-
- [Alex] Why is this house selling
for more than $2.5 million?
-
Or this apartment,
-
renting for almost $3,000 a month?
-
Is it greed? Conspiracy?
-
No.
-
Just a powerful economic concept,
the elasticity of supply.
-
Sounds complex,
but it's actually quite simple.
-
In the United States
and around the world,
-
many industries and jobs
-
have been concentrating
in a few dynamic cities,
-
like tech in Silicon Valley,
entertainment in LA,
-
and pharmaceuticals in Boston.
-
So more and more people --
-
they want to live
in these dynamic cities,
-
and that increases
the demand for housing.
-
And remember, what happens
with an increase in demand?
-
The demand curve
shifts to the right,
-
and buyers are willing to buy more
at any given price.
-
This leads to a new equilibrium,
-
with a higher quantity
sold at a higher price.
-
But which increase will be larger?
-
The quantity change,
or the price change?
-
That depends upon
-
whether the supply
is elastic or inelastic.
-
If the supply is elastic,
-
meaning that producers
can easily produce more housing,
-
then the quantity supplied
will increase a lot,
-
and the price
will only increase a little.
-
But if the supply is inelastic --
-
that means it's not easy
to produce more housing,
-
and our supply curve
looks more like this.
-
In this case,
-
the quantity supplied
only increases a little,
-
but the price goes up a lot.
-
That happens when housing suppliers
-
can't easily expand
their production
-
in response to the higher price.
-
Now, unfortunately, many cities
have inelastic housing supplies.
-
So as people flock to these cities,
we see higher and higher prices,
-
with little increase
in the quantity of housing.
-
Why?
-
Well, first, there are
natural problems.
-
Many of the in-demand cities --
-
they're surrounded
by beautiful water.
-
Nice, but that means
a limited supply of land.
-
But we compound natural problems
with unnatural ones.
-
In many cities,
-
zoning laws and other regulations
-
prevent builders
from creating more housing.
-
Take San Francisco, for example --
-
it's surrounded by water,
so there's limited land.
-
But if you can't build out,
how about building up?
-
There's plenty of land in the sky.
-
San Francisco's
zoning laws, however,
-
have made it impossible
or very expensive
-
to build taller buildings
in many parts of the city.
-
Even changing single-family homes
to duplexes or fourplexes
-
has typically been prohibited.
-
And that's not all.
-
Suppose a builder does find
a plot of land to use.
-
Well, next, they need
a building permit.
-
And the process for filing
for building permits --
-
they can be hard to understand.
-
City officials can leave applicants
hanging for years.
-
In San Francisco,
-
it takes an average of 627 days
-
to receive a building permit
for a new house.
-
That delay adds a lot
to the costs for builders.
-
And if a builder does get
a building permit, it's not over.
-
Many people can still veto
the project:
-
environmental agencies,
-
planning commissions,
-
historic preservation societies,
-
and groups of existing residents.
-
They can slow things down
with lawsuits, protests,
-
and bureaucratic objections.
-
So now that we better understand
-
why the supply of housing
is inelastic,
-
let's revisit our supply
and demand graph
-
and illustrate what happens
in the housing market
-
with an increase in demand.
-
Suppose a city is thriving,
-
and the demand to live
in that city increases.
-
The demand curve
shifts to the right.
-
To keep it simple,
-
say that ten people
want to move into the city.
-
Builders see
the increase in demand,
-
and they try to build more,
-
but they're stopped
-
by water, height restrictions,
-
zoning laws, bureaucracy, lawsuits.
-
That's our inelastic
supply of housing.
-
So imagine, somehow a builder
finds a way to construct one home,
-
increasing the quantity
supplied a little.
-
But ten people want to move in!
-
So who gets the new home?
-
Well, the potential
new residents --
-
they compete to get the new home
by bidding up the price.
-
The price for the new home goes up.
-
First, one person drops out,
-
and then the price
goes up some more,
-
and another person drops out.
-
The price keeps going higher
and higher and higher
-
until just one person is left,
-
and the high bidder
wins the new home.
-
Notice that it's not
the owners of housing
-
jacking up the price --
-
it's the buyers who must bid higher
to out-compete one another,
-
given the limited supply.
-
An inelastic supply of housing --
-
it does mean higher property values
for existing residents.
-
So existing property owners --
-
they have an incentive
to block new construction.
-
And that's one reason
why reform is difficult.
-
And who's harmed?
-
Well, lots of people,
-
but most especially
the potential residents
-
who are bid out of the market.
-
They'll have to live further away,
with longer commutes,
-
or they may not even be able
to live near good jobs at all.
-
And notice that the people
who are harmed --
-
they don't get a vote.
-
By definition,
-
the potential residents --
-
they don't live in the city
that priced them out of a home.
-
It's not all bad news, however.
-
Slowly, some cities
are starting to change.
-
In 2016, Auckland, New Zealand --
-
they liberalized their laws
-
to allow upzoning
in much of the city.
-
And the number
of new houses skyrocketed,
-
and housing prices moderated.
-
The rest of New Zealand
is now following suit.
-
Even San Francisco
is starting to allow
-
new duplexes and fourplexes.
-
So let's hear it for a more
elastic supply of housing.
-
[cheering]
-
Okay. There you have it.
-
If you want to understand
why housing prices are rising,
-
you must first understand
the elasticity of supply
-
and what makes housing supply
-
in many parts
of the world inelastic.
-
Now, you can test
your understanding of elasticity
-
by checking out
our practice questions.
-
We also have test banks
and lesson plans
-
for Economics teachers.
-
Or, if you're ready
for more microeconomics,
-
click for the next video.
-
♪ [music] ♪