< Return to Video

Price Ceilings: Lines and Search Costs

  • 0:09 - 0:13
    - [Alex] In this video, were going to take
    a look at another effect of price
  • 0:13 - 0:18
    ceilings: wasteful lines and other
    search costs. Let's get started.
  • 0:23 - 0:28
    It's important to understand that price
    controls do not eliminate competition.
  • 0:28 - 0:35
    Competition for scarce goods is an ever
    present force under all forms of social
  • 0:35 - 0:40
    organization. What price controls do is
    they change the form that competition
  • 0:40 - 0:48
    takes. So in a market, demanders compete
    by pushing prices up. Suppliers compete by
  • 0:48 - 0:54
    pushing prices down. When we have price
    controls, that shifting of prices is no
  • 0:54 - 0:59
    longer possible. But competition remains -
    it just takes other forms. Here's an
  • 0:59 - 1:05
    example of musical chairs. The quantity
    demanded exceeds the quantity supplied.
  • 1:05 - 1:11
    There's a shortage. But there's still lots
    of competition, lots of scrambling to get
  • 1:11 - 1:16
    hold of those goods which are in short
    supply. So lets take a closer look at some
  • 1:17 - 1:21
    of the forms that competition takes when
    we have price controls and shortages.
  • 1:22 - 1:26
    So suppose there's a price control on
    gasoline and oil, making it illegal to
  • 1:27 - 1:31
    compete for these goods by pushing the
    price up. Nevertheless, there are other
  • 1:31 - 1:36
    ways of competing. Some buyers, for example, might
    try bribing the station owners. This is not
  • 1:36 - 1:40
    necessarily the first thing which would
    happen in the United States, but in other
  • 1:40 - 1:44
    places and countries this is extremely
    common. Having a cousin who works in the
  • 1:44 - 1:49
    factory which is producing the good which
    is in shortage is extremely important.
  • 1:49 - 1:53
    Using ones political connections, being
    part of the political elite is
  • 1:53 - 1:57
    extremely important for obtaining goods,
    which are in shortage. Even in the United
  • 1:58 - 2:02
    States, remember that firms also need
    oil and gasoline in
  • 2:02 - 2:05
    order to operate. And in the
    1970s when there was a
  • 2:05 - 2:10
    shortage of oil, firms appealed to the
    Department of Energy, they lobbied their
  • 2:10 - 2:14
    Congressman and their Senator to obtain an
    allocation of oil for their firm.
  • 2:15 - 2:21
    For consumers, another way to obtain the
    good is to be willing to wait in line.
  • 2:22 - 2:27
    Now time waiting in line is also a cost.
    So let's ask, "How long will the
  • 2:27 - 2:32
    line get?" We can use our model to
    understand willingness to wait in line
  • 2:32 - 2:35
    and how long the lines will get.
    Let's take a look.
  • 2:36 - 2:40
    So here's our supply and demand diagram
    of the shortage. Remember that at the
  • 2:40 - 2:45
    controlled price we read the quantity
    demanded off the demand curve, Qd, and at
  • 2:45 - 2:51
    the controlled price we read quantity supplied off
    the supply curve, Qs. So Qs is the actual
  • 2:51 - 2:57
    amount of gasoline supplied given the
    controlled price of one dollar. Now, here
  • 2:57 - 3:04
    is the key question: How much are buyers
    willing to pay for a gallon of gasoline,
  • 3:05 - 3:11
    when Qs is the amount which is being
    supplied? How much are buyers willing to
  • 3:11 - 3:15
    pay? What is the most they are willing to pay for
    a gallon of gasoline? Well remember, we can
  • 3:15 - 3:19
    read that off the demand curve - that's
    what the demand curve tells us. So at the
  • 3:20 - 3:25
    controlled price, when the quantity
    supplied is Qs, buyers are willing to pay
  • 3:25 - 3:31
    $3 per gallon of gasoline. Theyre
    only allowed to pay in money $1.
  • 3:31 - 3:39
    So, if a buyer were to obtain a
    gallon of gasoline at a controlled price
  • 3:39 - 3:45
    of $1, that's actually worth to
    them $3. That explains why
  • 3:46 - 3:52
    people are willing to wait in line for a
    long time in order to get gasoline, because
  • 3:52 - 3:57
    the shortage has reduced the quantity
    supplied. It's raised the
  • 3:57 - 3:58
    willingness to pay for gasoline,
  • 3:58 - 4:04
    but it hasn't raised the price of
    gasoline. Therefore people are willing to
  • 4:04 - 4:12
    wait in line. And, in fact, the line
    will grow until on the margin the
  • 4:12 - 4:19
    time price plus the money price will be
    equal to the willingness to pay. So the
  • 4:20 - 4:25
    line will grow until the money price,
    which is $1/gallon, plus the
  • 4:25 - 4:33
    time price, the time wasted in line, which
    will grow up until it's $2/gallon,
  • 4:33 - 4:38
    until the total price equals the
    willingness to pay. Why is that? Well,
  • 4:38 - 4:44
    imagine that that were not the case. Imagine
    that you could obtain a gallon of gasoline
  • 4:44 - 4:49
    which is worth $3 for you. And you
    only had to pay a dollar plus 50 cents
  • 4:49 - 4:54
    in waiting time. Well that would be a
    great deal. So people will be willing to
  • 4:54 - 5:01
    wait in line so long as the total price,
    the money price plus the time price, is
  • 5:01 - 5:06
    less than the willingness to pay. This
    means that the line will continue to grow
  • 5:06 - 5:12
    until the total price is equal to the
    willingness to pay. So, if we now take the
  • 5:12 - 5:18
    time price, which is the difference between the
    willingness to pay and the controlled
  • 5:18 - 5:25
    price, times the quantity - that gives us the
    total value of wasted time. So, another
  • 5:26 - 5:31
    effect of price controls - it creates long
    lines in order to compete to get the good
  • 5:32 - 5:37
    instead of bidding the price up, they bid
    in terms of being willing to wait in line.
  • 5:37 - 5:41
    And those lines are wasteful, creates a
    lot of wasted time.
  • 5:43 - 5:46
    Let's take a look with a numerical
    example. Okay, here's a simple numerical
  • 5:47 - 5:52
    example to bring this home. Suppose that
    buyers value their time at $10/hour,
  • 5:52 - 5:57
    and that the average fuel tank holds 20
    gallons. Now imagine that a buyer arrives
  • 5:57 - 6:00
    early at the gasoline station
    and they wait one hour.
  • 6:00 - 6:07
    The total cost of the gasoline
    is then $20, $1/gallon times 20
  • 6:07 - 6:10
    gallons in money cost,
    plus $10 in time cost.
  • 6:10 - 6:14
    They waited an hour
    and they value their time
  • 6:14 - 6:19
    at $10/hour. So the total cost of
    the gasoline is then $30. It took
  • 6:19 - 6:26
    $30 worth of time and money in order to
    get 20 gallons. So the implied cost per
  • 6:26 - 6:32
    gallon is $1.50/gallon. However,
    remember that given the quantity supplied,
  • 6:32 - 6:38
    given the shortage, the value of
    gasoline is $3/gallon. So this buyer
  • 6:38 - 6:43
    managed to obtain something which
    is worth $3/gallon for only $1.50
  • 6:43 - 6:50
    per gallon. That's a good deal so other
    buyers are going to bid up the price
  • 6:50 - 6:56
    by arriving earlier and earlier. And this
    is going to push up the time cost. The
  • 6:56 - 7:01
    money cost is fixed because of the price
    control, but the time cost can still
  • 7:01 - 7:09
    increase. In fact, the line will lengthen
    until the total cost of obtaining 20
  • 7:09 - 7:16
    gallons of gasoline equals $60 or
    $3/gallon. In other words, the
  • 7:16 - 7:25
    buyers will end up spending $20 in money
    cost plus $40 in time cost, or four hours of
  • 7:25 - 7:30
    waiting. So we're able to calculate
    approximately how long the line will get.
  • 7:30 - 7:37
    It will get four hours worth of time. So
    this again illustrates that competition
  • 7:37 - 7:43
    does not go away when we have price
    controls. Instead competition takes
  • 7:43 - 7:49
    different forms, and one of those forms is -
    instead of bidding up the money price, the
  • 7:49 - 7:56
    time price is bid up and we get long and
    wasteful lines. So what we've just seen
  • 7:56 - 8:01
    is that in a free market, buyers compete to
    obtain goods by bidding up money
  • 8:01 - 8:07
    prices. And when we have price controls,
    one way that buyers compete to obtain
  • 8:07 - 8:12
    goods is by bidding up time prices, by
    being willing to wait in line. So what's a
  • 8:12 - 8:17
    better form of competition? Bidding or
    paying in money or paying in time? Does it
  • 8:18 - 8:21
    make a difference? After all, some people
    have got more money, some people have got more
  • 8:21 - 8:27
    time, is it just a matter of preference?
    No. It is much better to have an economic
  • 8:28 - 8:33
    system where competition takes the form of
    bidding in money than it takes the form of
  • 8:33 - 8:43
    bidding in time. Why? Paying in time is
    much more wasteful. When you bid in terms
  • 8:43 - 8:49
    of money, the money goes to the station
    owner. The money does not disappear. That
  • 8:49 - 8:55
    purchasing power is transferred from the
    consumer to the producer. On the other
  • 8:55 - 9:01
    hand, when buyers bid in terms of time,
    when they wait in line, that waiting in
  • 9:02 - 9:07
    line is just lost. It's not transferred to
    the producer. When you wait in line for
  • 9:07 - 9:14
    four hours to obtain gasoline, the seller
    of gasoline doesn't get to add four hours
  • 9:14 - 9:20
    to his lifespan. So that waiting in line
    is just a total loss. When you pay in
  • 9:20 - 9:26
    money, the purchasing power is transferred
    to the station owner. When you pay in
  • 9:27 - 9:33
    terms of time, the value of that time
    is simply lost. It benefits no one.
  • 9:33 - 9:38
    Okay, quick reminder of where we are. Price
    ceilings have five important effects. We've
  • 9:38 - 9:42
    looked at shortages and reductions in product
    quantity. We've just completed wasteful
  • 9:43 - 9:46
    lines and other search costs. Up next,
    a loss in gains from trade,
  • 9:46 - 9:49
    and then a misallocation of resources.
  • 9:50 - 9:55
    - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself, click
    Practice Questions. Or, if you're ready to
  • 9:55 - 9:57
    move on, just click Next Video.
Title:
Price Ceilings: Lines and Search Costs
Description:

In this video, we explore two more unintended consequences of price ceilings: long lines and search costs. What was it like waiting in long lines for gasoline back in the 1970s? Not fun. But why did this happen? When price ceilings were imposed on gasoline, people could not use prices to signal how much they were willing to pay for gas. Instead, the only way they could show how much (or how little) they wanted of gasoline, was to wait (or not wait) in line. Going to fuel up becomes less about paying in money and more about paying in time. At the end of the day, paying in time is much more wasteful. In this video, we’ll show how to calculate the value of the time wasted in line. 

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/price-ceiling-gasoline-example-search-costs#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/price-ceiling-deadweight-loss

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
10:02

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions