< Return to Video

Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss

  • 0:02 - 0:05
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:08 - 0:14
    - So far in our videos, we've looked at
    the effect of taxes on market prices, but
  • 0:14 - 0:19
    we haven't said much about why government
    levies taxes in the first place, namely to
  • 0:19 - 0:25
    get revenues. So let's look at that and
    also the cost of raising revenues, which
  • 0:25 - 0:26
    is deadweight loss.
  • 0:31 - 0:33
    We can show pretty much
    everything we need to show with a
  • 0:33 - 0:39
    single diagram. So here is our initial
    equilibrium. The price with no tax is $2
  • 0:39 - 0:46
    and the quantity exchanged with no tax is
    700 units. Now, let's recall that consumer
  • 0:46 - 0:52
    surplus is the consumer's gain from
    exchange, and it's this green area here,
  • 0:52 - 0:58
    the area underneath the demand curve and
    above the price, up to the quantity
  • 0:58 - 1:03
    exchanged. So it's the area above the
    price of $2 and up to the quantity
  • 1:03 - 1:09
    exchange of 700 below the demand curve,
    this area right here. Producer surplus is
  • 1:09 - 1:13
    the producer's gain from exchange, and is
    the area above the supply curve, up to the
  • 1:14 - 1:19
    quantity exchanged and below the price,
    below the producer's price. Now, you may
  • 1:19 - 1:26
    also recall that a free market maximizes
    consumer plus producer surplus. What we're
  • 1:26 - 1:30
    going to show is that when we have a tax,
    this is no longer true. The intervention
  • 1:30 - 1:35
    into the free market means that consumer
    and producer surplus are not maximized.
  • 1:35 - 1:42
    Let's take a look. So suppose we have tax
    of $1, and using our wedge method, we can
  • 1:43 - 1:48
    find what the new price is going to be for
    the buyers. It's going to be here. So the
  • 1:48 - 1:53
    new price for the buyer is say, $2.50.
    Notice now, the consumer surplus is not
  • 1:54 - 1:59
    this large green area since the price is
    now higher and the quantity exchanged has
  • 2:00 - 2:04
    fallen.
    The quantity exchanged falls from 700
  • 2:04 - 2:12
    units to 500 units. So the consumer
    surplus with the tax is this smaller green
  • 2:12 - 2:18
    area here. Again, it's the area above the
    buyer's price, up to the quantity
  • 2:18 - 2:24
    exchanged, and below the demand. So
    exactly the definition hasn't changed, but
  • 2:24 - 2:29
    because of the tax, the price of the buyer
    changes, and the quantity demanded
  • 2:29 - 2:33
    exchanges, so the consumer surplus changes
    as well. In this case, it gets a lot
  • 2:33 - 2:39
    smaller. What about producer surplus?
    Well, again, the price which the sellers
  • 2:39 - 2:45
    receive falls. So producer surplus is no
    longer this large blue area, but is now
  • 2:45 - 2:52
    just this much smaller blue area. So the
    tax reduces consumer surplus and it
  • 2:52 - 2:57
    reduces producer surplus. Now, what about
    this area in the middle? Well,
  • 2:57 - 3:02
    fortunately, that's not wasted. That, in
    fact, is tax revenues. So notice that the
  • 3:02 - 3:09
    tax, the height of the tax here is $1 and
    there are 500 units exchanged, so the
  • 3:10 - 3:16
    government gets $1 for each of those 500
    units. So this revenue, tax revenue is the
  • 3:16 - 3:23
    area. It's the height of this box times
    the width, and the height is the tax, the
  • 3:23 - 3:28
    width is the quantity exchanged. So this
    is tax revenue. Now, what about this final
  • 3:28 - 3:34
    bit over here? That used to be consumer
    and producer surplus, but now it's
  • 3:34 - 3:42
    deadweight loss. Nobody gets that. That is
    lost gains from trade. So remember, people
  • 3:42 - 3:49
    used to trade 700 units, now they're only
    trading 500 units. Those units were
  • 3:49 - 3:55
    benefiting people, but they're not anymore
    because these trades are not occurring.
  • 3:55 - 3:59
    I'm going to explain that in a little bit
    more detail in the next slide. For now,
  • 3:59 - 4:04
    just be sure that you understand how to
    label these areas.
  • 4:04 - 4:10
    So this is the new consumer surplus, tax
    revenues, the new producer surplus, and
  • 4:10 - 4:15
    this area is deadweight loss. Okay, let's
    explain deadweight loss in a little bit
  • 4:16 - 4:20
    more detail. Here's the way to think about
    deadweight loss. Suppose that you're
  • 4:20 - 4:24
    planning a trip to New York and you're
    going to take the bus. The benefit of the
  • 4:24 - 4:28
    trip to you, the value of seeing the
    sights in New York is $50, the cost of the
  • 4:29 - 4:30
    bus ticket is $40.
  • 4:30 - 4:34
    So do you take the trip?
    Is it a value? Yes, you take the trip. The
  • 4:34 - 4:39
    total value of the trip is $10, it's a
    positive, so you decide to take the trip.
  • 4:40 - 4:44
    Trips is equal to one. You make the trip.
    Okay, no problem. Now, suppose there's a
  • 4:44 - 4:52
    tax of $20 on bus fares and let's suppose
    that raises the cost of the trip from $40
  • 4:52 - 4:58
    to $60. It doesn't have to raise it by
    exactly that amount, by exactly the $20,
  • 4:58 - 5:04
    but let's suppose it does. Okay, so the
    cost of the trip is now $60. The benefit
  • 5:04 - 5:12
    is still $50. So do you take the trip? No.
    The benefit is less than the cost. So now,
  • 5:12 - 5:20
    no trip. Trips are equal to zero. Does the
    government raise any revenue from you? No.
  • 5:20 - 5:25
    Since you don't take the trip, the
    government makes no revenue. Is there a
  • 5:25 - 5:31
    deadweight loss? Yes. You have lost the
    value of the trip. You used to, when there
  • 5:32 - 5:36
    was no tax, you took the trip, it was
    worth $10, so the world was better off by
  • 5:36 - 5:42
    that $10 of value. Now with the tax, you
    don't take the trip, so that $10 is a
  • 5:43 - 5:50
    deadweight loss. It's gone. And notice
    that it's not made up for by revenue.
  • 5:50 - 5:59
    There's no revenue. So deadweight loss is
    the value of the trips not made because of
  • 5:59 - 6:03
    the tax, and there's no revenue on trips
    which aren't made.
  • 6:03 - 6:08
    Government only makes revenue on the trips
    which continue to occur. So deadweight
  • 6:08 - 6:14
    loss is the value of the trips not made
    because of the tax. Now, to return this to
  • 6:14 - 6:20
    a more general case, instead of trips,
    let's just replace that with trades.
  • 6:20 - 6:27
    Deadweight loss is the value of the trades
    not made because of the tax. Very quickly,
  • 6:27 - 6:33
    here's our diagram again. Before the tax,
    there were 700 trades. After the tax,
  • 6:33 - 6:40
    there were 500 trades. So these are the
    200 trades which are not made because of
  • 6:41 - 6:47
    the tax. And the value of those 200 trades
    occurs because for these trades, the
  • 6:47 - 6:55
    demanders value them more than it costs
    the suppliers to provide those trades. So
  • 6:55 - 6:59
    the demanders value the trades as given by
    the demand curve, the height of the demand
  • 6:59 - 7:05
    curve, the suppliers are willing to supply
    those trades, the cost to them is given by
  • 7:05 - 7:12
    the height of the supply curve, so the
    value, the value minus the cost, if you
  • 7:12 - 7:19
    like, is given by this triangle. Because
    those trades no longer occur, that value
  • 7:20 - 7:25
    is no longer produced, that's deadweight
    loss, the value of the trades which don't
  • 7:25 - 7:30
    occur because of the tax. Here's one more
    important point about deadweight loss.
  • 7:30 - 7:35
    Deadweight losses are larger the more
    elastic the demand curve holding revenues
  • 7:35 - 7:41
    constant. So for example, which of these
    goods would we more like to tax, the one
  • 7:42 - 7:46
    on the left where the demand curve is
    elastic or the one on the right where the
  • 7:47 - 7:52
    demand curve is more inelastic? Notice
    that tax revenues are the same. So if we
  • 7:52 - 7:57
    have a choice, which good do we wanna tax?
    Well, pretty clearly, we wanna tax the
  • 7:57 - 8:02
    good with the inelastic demand because the
    deadweight losses, the lost gains from
  • 8:02 - 8:06
    trade, are much smaller over here than
    they are over here.
  • 8:06 - 8:12
    So the tax on the good with the elastic
    demand, it's creating a lot of waste in
  • 8:12 - 8:17
    order to get this revenue. Over here, the
    tax on the good with the inelastic demand,
  • 8:17 - 8:22
    there's only a little bit of waste for the
    same amount of revenue. The intuition here
  • 8:22 - 8:29
    is pretty simple. If the demand curve is
    inelastic, then a tax won't deter many
  • 8:29 - 8:33
    trades. And that's what we don't want. We
    don't want to deter a lot of trades
  • 8:34 - 8:41
    because it's the lost gains from trade
    which create the problem. We don't get any
  • 8:41 - 8:48
    tax revenue when we deter a trade. There's
    no tax revenue when you deter an exchange.
  • 8:48 - 8:53
    So we want to make sure that we deter as
    few exchanges as possible and that will
  • 8:53 - 8:59
    maximize our revenue compared to our loss.
    Now, sometimes economists are laughed at
  • 8:59 - 9:03
    or derided because this implies, for
    example, that you ought to tax insulin, a
  • 9:04 - 9:09
    good with a very inelastic demand. Now,
    there are many reasons for taxing some
  • 9:09 - 9:13
    goods and not other goods, depending upon
    who uses the insulin, whether it's poor
  • 9:13 - 9:20
    people or rich people or how important
    health is and so forth. Nevertheless, as a
  • 9:20 - 9:25
    general rule, it is better to tax goods
    with an inelastic demand than goods with
  • 9:26 - 9:31
    an elastic demand. That's important, and
    let me give you an illustration of that.
  • 9:31 - 9:34
    Here's something which you might think
    would be a good idea to tax, luxury
  • 9:34 - 9:38
    yachts. They're only bought by the rich,
    so you're not really harming people very
  • 9:38 - 9:44
    much, right? Well, maybe so. However, in
    1990, the federal government actually
  • 9:45 - 9:50
    applied a 10% luxury tax to many luxury
    goods, including pleasure boats or yachts
  • 9:50 - 9:57
    with a sales price above $100,000, the
    expected tax revenue of $31 million. The
  • 9:57 - 10:02
    reality, however, was quite different. The
    tax revenues were only $16.6 million.
  • 10:02 - 10:08
    That was because sales of yachts fell
    tremendously. Perhaps the yacht buyers
  • 10:08 - 10:12
    decided, well, they could wait a year or
    two before buying their yacht, see what
  • 10:12 - 10:16
    happens, or maybe they decided they could
    buy their yachts in other countries.
  • 10:16 - 10:20
    Yachts are pretty easy to move around the
    world. After all, that's what they're for.
  • 10:21 - 10:27
    The net result, in fact, was a loss of
    7,000 jobs in the yacht industry. Indeed,
  • 10:28 - 10:32
    the federal government ended up paying
    out more in unemployment benefits to
  • 10:32 - 10:40
    unemployed yacht workers than it collected
    in tax revenues from yachts. Because of
  • 10:40 - 10:46
    this, the federal tax was repealed in
    1993. The lesson here, don't tax goods
  • 10:46 - 10:50
    which have really elastic demands.
    You're not going to get a lot of revenue,
  • 10:50 - 10:54
    you're going to deter a lot of trades, and
    that will create a lot of deadweight loss,
  • 10:55 - 10:59
    and perhaps, secondary losses for other
    people, such as the workers. That's it
  • 10:59 - 11:04
    actually for taxes. The only thing we have
    left to do is subsidies. We can actually
  • 11:05 - 11:09
    do that in the next lecture pretty quickly
    because subsidies are just negative taxes.
  • 11:09 - 11:14
    So everything we've said about taxes, with
    just a few changes to our language, will
  • 11:14 - 11:17
    go through with subsidies as well. Thanks.
  • 11:17 - 11:23
    - If you want to test yourself, click
    Practice Questions. Or if you're ready
  • 11:23 - 11:26
    to move on, just click Next Video.
  • 11:26 - 11:28
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss
Description:

Why do taxes exist? What are the effects of taxes? We discuss how taxes affect consumer surplus and producer surplus and discuss the concept of deadweight loss at length. We’ll also look at a real-world example of deadweight loss: taxing luxury yachts in the 1990s.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/deadweight-loss-definition-yacht-tax#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/subsidies-definition-subsidy-wedge

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
11:31

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions