
  • 1:47 - 1:48
    - I'm glad you mentioned
  • 1:48 - 1:49
    the regression
    discontinuity, Guido.
  • 1:49 - 1:53
    I think there's a lot of
    complementarity between IV and RD,
  • 1:55 - 1:57
    instrumental variables
    and regression discontinuity.
  • 2:01 - 2:03
    A lot of the econometric
    applications
  • 2:03 - 2:05
    of regression discontinuity
  • 2:05 - 2:07
    are what used
    to be called "fuzzy" RD,
  • 2:07 - 2:12
    where it's not discrete
    or deterministic at the cutoff
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    but just the change
    in rates or intensity.
  • 2:15 - 2:18
    And the LATE framework
    helps us understand
  • 2:18 - 2:19
    those applications
  • 2:19 - 2:21
    and gives us a clear interpretation
  • 2:21 - 2:25
    for something like
    in my paper with Victor Lavy,
  • 2:25 - 2:28
    where we use Maimonides'
    rule, the class size cutoffs,
  • 2:28 - 2:30
    and what are you getting there?
  • 2:30 - 2:32
    Of course, you can
    answer that question
  • 2:32 - 2:34
    with a linear
    constant effects model,
  • 2:34 - 2:36
    but it turns out
    we're not limited to that,
  • 2:36 - 2:40
    and RD is still very powerful
    and illuminating,
  • 2:41 - 2:43
    even when the correlation
  • 2:43 - 2:46
    between the cutoff
    and the variable of interest,
  • 2:46 - 2:49
    in this case, class size,
    is partial,
  • 2:49 - 2:51
    maybe even not that strong.
  • 2:52 - 2:55
    So there was definitely
    a parallel development.
  • 2:55 - 2:56
    It's also interesting...
  • 2:57 - 3:00
    Nobody talked about
    regression discontinuity designs
  • 3:00 - 3:01
    when we were in graduate school --
  • 3:01 - 3:03
    it was something
  • 3:03 - 3:05
    that other social scientists
    were interested in,
  • 3:06 - 3:10
    and that grew up
    alongside the LATE framework,
  • 3:10 - 3:12
    and we've both done work
  • 3:12 - 3:15
    on both applications
    and methods there,
  • 3:15 - 3:18
    and it's been very exciting
    to see that develop
  • 3:18 - 3:20
    and become so important.
  • 3:20 - 3:22
    It's part of a general evolution,
  • 3:22 - 3:26
    I think, towards credible
    identification strategies,
  • 3:26 - 3:27
    causal effects,
  • 3:29 - 3:31
    making econometrics
  • 3:31 - 3:33
    more about causal questions
    than about models.
  • 3:34 - 3:35
    In terms of the future,
  • 3:35 - 3:38
    I think one thing that LATE
    has helped facilitate
  • 3:38 - 3:42
    is a move towards
    more creative, randomized trials
  • 3:42 - 3:44
    where there's
    something of interest.
  • 3:46 - 3:48
    It's not possible
    or straightforward
  • 3:48 - 3:51
    to simply turn it off or on,
  • 3:51 - 3:55
    but you can encourage it
    or discourage it.
  • 3:55 - 3:58
    So you subsidize schooling
    with financial aid, for example.
  • 3:59 - 4:02
    So now we have a whole
    framework for interpreting that,
  • 4:04 - 4:07
    and it opens the doors
    to randomized trials
  • 4:07 - 4:09
    of things that maybe would
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    not have seemed possible before.
  • 4:14 - 4:18
    We've used that a lot in the work
    we do on schools in our --
  • 4:18 - 4:21
    in the Blueprint Lab at MIT.
  • 4:22 - 4:27
    We're exploiting random assignment
    in very creative ways, I think.
  • 4:28 - 4:31
    - [Isaiah] Related to that,
    do you see particular factors
  • 4:31 - 4:34
    that make for useful research
    in econometrics?
  • 4:34 - 4:38
    You've alluded to it having
    a clear connection
  • 4:38 - 4:40
    to problems
    that are actually coming up,
  • 4:40 - 4:43
    and empirical practice
    is often a good idea.
  • 4:43 - 4:45
    - Isn't it always a good idea?
  • 4:46 - 4:50
    I often find myself sitting
    in an econometrics theory seminar,
  • 4:51 - 4:52
    say the Harvard MIT seminar,
  • 4:53 - 4:56
    and I'm thinking, "What problem
    is this guy solving?
  • 4:56 - 4:58
    Who has this problem?"
  • 4:58 - 5:00
    And, you know...
  • 5:02 - 5:05
    sometimes there's an
    embarrassing silence if I ask
  • 5:05 - 5:08
    or there might be
    a fairly contrived scenario.
  • 5:09 - 5:12
    I want to see
    where the tool is useful.
  • 5:12 - 5:15
    There are some
    purely foundational tools --
  • 5:15 - 5:16
    I do take the point.
  • 5:16 - 5:22
    There are people who are working
    on conceptual foundations of...
  • 5:23 - 5:25
    it becomes more like
    mathematical statistics.
  • 5:26 - 5:28
    I mean, I remember
    an early example of that
  • 5:28 - 5:30
    that I struggled to understand
  • 5:30 - 5:32
    was the idea
    of stochastic equicontinuity,
  • 5:32 - 5:35
    which one of my thesis advisors,
    Whitney Newey,
  • 5:35 - 5:36
    was using to great effect,
  • 5:36 - 5:39
    and I was trying
    to understand that.
  • 5:41 - 5:42
    It's really foundational.
  • 5:42 - 5:45
    it's not an application
    that's driving that --
  • 5:46 - 5:47
    at least not immediately.
  • 5:49 - 5:53
    But most things are not like that,
    and so there should be a problem.
  • 5:54 - 5:59
    And I think it's on the seller
    of that sort of thing,
  • 6:00 - 6:02
    because there's opportunity cost,
  • 6:02 - 6:05
    the time and attention,
    and effort to understand things.
  • 6:06 - 6:07
    It's on the seller to say,
  • 6:07 - 6:09
    "Hey, I'm solving this problem,
  • 6:09 - 6:13
    and here's a set of results
    that show that it's useful,
  • 6:13 - 6:15
    and here's some insight
    that I get."
  • 6:16 - 6:18
    - [Isaiah] As you said, Josh,
    there's been a move
  • 6:18 - 6:21
    in the direction of thinking
    more about causality
  • 6:21 - 6:23
    in economics and empirical
    work in economics.
  • 6:23 - 6:27
    Any consequences of the spread
    of that view that surprised you
  • 6:27 - 6:28
    or anything that you view
    as downsides
  • 6:29 - 6:32
    of the way that empirical
    economics has gone?
  • 6:32 - 6:34
    - Sometimes I see
    somebody does IV,
  • 6:34 - 6:38
    and they get a result
    which seems implausibly large --
  • 6:39 - 6:40
    that's the usual case.
  • 6:42 - 6:45
    So it might be
    an extraordinarily large
  • 6:45 - 6:49
    causal effect of some
    relatively minor intervention,
  • 6:49 - 6:52
    which was randomized
    or for which you could make a case
  • 6:52 - 6:54
    that there's a good design.
  • 6:55 - 6:57
    And then when I see that,
  • 6:58 - 7:00
    I think it's very hard
    for me to believe
  • 7:00 - 7:02
    that this relatively
    minor intervention
  • 7:02 - 7:04
    has such a large effect.
  • 7:04 - 7:06
    The author will sometimes resort
  • 7:06 - 7:09
    to the local average
    treatment effects theorem
  • 7:09 - 7:11
    and say, "Well, these compliers --
  • 7:11 - 7:13
    they're special in some way,
  • 7:13 - 7:16
    and they just benefit
    extraordinarily
  • 7:16 - 7:18
    from this intervention."
  • 7:18 - 7:21
    I'm reluctant to take that
    at face value.
  • 7:21 - 7:24
    I think often when effects
    are too big,
  • 7:24 - 7:27
    it's because the exclusion
    restriction is failing,
  • 7:27 - 7:29
    so you don't really have the right
    endogenous variable
  • 7:29 - 7:31
    to scale that result.
  • 7:32 - 7:36
    And so, I'm not too happy to see
  • 7:37 - 7:40
    a generic heterogeneity argument
  • 7:40 - 7:42
    being used to excuse something
  • 7:42 - 7:44
    that I think might be
    a deeper problem.
  • 7:45 - 7:47
    - [Guido] I think it played
    somewhat of an unfortunate role
  • 7:47 - 7:50
    in the discussions
    between reduced form
  • 7:50 - 7:52
    and structural approaches,
  • 7:52 - 7:56
    where I feel
    that wasn't quite right.
  • 7:56 - 7:59
    The instrumental
    variables assumptions
  • 7:59 - 8:02
    are at the core,
  • 8:02 - 8:03
    structural assumptions
    about behavior --
  • 8:03 - 8:05
    they were coming from economic...
  • 8:07 - 8:10
    thinking about the economic
    behavior of agents,
  • 8:10 - 8:15
    and somehow it got pushed
    in a direction
  • 8:15 - 8:18
    that I think wasn't
    really very helpful.
  • 8:20 - 8:22
    I think, initially,
  • 8:23 - 8:24
    we wrote things up,
  • 8:24 - 8:26
    it was describing
    what was happening.
  • 8:26 - 8:30
    There were a set of methods
    people were using.
  • 8:30 - 8:32
    We clarified what
    those methods were doing
  • 8:33 - 8:38
    in a way that I think contain
    a fair amount of insight.
  • 8:39 - 8:42
    But it somehow
    got pushed into a corner
  • 8:42 - 8:45
    that I don't think
    was necessarily very helpful.
  • 8:45 - 8:49
    - In just the language
    of reduced form versus structural,
  • 8:49 - 8:50
    I find kind of funny in the sense
  • 8:50 - 8:53
    that the local average
    treatment effect model,
  • 8:53 - 8:54
    the potential outcomes model
  • 8:54 - 8:56
    is a nonparametric
    structural model,
  • 8:56 - 8:59
    if you want to think about it,
    as you suggested, Guido.
  • 8:59 - 9:01
    So there's something a little funny
  • 9:01 - 9:04
    about putting these
    two things in opposition when --
  • 9:04 - 9:05
    - [Guido] Yes.
    - [Josh] That language, of course,
  • 9:05 - 9:08
    comes from the simultaneous
    equations framework
  • 9:08 - 9:10
    that we inherited.
  • 9:10 - 9:11
    It has the advantage
  • 9:11 - 9:14
    that people seem to know
    what you mean when you use it,
  • 9:14 - 9:15
    but that might be
  • 9:17 - 9:18
    that different people
    are hearing different things.
  • 9:18 - 9:20
    - [Guido] Yeah. I think
    reduced form has become
  • 9:20 - 9:22
    used in a little bit
    of the pejorative way...
  • 9:22 - 9:24
    - [Josh] Sometimes.
  • 9:25 - 9:28
    ...which is not really quite what
    it was originally intended for.
  • 9:30 - 9:33
    - [Isaiah] I guess something else
    that strikes me in thinking about
  • 9:33 - 9:36
    the effects of the local average
    treatment effect framework
  • 9:36 - 9:38
    is that often folks will appeal
  • 9:38 - 9:40
    to a local average treatment
    effects intuition
  • 9:40 - 9:42
    for settings well beyond ones
  • 9:42 - 9:45
    where any sort of formal result
    has actually been established.
  • 9:45 - 9:49
    And I'm curious, given all the work
    that you guys did
  • 9:49 - 9:52
    to establish LATE results
    in different settings,
  • 9:52 - 9:54
    I'm curious, any thoughts on that?
  • 9:55 - 9:57
    - I think there's going
    to be a lot of cases
  • 9:57 - 10:02
    where the intuition
    does get you some distance,
  • 10:03 - 10:05
    but it's going to be
    somewhat limited,
  • 10:05 - 10:08
    and establishing
    formal results there
  • 10:08 - 10:09
    may be a little tricky
  • 10:09 - 10:13
    and then maybe only work
    in special circumstances,
  • 10:15 - 10:17
    and you end up
    with a lot of formality
  • 10:17 - 10:20
    that may not quite
    capture the intuition.
  • 10:20 - 10:22
    Sometimes I'm somewhat
    uneasy with them,
  • 10:22 - 10:24
    and they are not necessarily
    the papers I would want to write,
  • 10:25 - 10:28
    but I do think intuition
  • 10:28 - 10:31
    often does capture
    part of the problem.
  • 10:33 - 10:36
    I think, in some sense,
    we were very fortunate there
  • 10:37 - 10:39
    in the way that the LATE paper
    got handled at the journal,
  • 10:39 - 10:42
    so that, actually, the editor,
    made it much shorter
  • 10:42 - 10:46
    and that allowed us to focus
    on very clear, crisp results.
  • 10:50 - 10:52
    There's a somewhat
    unfortunate tendency
  • 10:52 - 10:53
    in the econometrics literature
  • 10:53 - 10:55
    of having the papers
    get longer and longer.
  • 10:55 - 10:57
    - Well, you should be able
    to fix that, man.
  • 10:57 - 10:59
    - I'm trying to fix that.
    [laughter]
  • 10:59 - 11:02
    But I think this is an example
    where it's very clear
  • 11:02 - 11:03
    that having it be short
    is actually --
  • 11:03 - 11:05
    - You should have imposed
    that no paper
  • 11:05 - 11:07
    can be longer than the LATE paper.
  • 11:07 - 11:10
    - That... wow! That may be great.
  • 11:10 - 11:12
    - At least no theory,
    no theory paper.
  • 11:12 - 11:13
    - Yeah, and I think...
  • 11:14 - 11:17
    I'm trying very hard to get
    the papers to be shorter,
  • 11:17 - 11:20
    and I think there is a lot
    of value today
  • 11:20 - 11:22
    because it's often
    the second part of the paper
  • 11:22 - 11:25
    that doesn't actually
    get you much further
  • 11:25 - 11:26
    in understanding things,
  • 11:27 - 11:30
    and it does make things
    much harder to read.
  • 11:32 - 11:36
    It goes back to how I think
    econometrics should be done.
  • 11:36 - 11:38
    You should focus on --
  • 11:39 - 11:41
    It should be reasonably
    close to empirical problems.
  • 11:42 - 11:44
    They should be very clear problems.
  • 11:45 - 11:49
    But then often the theory
    doesn't need to be quite so long.
  • 11:49 - 11:50
    - [Josh] Yeah.
  • 11:51 - 11:55
    - I think things have gone
    a little off track.
  • 11:56 - 11:58
    - [Isaiah] A relatively
    recent change
  • 11:58 - 12:00
    has been a seeming
    big increase in demand
  • 12:00 - 12:04
    for people with econometrics
    causal effect estimation skills
  • 12:04 - 12:05
    in the tech sector.
  • 12:05 - 12:08
    I'm interested,
    do either of you have thoughts
  • 12:08 - 12:10
    of how that's going to interact
  • 12:10 - 12:12
    with the development
    of empirical methods
  • 12:12 - 12:14
    or empirical research
    in economics going forward?
  • 12:15 - 12:17
    - [Josh] Well, there's
    sort of a meta point,
  • 12:17 - 12:21
    which is there's this new
    kind of employer,
  • 12:22 - 12:28
    the Amazons and the Uber,
    and the TripAdvisor world,
  • 12:28 - 12:29
    and I think that's great.
  • 12:29 - 12:32
    I like to tell my students
    about that.
  • 12:33 - 12:36
    At MIT, we have a lot
    of computer science majors --
  • 12:36 - 12:37
    that's our biggest major.
  • 12:37 - 12:42
    I try to seduce some of those folks
    into economics by saying
  • 12:43 - 12:47
    you can go work for these companies
  • 12:47 - 12:49
    that people
    are very keen to work for
  • 12:49 - 12:51
    because the work seems exciting,
  • 12:52 - 12:54
    that the skills
    that you get in econometrics
  • 12:54 - 12:56
    are as good or better
  • 12:56 - 13:00
    than any competing
    discipline has to offer.
  • 13:00 - 13:02
    So you should at least
    take some econ --
  • 13:02 - 13:04
    take some econometrics
    and some econ.
  • 13:05 - 13:07
    I did a fun project with Uber
  • 13:08 - 13:10
    on labor supply of Uber drivers,
  • 13:10 - 13:13
    and it was very, very exciting
    to be part of that.
  • 13:13 - 13:15
    Plus, I got to drive
    for Uber for a while,
  • 13:16 - 13:18
    and I thought that was fun too.
  • 13:18 - 13:19
    I did not make enough
  • 13:19 - 13:23
    that I was tempted
    to give up my MIT job,
  • 13:23 - 13:25
    but I enjoyed the experience.
  • 13:25 - 13:28
    I see a potential challenge
  • 13:28 - 13:31
    to our model
    of graduate education here,
  • 13:32 - 13:36
    which is, if we're training people
    to go work at Amazon,
  • 13:38 - 13:41
    it's not clear why
    we should be paying
  • 13:41 - 13:43
    graduate stipends for that.
  • 13:43 - 13:47
    Why should the taxpayer
    effectively be subsidizing that.
  • 13:47 - 13:51
    Our graduate education
    in the US is generously subsidized,
  • 13:51 - 13:53
    even in private universities --
  • 13:55 - 13:56
    there's a lot
    of public money there.
  • 13:56 - 13:59
    And I think the traditional
    rationale for that is,
  • 14:00 - 14:02
    we were training
    educators and scholars,
  • 14:02 - 14:06
    and there's a great externality
    from the work that we do,
  • 14:06 - 14:08
    it's either
    the research externality,
  • 14:08 - 14:10
    or a teaching externality.
  • 14:10 - 14:13
    But if many of our students
    are going to work
  • 14:13 - 14:15
    in the private sector --
  • 14:16 - 14:17
    that's fine,
  • 14:19 - 14:22
    but maybe their employers
    should pay for them.
  • 14:22 - 14:23
    - For me, it's just so different
  • 14:23 - 14:27
    from people working
    for consulting firms.
  • 14:27 - 14:29
    It's not clear to me
  • 14:29 - 14:33
    that the number of jobs
    in academics has changed.
  • 14:33 - 14:36
    - I feel like this is
    a growing sector,
  • 14:36 - 14:38
    whereas consulting...
  • 14:38 - 14:39
    You're right to raise that.
  • 14:39 - 14:42
    It might be the same
    for consulting.
  • 14:45 - 14:48
    I'm placing more and more
    students in these businesses,
  • 14:48 - 14:49
    so it's on my mind, in a way,
  • 14:49 - 14:54
    that I've not been attentive
    to consulting jobs.
  • 14:54 - 14:57
    Consulting was always important,
  • 14:57 - 14:59
    and I think also
    there's some movement
  • 14:59 - 15:01
    from consulting back
    into research --
  • 15:01 - 15:03
    it's a little more fluid.
  • 15:04 - 15:08
    A lot of the work in both domains,
  • 15:08 - 15:09
    I have to say,
    it's not really different,
  • 15:09 - 15:13
    but people who are working
    in the tech sector
  • 15:13 - 15:15
    are doing things that are
    potentially of scientific interest,
  • 15:15 - 15:17
    but mostly it's hidden.
  • 15:17 - 15:19
    Then you really have to say,
  • 15:19 - 15:21
    why is the government
    paying for this?
  • 15:22 - 15:24
    - Although, to Guido's point,
  • 15:24 - 15:27
    I guess there's
    a data question here of
  • 15:27 - 15:33
    has the total [non-EC]
    for-profit sector employment
  • 15:33 - 15:36
    of econ Ph.D. program
    graduates increased
  • 15:36 - 15:38
    or has it just been
    a substitution from finance
  • 15:38 - 15:40
    and consulting towards tech?
  • 15:40 - 15:42
    - I may be reacting to something
  • 15:42 - 15:44
    that's not really happening.
  • 15:44 - 15:46
    - I've actually done some work
  • 15:46 - 15:48
    with some of these tech companies.
  • 15:49 - 15:52
    I don't disagree with Josh's point
    that we need to think
  • 15:52 - 15:54
    a little bit about
    the funding model
  • 15:54 - 15:56
    who is, in the end, paying
    for the graduate education.
  • 15:57 - 15:59
    But from a scientific perspective,
  • 16:00 - 16:03
    not only do these places
    have great data,
  • 16:03 - 16:05
    and nowadays they tend to be
    very careful with that
  • 16:05 - 16:07
    for privacy reasons,
  • 16:07 - 16:09
    but they also have great questions.
  • 16:10 - 16:14
    I find it very inspiring to listen
    to the people there
  • 16:14 - 16:16
    and see what kind
    of questions they have,
  • 16:16 - 16:17
    and often they're questions
  • 16:18 - 16:21
    that also come up
    outside of these companies.
  • 16:21 - 16:27
    I have a couple of papers
    with Raj Chetty and Susan Athey
  • 16:27 - 16:32
    where we look at ways
    of combining experimental data
  • 16:32 - 16:33
    and observational data.
  • 16:36 - 16:39
    Raj Chetty was interested
    in what is the effect
  • 16:39 - 16:43
    of early childhood programs
    on outcomes later in life,
  • 16:43 - 16:46
    not just on test scores
    but on earnings and stuff,
  • 16:46 - 16:48
    and we kind of developed methods
  • 16:49 - 16:52
    that would help you shed light
    on that under some...
  • 16:53 - 16:54
    in some settings,
  • 16:54 - 16:57
    and the same problems came up
  • 16:57 - 17:01
    in these tech company settings.
  • 17:01 - 17:03
    And so, from my perspective,
  • 17:03 - 17:05
    it's the same kind of --
  • 17:05 - 17:08
    I was talking to people
    doing empirical work.
  • 17:08 - 17:10
    I tried to kind of look
    at these specific problems
  • 17:10 - 17:13
    and then try to come up
    with more general problems,
  • 17:15 - 17:18
    reformulating the problems
    at a higher level
  • 17:18 - 17:23
    so that I can think about solutions
    that work in a range of settings.
  • 17:23 - 17:25
    And so from that perspective,
  • 17:25 - 17:28
    the interactions
    with the tech companies
  • 17:28 - 17:30
    are just very valuable
    and very useful.
  • 17:32 - 17:35
    We do have students now
    doing internships there
  • 17:35 - 17:39
    and then coming back
    and writing more interesting theses
  • 17:39 - 17:43
    as a result of
    their experiences there.
  • 17:45 - 17:47
    - [Narrator] If you'd like to watch
    more Nobel Conversations,
  • 17:47 - 17:48
    click here.
  • 17:48 - 17:50
    Or if you'd like to learn
    more about econometrics,
  • 17:50 - 17:53
    check out Josh's
    "Mastering Econometrics" series.
  • 17:54 - 17:57
    If you'd like to learn more
    about Guido, Josh, and Isaiah,
  • 17:57 - 17:58
    check out the links
    in the description.
  • 17:59 - 18:01
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
How Is Econometrics Changing? (Josh Angrist, Guido Imbens, Isaiah Andrews)
ASR Confidence:
0.80
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Duration:
18:03

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions