-
♪ [music] ♪
-
- [Narrator] Welcome
to Nobel Conversations.
-
In this episode,
-
Josh Angrist and Guido Imbens
sit down with Isaiah Andrews
-
to discuss how the field
of econometrics is evolving.
-
- [Isaiah] So Guido and Josh,
you're both pioneers
-
in developing tools for
empirical research in economics.
-
And so I'd like to explore
-
sort of where you feel like
the field is heading,
-
sort of economics, econometrics,
the whole thing.
-
To start, I'd be interested to hear
-
about whether you feel like
sort of the way in which
-
the local average treatment
effects framework sort of took hold
-
has any lessons for how
new empirical methods in economics
-
develop and spread
or how they should.
-
- [Josh] That's a good question.
-
You go first.
-
(laughter)
-
Yeah, so I think
the important thing
-
is to come up
with good convincing cases
-
where the questions are clear
-
and where kind of
the methods apply in general.
-
So one thing I --
-
Kind of looking back
at the subsequent literature,
-
so I really like the regression
discontinuity literature
-
[where there were] clearly a bunch
of really convincing examples
-
and that allowed people to kind of
-
think more clearly, look harder
at the methodological questions.
-
Kind of do clear applications
-
that then allow you
to kind of think about,
-
"Wow, do this type of assumption
seem reasonable here?
-
What kind of things do we not like
in the early papers?
-
How can we improve things?"
-
So having clear applications
motivating these literatures,
-
I think it's very helpful.
-
- [Josh] I'm glad you mentioned
-
the regression
discontinuity, Guido.
-
I think there's a lot of
complementarity between IV and RD,
-
Instrumental Variables and
Regression Discontinuity.
-
And a lot of
the econometric applications
-
of regression discontinuity
-
are what used to be called
"fuzzy" RD,
-
where, you know, it's not discrete
or deterministic at the cutoff,
-
but just the change
in rates or intensity.
-
And the late framework helps us
understand those applications
-
and gives us a clear interpretation
-
for say, something like,
in my paper with Victor Lavy,
-
where we use Maimonides'
rule, the class size cutoffs.
-
What are you getting there?
-
Of course, you can
answer that question
-
with a linear
constant effects model,
-
but it turns out
we're not limited to that,
-
and RD is still very powerful
and illuminating,
-
even when, you know,
-
the correlation between the cutoff
and the variable of interest,
-
in this case class size,
is partial,
-
maybe even not that strong.
-
So there was definitely a kind of,
a parallel development.
-
It's also interesting,
-
you know, nobody talked about
regression discontinuity designs
-
when we were in graduate school,
-
it was something that other social
scientists were interested in,
-
and that kind of grew up
alongside the LATE framework
-
and we've both done work on
both applications and methods there
-
and it's been very exciting
to see that kind of develop
-
and become so important.
-
It's part of a general evolution,
I think, towards, you know,
-
credible identification strategies,
causal effects...
-
less, you know, making econometrics
-
more about causal questions
than about models.
-
In terms of the future,
-
I think one thing that LATE
has helped facilitate
-
is a move towards more creative,
randomized trials, where,
-
you know, there's
something of interest,
-
it's not possible
or straightforward
-
to simply turn it off or on,
-
but you can encourage it
or discourage it.
-
So you subsidize schooling
with financial aid, for example.
-
So now we have a whole
framework for interpreting that,
-
and it kind of opens
the doors to randomized trials
-
of things that maybe would,
you know,
-
not have seem possible before.
-
We've used that a lot in the work
we do on schools in our --
-
in the Blueprint Lab at MIT,
-
we're exploiting random assignment
and in very creative ways, I think.
-
- [Isaiah] Related to that, do you
see sort of particular factors
-
that make for useful research
in econometrics?
-
You've alluded to
it having a clear connection
-
to problems
that are actually coming up
-
and empirical practice
is often a good idea.
-
- [Josh] Isn't it always
a good idea?
-
I often find myself sitting in an
econometrics theory seminar,
-
say the Harvard MIT seminar,
-
and I'm thinking, "What problem
is this guy solving?
-
Who has this problem?"
-
And, you know,
-
sometimes there's an
embarrassing silence if I ask
-
or there might be
a fairly contrived scenario.
-
I want to see
where the tool is useful.
-
There are some
purely foundational tools,
-
I do take the point, you know,
there are people who are
-
working on conceptual
foundations of, you know,
-
it's more -- becomes more like
mathematical statistics.
-
I mean, I remember
an early example of that that I,
-
you know, I struggled to understand
-
was the idea
of stochastic equicontinuity,
-
which one of my thesis advisors,
Whitney Newey,
-
was using to great effect
-
and I was trying to understand that
and there isn't really --
-
It's really foundational, it's not
an application that's driving that,
-
at least not immediately.
-
But most things are not like that
and so there should be a problem.
-
And I think it's on the seller
of that sort of thing,
-
you know, because there's
opportunity cost,
-
the time and attention,
and effort to understand things
-
to, you know,
it's on the seller to say,
-
"Hey, I'm solving this problem
-
and here's a set of results
that show that it's useful,
-
and here's some insight
that I get."
-
- [Isaiah] As you said, Josh, great,
sort of there's been a move
-
in the direction of thinking
more about causality
-
in economics and empirical
work in economics,
-
any consequences of sort of the --
-
the spread of that view
that surprised you
-
or anything that you view
as downsides
-
of sort of the way
that empirical economics has gone?
-
- [Josh] Sometimes I see,
somebody does IV
-
and they get a result
which seems implausibly large.
-
That's the usual case.
-
So it might be, you know,
an extraordinarily large
-
causal effect of some
relatively minor intervention,
-
which was randomized
or for which you could make a case
-
that there's a good design.
-
And then when I see that,
and, you know, I think
-
it's very hard for me to believe
-
that this relatively
minor intervention
-
has such a large effect.
-
The author will sometimes resort
-
to the local average
treatment effects theorem
-
and say, "Well, these compliers,
-
you know, they're
special in some way."
-
And, you know,
they just benefit extraordinarily
-
from this intervention.
-
And I'm reluctant
to take that at face value.
-
I think, you know,
often when effects are too big,
-
it's because the exclusion
restriction is failing,
-
so you don't really have the right
endogenous variable
-
to scale that result.
-
And so I'm not too happy to see
-
you know, just sort of
a generic heterogeneity
-
argument being used
to excuse something
-
that I think might be
a deeper problem.
-
- [Guido] I think it played
somewhat of an unfortunate role
-
when the discussions kind of
between reduced form
-
and structural approaches,
-
where I feel
that wasn't quite right.
-
The instrumental
variables assumptions
-
are at the core - structural
assumptions about behavior -
-
they were coming from economic --
-
thinking about the economic
behavior of agents,
-
and somehow it got
pushed in a direction
-
that I think wasn't
really very helpful.
-
The way I think, initially the --
-
we wrote things up, it was
describing what was happening,
-
there were a set of methods
people were using,
-
we clarified what
those methods were doing
-
and in a way that I think
contain a fair amount of insight,
-
but it somehow
it got pushed into a corner
-
that I don't think
was necessarily very helpful.
-
- [Isaiah] I mean,
just the language
-
of reduced form versus structural
-
I find kind of funny
in the sense that,
-
right, the local average treatment
effect model, right,
-
the potential outcomes model is
a nonparametric structural model,
-
if you want to think about it,
as you sort of suggested, Guido.
-
So there's something a little funny
-
about putting these
two things in oposition when --
-
- [Guido] Yes.
- [Josh] Well, that language,
-
of course, comes from
the [inaudible] equations framework
-
that we inherited.
-
It has the advantage
-
that people seem to know
what you mean when you use it,
-
but might be that people
are hearing different,
-
different people
are hearing different things.
-
- [Guido] Yeah. I think [inaudible]
has sort of become --
-
used in a little bit
of the pejorative way, yeah?
-
- [Josh] Sometimes.
- [Guido] [The word].
-
Which is not really quite what
it was originally intended for.
-
- [Isaiah] I guess something else
that strikes me in thinking about
-
the effects of the local average
treatment effect framework
-
is that often folks will appeal to
-
a local average treatment effects
intuition for settings well beyond
-
ones where any sort
of formal result
-
has actually been established.
-
And I'm curious, given all the work
that you guys did to, you know,
-
establish late results
in different settings,
-
I'm curious, any thoughts on that?
-
- [Guido] I think there's
going to be a lot of cases
-
where the intuition
does get you some distance,
-
but it's going to be
somewhat limited
-
and establishing
formal results there
-
may be a little tricky
-
and then maybe only work
in special circumstances,
-
and you end up
with a lot of formality
-
that may not quite
capture the intuition.
-
Sometimes I'm somewhat
uneasy with them
-
and they are not necessarily
the papers I would want to write,
-
but I do think something --
-
intuition often does capture
part of the problem.
-
I think, in some sense we were
kind of very fortunate there
-
in the way that the late paper
got handled at the journal,
-
is that, actually, the editor,
made it much shorter
-
and that then allowed us to kind of
focus on very clear, crisp results.
-
Where if you -- you know, this
somewhat unfortunate tendency
-
in the econometrics literature
-
of having the papers
get longer and longer.
-
- [Josh] Well, you should
be able to fix that, man.
-
- [Guido] I'm trying to fix that.
-
But I think this is an example
where it's sort of very clear
-
that having it be short
is actually --
-
- [Josh] You should impose
that no paper
-
can be longer than the late paper.
-
- [Guido] That, wow.
-
That may be great.
-
- [Josh] At least no theory,
no theory paper.
-
- [Guido] Yeah,
and I think, I think...
-
I'm trying very hard to get
the papers to be shorter.
-
And I think there's a lot of value
-
today because it's often
the second part of the paper
-
that doesn't actually get you much
further in understanding things
-
and it does make things
much harder to read
-
and, you know,
it sort of goes back
-
to how I think econometrics
should be done,
-
you should focus on --
-
It should be reasonably
close to empirical problems.
-
They should be very clear problems.
-
But then often the theory
doesn't need to be quite so long.
-
- [Josh] Yeah.
-
- [Guido] I think things have gone
a little off track.
-
- [Isaiah] A new relatively
recent change
-
has been a seeming big
increase in demand
-
for people with sort of
econometrics,
-
causal effect estimation skills
in the tech sector.
-
I'm interested,
do either of you have thoughts
-
on sort of how
that's going to interact
-
with the development
of empirical methods,
-
or empirical research
in economics going forward?
-
- [Josh] Well, there's
sort of a meta point,
-
which is, there's this new
kind of employer,
-
the Amazons and the Uber,
and, you know, TripAdvisor world,
-
and I think that's great.
-
And I like to tell my students
about that, you know, especially --
-
at MIT we have a lot of
computer science majors.
-
That's our biggest major.
-
And I try to seduce some of those
folks into economics by saying,
-
you know, you can go
work for these,
-
you know, companies that people
are very keen to work for
-
because the work seems exciting,
-
you know, that the skills
that you get in econometrics
-
are as good or better
-
than any competing
discipline has to offer.
-
So you should at least
-
take some econ, take some
econometrics, and some econ.
-
I did a fun project with Uber
-
on labor supply of Uber drivers
-
and was very, very exciting
to be part of that.
-
Plus I got to drive
for Uber for a while
-
and I thought that was fun too.
-
I did not make enough
that I was tempted to
-
give up my MIT job,
but I enjoyed the experience.
-
I see a potential challenge to our
model of graduate education here,
-
which is, if we're training people
to go work at Amazon, you know,
-
it's not clear why, you know,
we should be paying
-
graduate stipends for that.
-
Why should the taxpayer effectively
be subsidizing that.
-
Our graduate education
in the US Is generously subsidized,
-
even in private universities,
-
it's ultimately -- there's a lot of
public money there,
-
and I think the
traditional rationale for that is,
-
you know, we were training
educators and scholars,
-
and there's a great externality
from the work that we do,
-
it's either
the research externality,
-
or a teaching externality.
-
But, you know,
if many of our students
-
are going to work
in the private sector,
-
that's fine, but maybe their
employers should pay for that.
-
- [Guido] But maybe
is not so different
-
from people working
for consulting firms.
-
It's not clear to me
-
that the number of jobs
in academics has changed.
-
- [Josh] I feel like this
is a growing sector,
-
whereas consulting --
you're right to raise that,
-
it might be the same
for consulting,
-
but this, you know,
-
I'm placing more and more
students in these businesses.
-
So, it's on my mind
in a way that I've sort of,
-
you know, not been attentive
to consulting jobs,
-
you know, consulting
was always important,
-
and I think also
there's some movement
-
from consulting back into research,
it's a little more fluid.
-
A lot of the work in both domains
-
I have to say,
it's not really different
-
but, you know, people who
are working in the tech sector
-
are doing things that are
potentially of scientific interest,
-
but mostly it's hidden.
-
Then you really I have to say,
-
you know, why is the government
paying for this?
-
Yeah, although, yeah,
I mean to Guidos point,
-
I guess there's
a data question here
-
of it has the sort of
total [no-neck] sort of say
-
for-profit sector employment
of econ Ph.D. program graduates
-
increased or has it just been
a substitution from finance
-
and consulting towards tech.
-
- [Josh] I may be reacting
to something
-
that's not really happening.
-
- [Guido] I've actually
done some work
-
with some of these tech companies.
-
I don't disagree with Josh's point
that we need to think
-
a little bit about
the funding model,
-
who is it in the end paying
for the graduate education.
-
But from a scientific perspective,
-
not only do these places
have great data
-
and nowadays they tend to be
very careful with that
-
for privacy reasons,
-
but they also have great questions.
-
I find it very inspiring
kind of to listen
-
to the people there and kind of see
what kind of questions they have,
-
and often they're questions
-
that also come up outside
of these companies.
-
I have a couple of papers
with Raj Chetty and Susan Athey,
-
where we look at ways
of combining experimental data
-
and observational data,
and kind of their --
-
Raj Chetty was interested
in what is the effect
-
of early childhood programs
on outcomes later in life,
-
not just kind on test scores,
but on earnings and stuff,
-
and we kind of developed methods
-
that would help you shed
light on that, onto some --
-
in some settings
and the same problems came up
-
kind of in this
tech company settings.
-
And so from my perspective,
-
it's the same kind of --
-
I was talking to people
doing empirical work,
-
I tried to kind of look at these
specific problems
-
and then try to come up
with more general problems,
-
we formulated the problems
at a higher level,
-
so that I can think about solutions
that work in a range of settings.
-
And so from that perspective,
-
the interactions
with the tech companies
-
are just very valuable
and very useful.
-
We do have students now
doing internships there
-
and then coming back
and writing more interesting thesis
-
as a result of their
experiences there.
-
- [Narrator] If you'd like to watch
more Nobel Conversations,
-
click here,
-
or if you'd like to learn
more about econometrics,
-
check out Josh's
"Mastering Econometrics" series.
-
If you'd like to learn more
about Guido, Josh and Isaiah
-
check out the links
in the description.
-
♪ [music] ♪