Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss
-
0:02 - 0:05♪ [music] ♪
-
0:08 - 0:14- So far in our videos, we've looked at
the effect of taxes on market prices, but -
0:14 - 0:19we haven't said much about why government
levies taxes in the first place, namely to -
0:19 - 0:25get revenues. So let's look at that and
also the cost of raising revenues, which -
0:25 - 0:26is deadweight loss.
-
0:31 - 0:33We can show pretty much
everything we need to show with a -
0:33 - 0:39single diagram. So here is our initial
equilibrium. The price with no tax is $2 -
0:39 - 0:46and the quantity exchanged with no tax is
700 units. Now, let's recall that consumer -
0:46 - 0:52surplus is the consumer's gain from
exchange, and it's this green area here, -
0:52 - 0:58the area underneath the demand curve and
above the price, up to the quantity -
0:58 - 1:03exchanged. So it's the area above the
price of $2 and up to the quantity -
1:03 - 1:09exchange of 700 below the demand curve,
this area right here. Producer surplus is -
1:09 - 1:13the producer's gain from exchange, and is
the area above the supply curve, up to the -
1:14 - 1:19quantity exchanged and below the price,
below the producer's price. Now, you may -
1:19 - 1:26also recall that a free market maximizes
consumer plus producer surplus. What we're -
1:26 - 1:30going to show is that when we have a tax,
this is no longer true. The intervention -
1:30 - 1:35into the free market means that consumer
and producer surplus are not maximized. -
1:35 - 1:42Let's take a look. So suppose we have tax
of $1, and using our wedge method, we can -
1:43 - 1:48find what the new price is going to be for
the buyers. It's going to be here. So the -
1:48 - 1:53new price for the buyer is say, $2.50.
Notice now, the consumer surplus is not -
1:54 - 1:59this large green area since the price is
now higher and the quantity exchanged has -
2:00 - 2:04fallen.
The quantity exchanged falls from 700 -
2:04 - 2:12units to 500 units. So the consumer
surplus with the tax is this smaller green -
2:12 - 2:18area here. Again, it's the area above the
buyer's price, up to the quantity -
2:18 - 2:24exchanged, and below the demand. So
exactly the definition hasn't changed, but -
2:24 - 2:29because of the tax, the price of the buyer
changes, and the quantity demanded -
2:29 - 2:33exchanges, so the consumer surplus changes
as well. In this case, it gets a lot -
2:33 - 2:39smaller. What about producer surplus?
Well, again, the price which the sellers -
2:39 - 2:45receive falls. So producer surplus is no
longer this large blue area, but is now -
2:45 - 2:52just this much smaller blue area. So the
tax reduces consumer surplus and it -
2:52 - 2:57reduces producer surplus. Now, what about
this area in the middle? Well, -
2:57 - 3:02fortunately, that's not wasted. That, in
fact, is tax revenues. So notice that the -
3:02 - 3:09tax, the height of the tax here is $1 and
there are 500 units exchanged, so the -
3:10 - 3:16government gets $1 for each of those 500
units. So this revenue, tax revenue is the -
3:16 - 3:23area. It's the height of this box times
the width, and the height is the tax, the -
3:23 - 3:28width is the quantity exchanged. So this
is tax revenue. Now, what about this final -
3:28 - 3:34bit over here? That used to be consumer
and producer surplus, but now it's -
3:34 - 3:42deadweight loss. Nobody gets that. That is
lost gains from trade. So remember, people -
3:42 - 3:49used to trade 700 units, now they're only
trading 500 units. Those units were -
3:49 - 3:55benefiting people, but they're not anymore
because these trades are not occurring. -
3:55 - 3:59I'm going to explain that in a little bit
more detail in the next slide. For now, -
3:59 - 4:04just be sure that you understand how to
label these areas. -
4:04 - 4:10So this is the new consumer surplus, tax
revenues, the new producer surplus, and -
4:10 - 4:15this area is deadweight loss. Okay, let's
explain deadweight loss in a little bit -
4:16 - 4:20more detail. Here's the way to think about
deadweight loss. Suppose that you're -
4:20 - 4:24planning a trip to New York and you're
going to take the bus. The benefit of the -
4:24 - 4:28trip to you, the value of seeing the
sights in New York is $50, the cost of the -
4:29 - 4:30bus ticket is $40.
-
4:30 - 4:34So do you take the trip?
Is it a value? Yes, you take the trip. The -
4:34 - 4:39total value of the trip is $10, it's a
positive, so you decide to take the trip. -
4:40 - 4:44Trips is equal to one. You make the trip.
Okay, no problem. Now, suppose there's a -
4:44 - 4:52tax of $20 on bus fares and let's suppose
that raises the cost of the trip from $40 -
4:52 - 4:58to $60. It doesn't have to raise it by
exactly that amount, by exactly the $20, -
4:58 - 5:04but let's suppose it does. Okay, so the
cost of the trip is now $60. The benefit -
5:04 - 5:12is still $50. So do you take the trip? No.
The benefit is less than the cost. So now, -
5:12 - 5:20no trip. Trips are equal to zero. Does the
government raise any revenue from you? No. -
5:20 - 5:25Since you don't take the trip, the
government makes no revenue. Is there a -
5:25 - 5:31deadweight loss? Yes. You have lost the
value of the trip. You used to, when there -
5:32 - 5:36was no tax, you took the trip, it was
worth $10, so the world was better off by -
5:36 - 5:42that $10 of value. Now with the tax, you
don't take the trip, so that $10 is a -
5:43 - 5:50deadweight loss. It's gone. And notice
that it's not made up for by revenue. -
5:50 - 5:59There's no revenue. So deadweight loss is
the value of the trips not made because of -
5:59 - 6:03the tax, and there's no revenue on trips
which aren't made. -
6:03 - 6:08Government only makes revenue on the trips
which continue to occur. So deadweight -
6:08 - 6:14loss is the value of the trips not made
because of the tax. Now, to return this to -
6:14 - 6:20a more general case, instead of trips,
let's just replace that with trades. -
6:20 - 6:27Deadweight loss is the value of the trades
not made because of the tax. Very quickly, -
6:27 - 6:33here's our diagram again. Before the tax,
there were 700 trades. After the tax, -
6:33 - 6:40there were 500 trades. So these are the
200 trades which are not made because of -
6:41 - 6:47the tax. And the value of those 200 trades
occurs because for these trades, the -
6:47 - 6:55demanders value them more than it costs
the suppliers to provide those trades. So -
6:55 - 6:59the demanders value the trades as given by
the demand curve, the height of the demand -
6:59 - 7:05curve, the suppliers are willing to supply
those trades, the cost to them is given by -
7:05 - 7:12the height of the supply curve, so the
value, the value minus the cost, if you -
7:12 - 7:19like, is given by this triangle. Because
those trades no longer occur, that value -
7:20 - 7:25is no longer produced, that's deadweight
loss, the value of the trades which don't -
7:25 - 7:30occur because of the tax. Here's one more
important point about deadweight loss. -
7:30 - 7:35Deadweight losses are larger the more
elastic the demand curve holding revenues -
7:35 - 7:41constant. So for example, which of these
goods would we more like to tax, the one -
7:42 - 7:46on the left where the demand curve is
elastic or the one on the right where the -
7:47 - 7:52demand curve is more inelastic? Notice
that tax revenues are the same. So if we -
7:52 - 7:57have a choice, which good do we wanna tax?
Well, pretty clearly, we wanna tax the -
7:57 - 8:02good with the inelastic demand because the
deadweight losses, the lost gains from -
8:02 - 8:06trade, are much smaller over here than
they are over here. -
8:06 - 8:12So the tax on the good with the elastic
demand, it's creating a lot of waste in -
8:12 - 8:17order to get this revenue. Over here, the
tax on the good with the inelastic demand, -
8:17 - 8:22there's only a little bit of waste for the
same amount of revenue. The intuition here -
8:22 - 8:29is pretty simple. If the demand curve is
inelastic, then a tax won't deter many -
8:29 - 8:33trades. And that's what we don't want. We
don't want to deter a lot of trades -
8:34 - 8:41because it's the lost gains from trade
which create the problem. We don't get any -
8:41 - 8:48tax revenue when we deter a trade. There's
no tax revenue when you deter an exchange. -
8:48 - 8:53So we want to make sure that we deter as
few exchanges as possible and that will -
8:53 - 8:59maximize our revenue compared to our loss.
Now, sometimes economists are laughed at -
8:59 - 9:03or derided because this implies, for
example, that you ought to tax insulin, a -
9:04 - 9:09good with a very inelastic demand. Now,
there are many reasons for taxing some -
9:09 - 9:13goods and not other goods, depending upon
who uses the insulin, whether it's poor -
9:13 - 9:20people or rich people or how important
health is and so forth. Nevertheless, as a -
9:20 - 9:25general rule, it is better to tax goods
with an inelastic demand than goods with -
9:26 - 9:31an elastic demand. That's important, and
let me give you an illustration of that. -
9:31 - 9:34Here's something which you might think
would be a good idea to tax, luxury -
9:34 - 9:38yachts. They're only bought by the rich,
so you're not really harming people very -
9:38 - 9:44much, right? Well, maybe so. However, in
1990, the federal government actually -
9:45 - 9:50applied a 10% luxury tax to many luxury
goods, including pleasure boats or yachts -
9:50 - 9:57with a sales price above $100,000, the
expected tax revenue of $31 million. The -
9:57 - 10:02reality, however, was quite different. The
tax revenues were only $16.6 million. -
10:02 - 10:08That was because sales of yachts fell
tremendously. Perhaps the yacht buyers -
10:08 - 10:12decided, well, they could wait a year or
two before buying their yacht, see what -
10:12 - 10:16happens, or maybe they decided they could
buy their yachts in other countries. -
10:16 - 10:20Yachts are pretty easy to move around the
world. After all, that's what they're for. -
10:21 - 10:27The net result, in fact, was a loss of
7,000 jobs in the yacht industry. Indeed, -
10:28 - 10:32the federal government ended up paying
out more in unemployment benefits to -
10:32 - 10:40unemployed yacht workers than it collected
in tax revenues from yachts. Because of -
10:40 - 10:46this, the federal tax was repealed in
1993. The lesson here, don't tax goods -
10:46 - 10:50which have really elastic demands.
You're not going to get a lot of revenue, -
10:50 - 10:54you're going to deter a lot of trades, and
that will create a lot of deadweight loss, -
10:55 - 10:59and perhaps, secondary losses for other
people, such as the workers. That's it -
10:59 - 11:04actually for taxes. The only thing we have
left to do is subsidies. We can actually -
11:05 - 11:09do that in the next lecture pretty quickly
because subsidies are just negative taxes. -
11:09 - 11:14So everything we've said about taxes, with
just a few changes to our language, will -
11:14 - 11:17go through with subsidies as well. Thanks.
-
11:17 - 11:23- If you want to test yourself, click
Practice Questions. Or if you're ready -
11:23 - 11:26to move on, just click Next Video.
-
11:26 - 11:28♪ [music] ♪
- Title:
- Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss
- Description:
-
Why do taxes exist? What are the effects of taxes? We discuss how taxes affect consumer surplus and producer surplus and discuss the concept of deadweight loss at length. We’ll also look at a real-world example of deadweight loss: taxing luxury yachts in the 1990s.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics
Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/deadweight-loss-definition-yacht-tax#QandA
Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/subsidies-definition-subsidy-wedge
- Video Language:
- English
- Team:
- Marginal Revolution University
- Project:
- Micro
- Duration:
- 11:31
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss |