< Return to Video

What is the tragedy of the commons? - Nicholas Amendolare

  • 0:08 - 0:12
    Imagine as a thought experiment
    that you live in a small village
  • 0:12 - 0:15
    and depend on
    the local fish pond for food.
  • 0:15 - 0:18
    You share the pond
    with three other villagers.
  • 0:18 - 0:23
    The pond starts off with a dozen fish,
    and the fish reproduce.
  • 0:23 - 0:28
    For every two fish, there will be
    one baby added each night.
  • 0:28 - 0:30
    So, in order to maximize
    your supply of food,
  • 0:30 - 0:34
    how many fish should you catch each day?
  • 0:34 - 0:37
    Take a moment to think about it.
  • 0:37 - 0:40
    Assume baby fish grow
    to full size immediately
  • 0:40 - 0:43
    and that the pond begins at full capacity,
  • 0:43 - 0:47
    and ignore factors
    like the sex of the fish you catch.
  • 0:47 - 0:51
    The answer? One, and it's not just you.
  • 0:51 - 0:54
    The best way to maximize
    every villager's food supply
  • 0:54 - 0:58
    is for each fisherman to take
    just one fish each day.
  • 0:58 - 1:00
    Here's how the math works.
  • 1:00 - 1:05
    If each villager takes one fish,
    there will be eight fish left over night.
  • 1:05 - 1:07
    Each pair of fish produces one baby,
  • 1:07 - 1:12
    and the next day, the pond
    will be fully restocked with twelve fish.
  • 1:12 - 1:17
    If anyone takes more than one,
    the number of reproductive pairs drops,
  • 1:17 - 1:22
    and the population
    won't be able to bounce back.
  • 1:22 - 1:25
    Eventually, the fish in the lake
    will be gone,
  • 1:25 - 1:29
    leaving all four villagers to starve.
  • 1:29 - 1:32
    This fish pond is just one example
    of a classic problem
  • 1:32 - 1:35
    called the tragedy of the commons.
  • 1:35 - 1:38
    The phenomenon was first described
    in a pamphlet
  • 1:38 - 1:42
    by economist
    William Forster Lloyd in 1833
  • 1:42 - 1:45
    in a discussion of
    the overgrazing of cattle
  • 1:45 - 1:48
    on village common areas.
  • 1:48 - 1:53
    More than 100 years later, ecologist
    Garrett Hardin revived the concept
  • 1:53 - 1:55
    to describe what happens
    when many individuals
  • 1:55 - 1:58
    all share a limited resource,
  • 1:58 - 2:00
    like grazing land,
  • 2:00 - 2:01
    fishing areas,
  • 2:01 - 2:02
    living space,
  • 2:02 - 2:04
    even clean air.
  • 2:04 - 2:08
    Hardin argued that these situations
    pit short-term self-interest
  • 2:08 - 2:10
    against the common good,
  • 2:10 - 2:13
    and they end badly for everyone,
  • 2:13 - 2:14
    resulting in overgrazing,
  • 2:14 - 2:15
    overfishing,
  • 2:15 - 2:16
    overpopulation,
  • 2:16 - 2:18
    pollution,
  • 2:18 - 2:21
    and other social
    and environmental problems.
  • 2:21 - 2:23
    The key feature of
    a tragedy of the commons
  • 2:23 - 2:29
    is that it provides an opportunity for
    an individual to benefit him or herself
  • 2:29 - 2:34
    while spreading out any negative effects
    across the larger population.
  • 2:34 - 2:37
    To see what that means,
    let's revisit our fish pond.
  • 2:37 - 2:40
    Each individual fisherman is motivated
  • 2:40 - 2:43
    to take as many fish
    as he can for himself.
  • 2:43 - 2:46
    Meanwhile, any decline
    in fish reproduction
  • 2:46 - 2:49
    is shared by the entire village.
  • 2:49 - 2:51
    Anxious to avoid
    losing out to his neighbors,
  • 2:51 - 2:56
    a fisherman will conclude that it's in his
    best interest to take an extra fish,
  • 2:56 - 2:57
    or two,
  • 2:57 - 2:59
    or three.
  • 2:59 - 3:03
    Unfortunately, this is the same conclusion
    reached by the other fisherman,
  • 3:03 - 3:04
    and that's the tragedy.
  • 3:04 - 3:10
    Optimizing for the self in the short term
    isn't optimal for anyone in the long term.
  • 3:10 - 3:13
    That's a simplified example,
    but the tragedy of the commons
  • 3:13 - 3:18
    plays out in the more complex systems
    of real life, too.
  • 3:18 - 3:23
    The overuse of antibiotics has led to
    short-term gains in livestock production
  • 3:23 - 3:25
    and in treating common illnesses,
  • 3:25 - 3:30
    but it's also resulted in the evolution
    of antibiotic-resistant bacteria,
  • 3:30 - 3:33
    which threaten the entire population.
  • 3:33 - 3:36
    A coal-fired power plant produces
    cheap electricity for its customers
  • 3:36 - 3:39
    and profits for its owners.
  • 3:39 - 3:41
    These local benefits are helpful
    in the short term,
  • 3:41 - 3:47
    but pollution from mining and burning coal
    is spread across the entire atmosphere
  • 3:47 - 3:50
    and sticks around for thousands of years.
  • 3:50 - 3:52
    There are other examples, too.
  • 3:52 - 3:53
    Littering,
  • 3:53 - 3:54
    water shortages,
  • 3:54 - 3:55
    deforestation,
  • 3:55 - 3:57
    traffic jams,
  • 3:57 - 4:00
    even the purchase of bottled water.
  • 4:00 - 4:05
    But human civilization has proven it's
    capable of doing something remarkable.
  • 4:05 - 4:07
    We form social contracts,
  • 4:07 - 4:09
    we make communal agreements,
  • 4:09 - 4:10
    we elect governments,
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    and we pass laws.
  • 4:12 - 4:18
    All this to save our collective selves
    from our own individual impulses.
  • 4:18 - 4:22
    It isn't easy, and we certainly
    don't get it right nearly all of the time.
  • 4:22 - 4:27
    But humans at our best have shown
    that we can solve these problems
  • 4:27 - 4:31
    and we can continue to do so
    if we remember Hardin's lesson.
  • 4:31 - 4:34
    When the tragedy of the commons applies,
  • 4:34 - 4:37
    what's good for all of us
    is good for each of us.
Title:
What is the tragedy of the commons? - Nicholas Amendolare
Description:

View full lesson: https://ed.ted.com/lessons/what-is-the-tragedy-of-the-commons-nicholas-amendolare

Is it possible that overfishing, super germs, and global warming are all caused by the same thing? In 1968, a man named Garrett Hardin sat down to write an essay about overpopulation. Within it, he discovered a pattern of human behavior that explains some of history’s biggest problems. Nicholas Amendolare describes the tragedy of the commons.

Lesson by Nicholas Amendolare, directed by TED-Ed.

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
closed TED
Project:
TED-Ed
Duration:
04:58

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions