-
Imagine as a thought experiment
that you live in a small village
-
and depend on
the local fish pond for food.
-
You share the pond
with three other villagers.
-
The pond starts off with a dozen fish
and the fish reproduce.
-
For every two fish, there will be
one baby added each night.
-
So, in order to maximize
your supply of food,
-
how many fish should you catch each day?
-
Take a moment to think about it.
-
Assume baby fish grow
to full size immediately,
-
and that the pond begins at full capacity,
-
and ignore factors
like the sex of the fish you catch.
-
The answer? One, and it's not just you.
-
The best way to maximize
every villager's food supply
-
is for each fisherman to take
just one fish each day.
-
Here's how the math works.
-
If each villager takes one fish,
there will be eight fish left over night.
-
Each pair of fish produces one baby,
-
and the next day, the pond
will be fully restocked with twelve fish.
-
If anyone takes more than one,
the number of reproductive pairs drops
-
and the population
won't be able to bounce back.
-
Eventually, the fish in the lake
will be gone,
-
leaving all four villagers to starve.
-
This fish pond is just one example
of a classic problem
-
called the tragedy of the commons.
-
The phenomenon was first described
in a pamphlet
-
by economist
William Forster Lloyd in 1833
-
in a discussion of
the overgrazing of cattle
-
on village common areas.
-
More than 100 years later, ecologist
Garrett Hardin revived the concept
-
to describe what happens
when many individuals
-
all share a limited resource,
-
like grazing land,
-
fishing areas,
-
living space,
-
even clean air.
-
Hardin argued that these situations
pit short-term self-interest
-
against the common good,
-
and they end badly for everyone,
-
resulting in overgrazing,
-
overfishing,
-
overpopulation,
-
pollution,
-
and other social
and environmental problems.
-
The key feature of
a tragedy of the commons
-
is that it provides an opportunity for
an individual to benefit him or herself
-
while spreading out any negative effects
across the larger population.
-
To see what that means,
let's revisit our fish pond.
-
Each individual fisherman is motivated
-
to take as many fish
as he can for himself.
-
Meanwhile, any decline
in fish reproduction
-
is shared by the entire village.
-
Anxious to avoid
losing out to his neighbors,
-
a fisherman will conclude that it's in his
best interest to take an extra fish,
-
or two,
-
or three.
-
Unfortunately, this is the same conclusion
reached by the other fisherman,
-
and that's the tragedy.
-
Optimizing for the self in the short term
isn't optimal for anyone in the long term.
-
That's a simplified example,
but the tragedy of the commons
-
plays out in the more complex systems
of real life, too.
-
The overuse of antibiotics has led to
short-term gains in livestock production
-
and in treating common illnesses,
-
but it's also resulted in the evolution
of antibiotic-resistant bacteria,
-
which threaten the entire population.
-
A coal-fired power plant produces
cheap electricity for its customers
-
and profits for its owners.
-
These local benefits are helpful
in the short term,
-
but pollution from mining and burning coal
is spread across the entire atmosphere
-
and sticks around for thousands of years.
-
There are other examples, too.
-
Littering,
-
water shortages,
-
deforestation,
-
traffic jams,
-
even the purchase of bottled water.
-
But human civilization has proven it's
capable of doing something remarkable.
-
We form social contracts,
-
we make communal agreements,
-
we elect governments,
-
and we pass laws.
-
All this to save our collective selves
from our own individual impulses.
-
It isn't easy, and we certainly
don't get it right nearly all of the time.
-
But humans at our best have shown
that we can solve these problems
-
and we can continue to do so
if we remember Hartin's lesson.
-
When the tragedy of the commons applies,
-
what's good for all of us
is good for each of us.