Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance
-
0:02 - 0:06♪ [music] ♪
-
0:14 - 0:15- [Professor Tyler Cowen]
In the previous video, -
0:15 - 0:18we introduced the ideas
of asymmetric information, -
0:18 - 0:21and adverse selection
and we applied those ideas -
0:21 - 0:23to the used car market.
-
0:23 - 0:25Let's take those same
basic concepts, -
0:25 - 0:29and build a basic model
of health insurance. -
0:29 - 0:31Suppose that potential
health insurance consumers -
0:31 - 0:34come in a range of states of health.
-
0:34 - 0:36For instance,
the least healthy people -
0:36 - 0:39might cost about $30,000 a year.
-
0:39 - 0:41That's these folks here.
-
0:41 - 0:44The most healthy might cost
nothing in healthcare. -
0:44 - 0:46That's these folks over here.
-
0:46 - 0:49Now consumers know this information,
-
0:49 - 0:51but by assumption, insurers don't.
-
0:51 - 0:53From the insurer point of view,
-
0:53 - 0:56everyone is of the same
average health. -
0:56 - 0:59Here again, we have
asymmetric information. -
0:59 - 1:01That is consumers of healthcare
-
1:01 - 1:03have more information about
-
1:03 - 1:05their health status
than insurers do. -
1:05 - 1:09In this scenario, insurers have to
price the coverage -
1:09 - 1:12based on the average cost
among all consumers, -
1:12 - 1:14namely, $15,000.
-
1:15 - 1:19But if the insurance costs $15,000,
then a portion of the market, -
1:19 - 1:21the relatively healthy people,
-
1:21 - 1:23they will choose not
to buy insurance as -
1:23 - 1:26the cost of that insurance
is greater to them -
1:26 - 1:28than the expected benefit.
-
1:28 - 1:31So only part of this market
will buy insurance. -
1:31 - 1:34The average cost of those
who actually will buy -
1:34 - 1:39is then not $15,000 but $22,500.
-
1:39 - 1:42In that case,
the insurance company, -
1:42 - 1:46if it tries to price at $15,000,
loses money. -
1:46 - 1:51If the insurance company instead
raises the price to $22,500, -
1:51 - 1:55well, the same dynamic
is actually going to kick in again. -
1:55 - 1:57That is relatively healthy people
-
1:57 - 1:59won't find it worth
paying that price. -
1:59 - 2:01The sicker people still will buy,
-
2:01 - 2:03and that will raise
the expected costs -
2:03 - 2:06to the insurer,
and thus the price even further. -
2:07 - 2:10This dynamic continues
until the individual insurance firm -
2:10 - 2:13finds there is no price
at which it can attract -
2:13 - 2:16a set of customers with
healthcare costs -
2:16 - 2:18lower than the price of insurance.
-
2:19 - 2:23This is the same death spiral
we saw before with used cars -
2:23 - 2:25and it leads to a market failure.
-
2:26 - 2:28As we saw in the used car market,
-
2:28 - 2:31there are several reasons
why reality may differ -
2:31 - 2:32from the simple model.
-
2:32 - 2:36First, the model we laid out would
predict that the healthy people, -
2:36 - 2:38those who exercise,
eat their veggies, -
2:38 - 2:41and buckle their seatbelts would
not buy insurance, -
2:41 - 2:45while the model is predicting that
the smokers, the mountain climbers, -
2:45 - 2:49and the motorcycle riders would
buy insurance. -
2:49 - 2:51Is this true? Mostly no.
-
2:51 - 2:53The people who buy health insurance
-
2:53 - 2:56actually turn out to be
the healthier people as well. -
2:56 - 2:58Why is that?
-
2:58 - 3:01Well, those who try to avoid risk
by eating well -
3:01 - 3:05also try to avoid risk
by buying health insurance. -
3:05 - 3:06Our initial assumption that
-
3:06 - 3:08everyone calculates
costs and benefits -
3:08 - 3:11in exactly the same way
is too simple. -
3:11 - 3:13Once you account for the fact that
-
3:13 - 3:16people have differential
tolerances for risk, -
3:16 - 3:18you can end up having
the healthier people be -
3:18 - 3:21those who choose to buy
the health insurance. -
3:21 - 3:24This is called
“propitious selection” -
3:24 - 3:27where the people who buy
the health insurance are healthier, -
3:27 - 3:29not sicker than average.
-
3:29 - 3:33This can keep costs low,
and prevent the death spiral. -
3:34 - 3:37Another possible response
to the adverse selection problem -
3:37 - 3:39in health insurance
might seem familiar. -
3:39 - 3:42If you recall,
we saw that services such as -
3:42 - 3:45CARFAX and Certified Inspections
-
3:45 - 3:48can alleviate
the asymmetric information problem -
3:48 - 3:50when buying a used car.
-
3:50 - 3:53These services allow
the buyer of the car -
3:53 - 3:54to have similar information
-
3:54 - 3:57to that possessed
by the seller of the car. -
3:58 - 4:00The result of this information
is that better cars -
4:00 - 4:04can sell for more,
and lemons can sell for less. -
4:04 - 4:07Is there an analogous approach
for people in health insurance? -
4:07 - 4:08Well, yes.
-
4:08 - 4:10The health of people
can be inspected -
4:10 - 4:12just as cars are inspected.
-
4:12 - 4:15So while consumers initially
may have more information -
4:15 - 4:18about their health than what
the insurance companies have, -
4:18 - 4:21a checkup will allow
the insurance firms -
4:21 - 4:24to get a better idea of
the consumer's expected -
4:24 - 4:25healthcare costs.
-
4:25 - 4:27And that allows
the insurance companies -
4:27 - 4:32to charge healthy consumers less
and sicker consumers more. -
4:32 - 4:33In the used car market,
-
4:33 - 4:35that seemed like
a pretty good solution. -
4:35 - 4:38After all, better cars
should sell for more, -
4:38 - 4:40and lemons should sell for less.
-
4:40 - 4:42In the health insurance market,
-
4:42 - 4:43that solution might work,
-
4:43 - 4:46but some people feel it is
doubly unfair. -
4:46 - 4:48Not only are the sick sick,
-
4:48 - 4:50but now they also have
to pay more -
4:50 - 4:52for their health insurance.
-
4:52 - 4:53Another problem
with inspection is that -
4:53 - 4:56it might reveal
too much information, -
4:56 - 4:59thereby rendering health insurance
no longer viable. -
4:59 - 5:02For instance, let's say there's
a very good diagnostic test, -
5:02 - 5:05and it determines that
a patient A has cancer -
5:05 - 5:10and then B we know that cancer
will cost $1 million to treat. -
5:10 - 5:12Well, to insure against that cancer,
-
5:12 - 5:15the price of the policy
has to be about $1 million, -
5:15 - 5:17but that's no longer insurance.
-
5:17 - 5:19That's just presenting the patient
with the bill. -
5:19 - 5:23Insurance is protecting against
unexpected states of affairs, -
5:23 - 5:25and it's a kind of risk pooling,
-
5:25 - 5:28a kind of protecting yourself
against the high bill. -
5:28 - 5:30But if you're getting the high bill
no matter what when you're sick, -
5:30 - 5:34well, then we've lost
those benefits of insurance. -
5:35 - 5:37Another solution to
the adverse selection problem -
5:37 - 5:40when used extensively
in the United States -
5:40 - 5:42is group health insurance
through employers. -
5:42 - 5:46Most people in America
don't purchase insurance directly. -
5:46 - 5:48Instead, their employer
purchases it for them -
5:48 - 5:50as part of a group plan.
-
5:50 - 5:54The benefit of the system is that
the insurance company -
5:54 - 5:57doesn't have to worry about
adverse selection so much -
5:57 - 6:00The employer doesn't know much
more about its employees' health -
6:00 - 6:02than does the insurance firm.
-
6:02 - 6:04Furthermore, the employer is
going to be buying -
6:04 - 6:08health insurance for the employees
regardless of their health. -
6:08 - 6:11So for these reasons,
the adverse selection problem is -
6:11 - 6:14much weaker with
group health insurance. -
6:14 - 6:18Group health insurance, however,
does cause other problems. -
6:18 - 6:21If you lose your job,
you can lose your health insurance. -
6:21 - 6:23And what we do about retirees?
-
6:24 - 6:26In the United States,
various laws have made -
6:26 - 6:29health insurance more affordable,
-
6:29 - 6:31and furthermore retirees are insured
by the government -
6:31 - 6:33under Medicare.
-
6:33 - 6:37So, there are some solutions,
albeit imperfect ones as usual. -
6:38 - 6:41The most recent approach
to the adverse selection problem -
6:41 - 6:43was implemented
in the Affordable Care Act, -
6:43 - 6:46otherwise known as Obamacare.
-
6:46 - 6:48Under the Affordable Care Act,
-
6:48 - 6:51everyone is supposed to buy
health insurance. -
6:51 - 6:54If you don't,
you will be fined by law. -
6:54 - 6:58The idea here is to force
all the healthy people into the pool -
6:58 - 6:59of those who buy insurance
-
6:59 - 7:02that will moderate the cost
of health insurance, -
7:02 - 7:04and we will avoid the death spiral.
-
7:04 - 7:06As you can see, although
-
7:06 - 7:09the adverse selection model
is pretty simple, -
7:09 - 7:10it has lots of applications
-
7:10 - 7:13to some pretty complex
real-world problems. -
7:13 - 7:17Next up we'll tackle moral
hazard. See you then. -
7:17 - 7:19♪ [music] ♪
-
7:19 - 7:20- [Announcer] If you want
to test yourself, -
7:20 - 7:22click “Practice Questions."
-
7:22 - 7:26Or, if you're ready to move on,
just click “Next Video.”
- Title:
- Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance
- Description:
-
In this video, we discuss asymmetric information, adverse selection, and propitious selection in relation to the market for health insurance. Health insurance consumers come in a range of health, but to insurance companies, everyone has the same average health. Consumer have more information about their health than do insurers. How does this affect the price of health insurance? Why would some consumers prefer to not buy health insurance at all? And how does this all relate to the Affordable Care Act? Let’s dive in.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics
Ask a question about the video: http://www.mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/lemons-problem-asymmetric-information-health-insurance#QandA
Next video: http://www.mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/moral-hazard-adverse-selection
- Video Language:
- English
- Team:
Marginal Revolution University
- Project:
- Micro
- Duration:
- 07:31
![]() |
danielle rox edited English subtitles for Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance | |
![]() |
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance | |
![]() |
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance |