< Return to Video

Keynesian cross and the multiplier | Macroeconomics | Khan Academy

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    In the last video, we saw
    how the Keynesian Cross
  • 0:03 - 0:06
    could help us visualize an increase in
  • 0:06 - 0:08
    government spending
    which was a shift in our
  • 0:08 - 0:11
    aggregate planned expenditure
    line right over here
  • 0:11 - 0:14
    and we saw how the
    actual change, the actual
  • 0:14 - 0:18
    increase in output if you take all the
  • 0:18 - 0:20
    assumptions that we
    took in this, the actual
  • 0:20 - 0:23
    change in output and
    aggregate income was larger
  • 0:23 - 0:26
    than the change in government spending.
  • 0:26 - 0:29
    You might say okay,
    Keynesian thinking, this
  • 0:29 - 0:30
    is very left wing, this is the
  • 0:30 - 0:32
    government's growing larger right here.
  • 0:32 - 0:35
    I'm more conservative.
    I'm not a believer in
  • 0:35 - 0:36
    Keynesian thinking.
  • 0:36 - 0:38
    The reality is you actually might be.
  • 0:38 - 0:40
    Whether you're on the right or the left,
  • 0:40 - 0:41
    although Keynesian economics tends to be
  • 0:41 - 0:44
    poo-pooed more by the
    right and embraced more
  • 0:44 - 0:50
    by the left, most of the
    mainstream right policies,
  • 0:50 - 0:52
    especially in the US,
    have actually been very
  • 0:52 - 0:53
    Keynesian.
  • 0:53 - 0:54
    They just haven't been
    by manipulating this
  • 0:54 - 0:56
    variable right over here.
  • 0:56 - 0:58
    For example, when people
    talk about expanding
  • 0:58 - 1:01
    the economy by lowering taxes, they are a
  • 1:01 - 1:04
    Keynesian when they say
    that because if we were
  • 1:04 - 1:06
    to rewind and we go back to our original
  • 1:06 - 1:09
    function so if we don't
    do this, if we go back to
  • 1:09 - 1:16
    just having our G here,
    we're now back on this
  • 1:16 - 1:18
    orange line, our original
    planned expenditure,
  • 1:18 - 1:21
    you could, based on this
    model right over here,
  • 1:21 - 1:24
    also shift it up by lowering taxes.
  • 1:24 - 1:30
    If you change your taxes to be taxes minus
  • 1:30 - 1:33
    some delta in taxes, the
    reason why this is going
  • 1:33 - 1:35
    to shift the whole curve
    up is because you're
  • 1:35 - 1:39
    multiplying this whole thing by a negative
  • 1:39 - 1:42
    number, by negative C1.
  • 1:42 - 1:44
    C1, your marginal
    propensity to consume, we're
  • 1:44 - 1:45
    assuming is positive.
  • 1:45 - 1:47
    There's a negative out here.
  • 1:47 - 1:49
    When you multiply it
    by a negative, when you
  • 1:49 - 1:52
    multiply a decrease by
    a negative, this is a
  • 1:52 - 1:56
    negative change in taxes,
    then this whole thing
  • 1:56 - 1:58
    is going to shift up again.
  • 1:58 - 2:00
    You would actually shift up.
  • 2:00 - 2:03
    You would actually shift
    up in this case and
  • 2:03 - 2:05
    depending on what the
    actual magnitude of the
  • 2:05 - 2:08
    change in taxes are,
    but you would actually
  • 2:08 - 2:11
    shift up and the amount
    that you would shift up -
  • 2:11 - 2:12
    I don't want to make my graph to messy so
  • 2:12 - 2:16
    this is our new aggregate
    planned expenditures -
  • 2:16 - 2:19
    but the amount you
    would move up is by this
  • 2:19 - 2:25
    coefficient down here, C1, -C1 x -delta T.
  • 2:25 - 2:27
    You're change, the amount
    that you would move up,
  • 2:27 - 2:33
    is -C1 x -delta T, if we assume delta T is
  • 2:33 - 2:38
    positive and so you
    actually have a C1, delta T.
  • 2:38 - 2:40
    The negatives cancel out
    so that's actually how
  • 2:40 - 2:42
    much it would actually move up.
  • 2:42 - 2:44
    It's also Keynesian when you say if we
  • 2:44 - 2:46
    increase taxes that will
    lower aggregate output
  • 2:46 - 2:51
    because if you increase
    taxes, now all of a
  • 2:51 - 2:55
    sudden this is a positive,
    this is a positive
  • 2:55 - 2:56
    and then you would shift the curve by that
  • 2:56 - 2:57
    much.
  • 2:57 - 3:00
    You would actually
    shift the curve down and
  • 3:00 - 3:06
    then you would get to a
    lower equilibrium GDP.
  • 3:06 - 3:09
    This really isn't a difference between
  • 3:09 - 3:13
    right leaning fiscal
    policy or left leaning
  • 3:13 - 3:15
    fiscal policy and
    everything I've talked about
  • 3:15 - 3:17
    so far at the end of the
    last video and this video
  • 3:17 - 3:18
    really has been fiscal policy.
  • 3:18 - 3:21
    This has been the spending
    lever of fiscal policy
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    and this right over here
    has been the taxing lever
  • 3:24 - 3:25
    of fiscal policy.
  • 3:25 - 3:27
    If you believe either of those can effect
  • 3:27 - 3:30
    aggregate output, then you are essentially
  • 3:30 - 3:33
    subscribing to the Keynesian model.
  • 3:33 - 3:36
    Now one thing that I did
    touch on a little bit
  • 3:36 - 3:39
    in the last video is
    whatever our change is,
  • 3:39 - 3:41
    however much we shift
    this aggregate planned
  • 3:41 - 3:45
    expenditure curve, the
    change in our output
  • 3:45 - 3:47
    actually was some multiple of that.
  • 3:47 - 3:50
    What I want to do now is
    show you mathematically
  • 3:50 - 3:52
    that it actually all works
    out that the multiple is
  • 3:52 - 3:54
    actually the multiplier.
  • 3:54 - 3:56
    If we go back to our
    original and this will just
  • 3:56 - 3:59
    get a little bit mathy
    right over here so I'm
  • 3:59 - 4:00
    just going to rewrite it all.
  • 4:00 - 4:04
    We have our planned
    expenditure, just to redig
  • 4:04 - 4:07
    our minds into the actual expression, the
  • 4:07 - 4:09
    planned expenditure is
    equal to the marginal
  • 4:09 - 4:13
    propensity to consume
    times aggregate income
  • 4:13 - 4:14
    and then you're going to have all of this
  • 4:14 - 4:16
    business right over here.
  • 4:16 - 4:17
    We're just going to go
    with the original one,
  • 4:17 - 4:18
    not what I changed.
  • 4:18 - 4:20
    All this business, let's just call this B.
  • 4:20 - 4:23
    That will just make it
    simple for us to manipulate
  • 4:23 - 4:26
    this so let's just call
    of this business right
  • 4:26 - 4:27
    over here B.
  • 4:27 - 4:29
    We could substitute that back in later.
  • 4:29 - 4:33
    We know that an economy is in equilibrium
  • 4:33 - 4:36
    when planned expenditures
    is equal to output.
  • 4:36 - 4:39
    That is an economy in
    equilibrium so let's set this.
  • 4:39 - 4:43
    Let's set planned expenditures equal to
  • 4:43 - 4:45
    aggregate output, which
    is the same thing as
  • 4:45 - 4:47
    aggregate expenditures, the same thing as
  • 4:47 - 4:49
    aggregate income.
  • 4:49 - 4:53
    We can just solve for
    our equilibrium income.
  • 4:53 - 4:54
    We can just solve for it.
  • 4:54 - 5:00
    You get Y=C1xY+B, this
    is going to look very
  • 5:00 - 5:01
    familiar to you in a second.
  • 5:01 - 5:04
    Subtract C1xY from both sides.
  • 5:04 - 5:08
    Y-C1Y, that's the left-hand side now.
  • 5:08 - 5:10
    On the right-hand side,
    obviously if we subtract
  • 5:10 - 5:15
    C1Y, it's going to go away
    and that is equal to B.
  • 5:15 - 5:20
    Then we can factor out
    the aggregate income from
  • 5:20 - 5:28
    this, so Yx1-C1=B and
    then we divide both sides
  • 5:28 - 5:35
    by 1-C1 and we get, that cancels out.
  • 5:35 - 5:37
    I'll write it right over here.
  • 5:37 - 5:42
    We get, a little bit of
    a drum roll, aggregate
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    income, our equilibrium, aggregate income,
  • 5:46 - 5:48
    aggregate output.
  • 5:48 - 5:57
    GDP is going to be equal to 1/1-C1xB.
  • 5:57 - 6:00
    Remember B was all this business up here.
  • 6:00 - 6:02
    Now what is this?
  • 6:02 - 6:03
    You might remember this
    or if you haven't seen
  • 6:03 - 6:05
    the video, you might
    want to watch the video
  • 6:05 - 6:06
    on the multiplier.
  • 6:06 - 6:08
    This C1 right over here is our marginal
  • 6:08 - 6:12
    propensity to consume.
  • 6:12 - 6:15
    1 minus our marginal propensity to consume
  • 6:15 - 6:16
    is actually - And I
    don't think I've actually
  • 6:16 - 6:18
    referred to it before which
    let me rewrite it here
  • 6:18 - 6:21
    just so that you know the
    term - so C1 is equal to
  • 6:21 - 6:26
    our marginal propensity to consume.
  • 6:26 - 6:30
    For example, if this is
    30% or 0.3, that means
  • 6:30 - 6:32
    for every incremental dollar of disposable
  • 6:32 - 6:35
    income I get, I want to spend $.30 of it.
  • 6:35 - 6:39
    Now 1-C1, you could view
    this as your marginal
  • 6:39 - 6:42
    propensity to save.
  • 6:42 - 6:44
    If I'm going to spend
    30%, that means I'm going
  • 6:44 - 6:46
    to save 70%.
  • 6:46 - 6:49
    This is just saying
    I'm going to save 1-C1.
  • 6:49 - 6:51
    If I'm spending 30% of that incremental
  • 6:51 - 6:55
    disposable dollar, then I'm
    going to save 70% of it.
  • 6:55 - 6:56
    This whole thing, this is the marginal
  • 6:56 - 6:58
    propensity to consume.
  • 6:58 - 7:01
    This entire denominator
    is the marginal propensity
  • 7:01 - 7:06
    to save and then one over
    that, so 1/1-C1 which
  • 7:06 - 7:09
    is the the same thing
    as 1/marginal propensity
  • 7:09 - 7:11
    to save, that is the multiplier.
  • 7:11 - 7:12
    We saw that a few videos ago.
  • 7:12 - 7:14
    If you take this infinite
    geometric series,
  • 7:14 - 7:16
    if we just think through
    how money spends, if I
  • 7:16 - 7:19
    spend some money on some
    good or service, the
  • 7:19 - 7:21
    person who has that
    money as income is going
  • 7:21 - 7:24
    to spend some fraction
    of it based on their
  • 7:24 - 7:26
    marginal propensity to
    consume and we're assuming
  • 7:26 - 7:28
    that it's constant
    throughout the economy at all
  • 7:28 - 7:31
    income levels for this
    model right over here.
  • 7:31 - 7:34
    Then they'll spend some
    of it and then the person
  • 7:34 - 7:35
    that they spend it on,
    they're going to spend
  • 7:35 - 7:36
    some fraction.
  • 7:36 - 7:38
    When you keep adding all
    that infinite series up,
  • 7:38 - 7:42
    you actually get this
    multiplier right over here.
  • 7:42 - 7:49
    This is equal to our multiplier.
  • 7:49 - 7:54
    For example, if B gets
    shifted up by any amount,
  • 7:54 - 7:57
    let's say B gets shifted
    up and it could get
  • 7:57 - 7:59
    shifted up by changes in any of this stuff
  • 7:59 - 8:00
    right over here.
  • 8:00 - 8:02
    Net exports can change,
    planned investments
  • 8:02 - 8:04
    can change, could be shifted up or down.
  • 8:04 - 8:09
    The impact on GDP is
    going to be whatever that
  • 8:09 - 8:12
    shift is times the multiplier.
  • 8:12 - 8:14
    We saw it before.
  • 8:14 - 8:23
    If, for example, if C1=0.6, that means for
  • 8:23 - 8:26
    every incremental disposable
    dollar, people will
  • 8:26 - 8:27
    spend 60% of it.
  • 8:27 - 8:32
    That means that the
    marginal propensity to save
  • 8:32 - 8:34
    is equal to 40%.
  • 8:34 - 8:36
    They're going to save
    40% of any incremental
  • 8:36 - 8:42
    disposable dollar and
    then the multiplier is
  • 8:42 - 8:46
    going to be one over
    that, is going to be 1/0.4
  • 8:46 - 8:48
    which is the same thing
    as one over two-fifths,
  • 8:48 - 8:51
    which is the same thing
    as five-halves, which
  • 8:51 - 8:54
    is the same thing as 2.5.
  • 8:54 - 8:58
    For example, in this
    situation, we just saw that
  • 8:58 - 9:02
    Y, the equilibrium Y is
    going to be 2.5 times
  • 9:02 - 9:04
    whatever all of this other business is.
  • 9:04 - 9:08
    If we change B by, let's
    say, $1 billion and
  • 9:08 - 9:12
    maybe if we increase B by $1 billion.
  • 9:12 - 9:15
    We might increase B by
    $1 billion by increasing
  • 9:15 - 9:17
    government spending by $1
    billion or maybe having
  • 9:17 - 9:20
    this whole term including
    this negative right
  • 9:20 - 9:24
    over here become less
    negative by $1 billion.
  • 9:24 - 9:26
    Maybe we have planned
    investment increase by
  • 9:26 - 9:29
    $1 billion and that could
    actually be done a little
  • 9:29 - 9:31
    bit with tax policy too
    by letting companies
  • 9:31 - 9:33
    maybe depreciate their assets faster.
  • 9:33 - 9:36
    If we could increase net
    exports by $1 billion.
  • 9:36 - 9:39
    Essentially any way that we
    increase B by $1 billion,
  • 9:39 - 9:44
    that'll increase GDP by
    $2.5 billion, 2.5 times
  • 9:44 - 9:45
    our change in B.
  • 9:45 - 9:48
    We can write this down this way.
  • 9:48 - 9:54
    Our change in Y is going
    to be 2.5 times our
  • 9:54 - 9:55
    change in B.
  • 9:55 - 9:57
    Another way to think
    about it when you write
  • 9:57 - 10:00
    the expression like
    this, if you said Y is a
  • 10:00 - 10:02
    function of B, then you
    would say look the slope
  • 10:02 - 10:08
    is 2.5, so change in Y over change in B is
  • 10:08 - 10:11
    equal to 2.5, but I just
    wanted to right this
  • 10:11 - 10:12
    to show you that this isn't some magical
  • 10:12 - 10:14
    voodoo that we're doing.
  • 10:14 - 10:16
    This is what we looked at
    visually when we looked
  • 10:16 - 10:17
    at the Keynesian Cross.
  • 10:17 - 10:20
    This is really just describing the same
  • 10:20 - 10:23
    multiplier effect that
    we saw in previous videos
  • 10:23 - 10:27
    and where we actually derived
    the actual multiplier.
Title:
Keynesian cross and the multiplier | Macroeconomics | Khan Academy
Description:

Converting fractions to decimals sometimes requires us to brush up on our long division skills. We'll walk you through it.

Practice this lesson yourself on KhanAcademy.org right now: https://www.khanacademy.org/math/pre-algebra/decimals-pre-alg/decimal-to-fraction-pre-alg/e/converting_fractions_to_decimals?utm_source=YT&utm_medium=Desc&utm_campaign=PreAlgebra

Watch the next lesson: https://www.khanacademy.org/math/pre-algebra/decimals-pre-alg/decimal-to-fraction-pre-alg/v/decimals-and-fractions?utm_source=YT&utm_medium=Desc&utm_campaign=PreAlgebra

Missed the previous lesson?
https://www.khanacademy.org/math/pre-algebra/decimals-pre-alg/decimal-to-fraction-pre-alg/v/converting-fractions-to-decimals?utm_source=YT&utm_medium=Desc&utm_campaign=PreAlgebra

Pre-Algebra on Khan Academy: No way, this isn't your run of the mill arithmetic. This is Pre-algebra. You're about to play with the professionals. Think of pre-algebra as a runway. You're the airplane and algebra is your sunny vacation destination. Without the runway you're not going anywhere. Seriously, the foundation for all higher mathematics is laid with many of the concepts that we will introduce to you here: negative numbers, absolute value, factors, multiples, decimals, and fractions to name a few. So buckle up and move your seat into the upright position. We're about to take off!

About Khan Academy: Khan Academy offers practice exercises, instructional videos, and a personalized learning dashboard that empower learners to study at their own pace in and outside of the classroom. We tackle math, science, computer programming, history, art history, economics, and more. Our math missions guide learners from kindergarten to calculus using state-of-the-art, adaptive technology that identifies strengths and learning gaps. We've also partnered with institutions like NASA, The Museum of Modern Art, The California Academy of Sciences, and MIT to offer specialized content.

For free. For everyone. Forever. #YouCanLearnAnything

Subscribe to KhanAcademy’s Pre-Algebra channel:: https://www.youtube.com/channel/UCIMlYkATtXOFswVoCZN7nAA?sub_confirmation=1
Subscribe to KhanAcademy: https://www.youtube.com/subscription_center?add_user=khanacademy

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Khan Academy
Duration:
10:27

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions