< Return to Video

Bundling

  • 0:01 - 0:04
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:12
    - [Alex] In our final video
    on price discrimination,
  • 0:12 - 0:15
    we're going to be
    talking about bundling.
  • 0:20 - 0:25
    Bundling is selling two
    or more goods together as a package
  • 0:25 - 0:29
    so Microsoft, for example,
    sells Word, Excel, PowerPoint,
  • 0:29 - 0:32
    a few other programs, together
    in a package called Office.
  • 0:33 - 0:36
    You can also buy these programs
    individually but the total price
  • 0:36 - 0:39
    then would much exceed
    the Office price.
  • 0:39 - 0:41
    So most people buy it as Office.
  • 0:41 - 0:43
    Cable TV is a collection,
  • 0:43 - 0:47
    typically of, let's say, a hundred
    channels, or you might buy
  • 0:47 - 0:50
    twenty channels, the movie pack --
    you might add on to your hundred
  • 0:50 - 0:53
    with the movie pack,
    a bundle or package.
  • 0:53 - 0:59
    LexisNexis is a collection of
    thousands of different news sources.
  • 0:59 - 1:02
    Newspapers themselves are bundles.
  • 1:02 - 1:04
    They're bundles, let's say,
    of sections: the sports section,
  • 1:04 - 1:05
    the business section.
  • 1:05 - 1:08
    Not everyone who reads
    the business section reads
  • 1:08 - 1:10
    the sports section,
    and vice versa.
  • 1:10 - 1:13
    Spotify, which we'll talk
    a little bit more about later,
  • 1:13 - 1:18
    is a bundle of songs --
    16 million songs now and growing.
  • 1:19 - 1:22
    It's surprising how much bundling
    can increase profits.
  • 1:22 - 1:24
    Let's look at a simple example.
  • 1:24 - 1:27
    Suppose there are two products,
    Word and Excel.
  • 1:27 - 1:30
    And let's imagine selling them
    at first individually.
  • 1:30 - 1:32
    So for Word it's pretty clear
    that there are only
  • 1:32 - 1:34
    two sensible prices.
  • 1:34 - 1:38
    Amanda values Word at $100 --
    Yvonne only at $40.
  • 1:38 - 1:42
    So either the firm should price
    at $100 and just sell one unit
  • 1:42 - 1:45
    or price at $40 and sell two.
  • 1:45 - 1:47
    Same thing for Excel.
  • 1:47 - 1:50
    Either the firm should price
    at $20 and sell two units,
  • 1:50 - 1:52
    both to Amanda and to Yvonne,
  • 1:52 - 1:56
    or sell at $90 and sell
    just one unit to Yvonne.
  • 1:56 - 1:59
    So let's take a look at the profits
  • 1:59 - 2:04
    from the high price strategy,
    selling at $190.
  • 2:04 - 2:08
    So in this case Microsoft will sell
    one unit at $100, one unit at $90
  • 2:08 - 2:10
    for a total profit of $190.
  • 2:11 - 2:13
    Notice here we're assuming
    that marginal costs are zero
  • 2:13 - 2:16
    so revenues are the same as profits.
  • 2:16 - 2:19
    Now let's look
    at the low price strategy.
  • 2:19 - 2:24
    In this case, Microsoft will sell
    two units of Word at $40 each
  • 2:24 - 2:29
    and two units of Excel at $20 each
    for a total of $120.
  • 2:29 - 2:32
    Now you can check
    the combinations here,
  • 2:32 - 2:35
    but take it for granted
    that the maximum profit
  • 2:35 - 2:39
    with the individual sale is
    from selling at the high price,
  • 2:39 - 2:43
    and thus the profits are $190.
  • 2:43 - 2:45
    Now let's consider
    an alternative strategy.
  • 2:45 - 2:47
    Suppose we combine Word
  • 2:47 - 2:52
    and Excel in a product
    or a bundle called Office.
  • 2:52 - 2:55
    Amanda values Office at $120.
  • 2:55 - 2:59
    That is, the combination of Word
    for $100 and Excel for $20,
  • 2:59 - 3:01
    she values for a total of $120.
  • 3:01 - 3:05
    Yvonne values Office at $130.
  • 3:05 - 3:08
    Again it's pretty clear that there
    are only two sensible prices --
  • 3:08 - 3:12
    sell at $130 and just sell one unit
    or sell at $120 and sell two.
  • 3:12 - 3:15
    Pretty obvious that what
    you want to do is to price
  • 3:15 - 3:20
    the bundle at $120, sell two units,
    make $240 and then notice
  • 3:20 - 3:26
    bundling has increased profits
    by $50 or by 26%.
  • 3:26 - 3:30
    Pretty good deal just for combining
    the products in a package.
  • 3:30 - 3:32
    So what's really going on here?
  • 3:33 - 3:37
    The problem with selling
    Word and Excel individually is
  • 3:37 - 3:40
    that the demands for the individual
    products are highly variable.
  • 3:40 - 3:45
    So, Amanda values Word at $100,
    but Yvonne only at $40.
  • 3:45 - 3:49
    On the other case for Excel,
    Amanda values Excel at $20,
  • 3:49 - 3:54
    Yvonne at $90, so there's a lot
    of variability in the demands
  • 3:54 - 3:55
    for the two products.
  • 3:55 - 3:59
    That means that the firm is forced
    to make a choice to sell high
  • 3:59 - 4:02
    but sell only a few copies
    or to sell low
  • 4:02 - 4:04
    and to sell more copies.
  • 4:04 - 4:08
    On the other hand, look at what
    happens when the firm bundles.
  • 4:08 - 4:12
    So the variability between
    the bundle values is
  • 4:12 - 4:14
    now much, much lower.
  • 4:14 - 4:19
    Because the variability is lower,
    the firm is able to price it closer
  • 4:19 - 4:22
    to the mean and grab up more
    of the consumer surplus.
  • 4:22 - 4:27
    Now in this case, the bundling
    works particularly effectively
  • 4:27 - 4:30
    because Amanda and Yvonne
    have negative correlations --
  • 4:30 - 4:34
    that is Amanda has a high value
    for Word and a low for Excel
  • 4:34 - 4:38
    while Yvonne has a high value
    for Excel and a low for Word.
  • 4:38 - 4:42
    Negative correlation helps
    here a lot, but it's
  • 4:42 - 4:43
    actually not necessary.
  • 4:43 - 4:48
    More generally what matters is
    that the demand for the bundle is
  • 4:48 - 4:52
    less variable than the demand
    for the individual products.
  • 4:52 - 4:56
    Zero marginal cost is
    also a big help here.
  • 4:56 - 4:58
    And the principle here is
    that it's never wise to sell
  • 4:58 - 5:03
    someone something if they value it
    at less than the cost.
  • 5:03 - 5:07
    So imagine that somebody values
    a product at $20,
  • 5:07 - 5:11
    and it costs you $30 to produce it.
  • 5:11 - 5:14
    While you could get them
    to buy it as part of the bundle,
  • 5:14 - 5:16
    but that's never going
    to maximize profit,
  • 5:16 - 5:20
    because by taking that product out
    of the bundle you can cut
  • 5:20 - 5:24
    your costs, $30,
    by more than you can cut
  • 5:24 - 5:27
    the willingness to pay, $20.
  • 5:27 - 5:28
    So you never want to sell someone
  • 5:28 - 5:31
    something if they value it
    at less than the cost.
  • 5:31 - 5:35
    When marginal costs are positive,
    there's always a fear that
  • 5:35 - 5:37
    by bundling you're going
    to be selling something
  • 5:37 - 5:41
    that the person values
    at less than the cost.
  • 5:41 - 5:44
    If marginal cost is zero,
    we don't have that problem,
  • 5:44 - 5:47
    so we can bundle
    to our heart's content.
  • 5:47 - 5:52
    So bundling is really going
    to work well when we have
  • 5:52 - 5:55
    zero marginal cost products,
    like information goods.
  • 5:56 - 5:59
    When marginal costs are zero,
    it could make sense
  • 5:59 - 6:02
    to bundle hundreds or even
    thousands of goods together,
  • 6:02 - 6:03
    information goods.
  • 6:03 - 6:07
    A very excellent paper on this
    by Bakos and Brynjolfsson,
  • 6:07 - 6:09
    and their basic story is this:
  • 6:09 - 6:12
    Suppose that consumers have
    different valuations
  • 6:12 - 6:13
    for different goods.
  • 6:14 - 6:17
    So for one good, for one consumer,
    the consumer may put a high value
  • 6:17 - 6:22
    on that good but on the next good
    they may have a low value.
  • 6:22 - 6:25
    Equally likely to have
    a high or low value.
  • 6:25 - 6:30
    Now imagine that on the first good,
    the consumer has a high value.
  • 6:30 - 6:33
    On the second good they're
    likely to have a value
  • 6:33 - 6:35
    which is less high.
  • 6:35 - 6:39
    So when you combine those
    two goods, you're going to get
  • 6:39 - 6:42
    a more intermediate result,
    a result closer to the mean.
  • 6:42 - 6:46
    So when you add up or average
    all the different goods,
  • 6:46 - 6:48
    maybe one here,
    and one here and one here --
  • 6:48 - 6:52
    you add more and more goods
    to the bundle -- what you get is
  • 6:52 - 6:54
    a demand for the bundle
    which is closer to the mean.
  • 6:55 - 6:59
    In terms of a demand curve,
    this setup means
  • 6:59 - 7:03
    that the demand curve is linear,
    like this for an individual good,
  • 7:03 - 7:05
    but if you have a two-good bundle,
  • 7:05 - 7:09
    it increases the quantity
    demanded to the mean.
  • 7:09 - 7:11
    Let's in fact take a look
    at 20-good bundle.
  • 7:11 - 7:17
    So the demand for a 20-good bundle,
    even though each individual good
  • 7:17 - 7:20
    in that bundle has
    this linear demand --
  • 7:20 - 7:26
    the demand for the bundle itself is
    much greater at the mean.
  • 7:26 - 7:28
    It's concentrated around the mean.
  • 7:28 - 7:31
    You get this big increase in
    the quantity demanded at the mean
  • 7:31 - 7:36
    as the bundle values go to the mean.
  • 7:36 - 7:41
    Because the demand -- the quantity
    demanded -- is concentrated
  • 7:41 - 7:45
    at the mean, just a small reduction
    in price can increase
  • 7:45 - 7:48
    the quantity demanded,
    and that's what the firm will do.
  • 7:48 - 7:51
    It'll drop the bundle price
    a little bit, sell a lot more,
  • 7:51 - 7:55
    and eat up much more
    of the total consumer surplus.
  • 7:55 - 7:59
    So that's why it makes
    sense to bundle thousands
  • 7:59 - 8:02
    of goods when the goods
    have zero marginal cost.
  • 8:03 - 8:06
    Okay, let's say a few words
    about profits, consumer welfare
  • 8:06 - 8:08
    and total welfare efficiency.
  • 8:08 - 8:10
    This is a little bit tricky because
    the results are not perfectly
  • 8:10 - 8:13
    general but the basic idea is this.
  • 8:13 - 8:16
    Bundling increases profits,
    otherwise the firm wouldn't do it,
  • 8:16 - 8:19
    and we've seen why
    it increases profits.
  • 8:19 - 8:23
    Now some of that increase comes
    from reductions in consumer surplus,
  • 8:23 - 8:25
    a transfer from consumers.
  • 8:25 - 8:29
    But some of it comes
    from reductions in deadweight loss,
  • 8:29 - 8:32
    that is it comes
    from increased sales.
  • 8:32 - 8:34
    The increased sales add
    to efficiency.
  • 8:34 - 8:40
    Overall consumer welfare could go
    up or down, holding fixed
  • 8:40 - 8:42
    the number and quality of goods.
  • 8:42 - 8:45
    At least in one classic case,
    in the big bundle zero
  • 8:45 - 8:48
    marginal cost case,
    total welfare increases.
  • 8:48 - 8:54
    That is the profits and the
    reduction in deadweight loss
  • 8:54 - 8:58
    more than make up for reductions
    in consumer surplus.
  • 8:58 - 9:01
    Now, goods with zero marginal cost
  • 9:01 - 9:05
    often have very
    high fixed costs, like software.
  • 9:05 - 9:07
    There's a lot of investment in
    producing the software
  • 9:07 - 9:10
    in the first place,
    even though it's easy to distribute.
  • 9:10 - 9:15
    Movies and TV, information
    in general is like this.
  • 9:15 - 9:17
    And to the extent that increased
  • 9:17 - 9:21
    profits, increased investment
    in the fixed cost of creation,
  • 9:21 - 9:25
    bundling will also tend
    to increase consumer welfare,
  • 9:25 - 9:27
    as well as efficiency.
  • 9:27 - 9:30
    So on average, my belief is
    that the case for bundling
  • 9:30 - 9:32
    is actually pretty good.
  • 9:32 - 9:34
    Now let's look at an application.
  • 9:35 - 9:38
    Cable TV is typically sold
    as a package or a bundle
  • 9:38 - 9:39
    of hundreds of channels.
  • 9:39 - 9:42
    And this makes a lot of sense
    because cable TV satisfies
  • 9:42 - 9:46
    all of our conditions
    for bundling to be profitable
  • 9:46 - 9:47
    and also to be efficient.
  • 9:48 - 9:51
    For example, people who are
    watching a lot of ESPN
  • 9:51 - 9:54
    are probably not watching
    a lot of Bravo, a lot of "Top Chef."
  • 9:54 - 9:58
    Not only do preferences differ,
    but there's only 24 hours in a day.
  • 9:58 - 10:00
    So if you're watching a lot
    of ESPN, you can't be watching
  • 10:00 - 10:03
    a lot of "Top Chef" and vice versa.
  • 10:03 - 10:08
    But this negative correlation
    among channel values creates
  • 10:08 - 10:12
    a bundle value, which goes closer
    to the mean, which becomes
  • 10:12 - 10:13
    more homogeneous.
  • 10:13 - 10:17
    And that's exactly what we require
    for bundling to be profitable.
  • 10:17 - 10:20
    In addition, marginal costs are zero.
  • 10:20 - 10:23
    So we don't have to worry
    about selling someone a channel
  • 10:23 - 10:25
    which they value
    at less than the cost.
  • 10:25 - 10:29
    We can give someone a channel for
    free without increasing our costs.
  • 10:30 - 10:34
    In addition, cable TV has
    got a lot of fixed costs.
  • 10:34 - 10:37
    First, the costs which are
    extensive of laying the cable,
  • 10:37 - 10:41
    and also the costs of producing
    the programming itself.
  • 10:41 - 10:44
    So for all of these reasons,
    negative correlation,
  • 10:44 - 10:47
    zero marginal cost
    and high fixed costs,
  • 10:47 - 10:51
    cable TV is an excellent candidate
    for bundling, but this makes
  • 10:51 - 10:54
    a lot of people very upset.
  • 10:54 - 10:57
    Because of negative correlation,
    people who watch football are
  • 10:57 - 11:00
    not watching "Top Chef"
    and people watching "Top Chef" are
  • 11:00 - 11:02
    not watching football,
    so some people feel that
  • 11:02 - 11:04
    they're being ripped off --
    that they're being forced to pay
  • 11:04 - 11:08
    for something that they don't use
    and there's kind of a naive theory
  • 11:08 - 11:10
    that if I'm paying a hundred dollars
  • 11:10 - 11:13
    for a hundred channels,
    then under á la carte pricing --
  • 11:13 - 11:16
    if only I wasn't forced
    to buy the package --
  • 11:16 - 11:20
    I'd be paying $1 per channel,
    and I'd buy only the channels
  • 11:20 - 11:21
    that I really want.
  • 11:21 - 11:24
    But, of course,
    that theory is wrong.
  • 11:24 - 11:27
    The per channel price
    would increase and would likely
  • 11:27 - 11:29
    increase rather dramatically.
  • 11:29 - 11:32
    Moreover, we know
    from the theory of bundling
  • 11:32 - 11:36
    that the firm makes the most profit
    when just about everyone is
  • 11:36 - 11:38
    getting the same value
    from the bundle.
  • 11:38 - 11:41
    So people shouldn't fear
    that they're being ripped off.
  • 11:41 - 11:43
    People who will watch "Top Chef" --
  • 11:43 - 11:45
    they're getting a lot of value
    from the bundle.
  • 11:45 - 11:47
    People watching football --
  • 11:47 - 11:49
    they're getting a lot of value
    from the bundle.
  • 11:49 - 11:51
    There's no reason
    to think that one party is
  • 11:51 - 11:52
    ripping the other party off.
  • 11:52 - 11:55
    Now maybe overall we'd be
    better with more competition,
  • 11:55 - 11:57
    but that's sort of
    a different question.
  • 11:58 - 12:02
    There's also in the case of cable TV,
    complicated dynamics
  • 12:02 - 12:05
    between consumers, distributors
    and content sellers.
  • 12:05 - 12:09
    It's unclear if you switch
    to á la carte pricing who would
  • 12:09 - 12:12
    really grab up
    that consumer surplus.
  • 12:12 - 12:14
    It's probably not going
    to be the consumers.
  • 12:14 - 12:17
    It might be the distributors
    who sometimes push
  • 12:17 - 12:18
    for á la carte pricing.
  • 12:18 - 12:20
    It might even be
    the content sellers,
  • 12:20 - 12:22
    but there'd be a lot of gaming
    of the system going on,
  • 12:22 - 12:25
    and it's not that all clear
    that consumers would win that game.
  • 12:26 - 12:30
    There would also be some increased
    costs if the cable companies had
  • 12:30 - 12:33
    to sell by channel and if people
    could have, you know,
  • 12:33 - 12:36
    all the combinations and permutations
    of different channels
  • 12:36 - 12:39
    which was possible, would likely
    increase transactions costs.
  • 12:39 - 12:41
    Maybe in this example
    only by a little bit.
  • 12:41 - 12:47
    Finally, if this decreased profits
    for the distributors,
  • 12:47 - 12:50
    which it would, that is going
    to have ultimate effects
  • 12:50 - 12:53
    on the quality and the number
    of channels, the number of content
  • 12:53 - 12:56
    providers, and how much
    they're willing to invest
  • 12:56 - 12:59
    in new programming,
    so overall my belief is
  • 12:59 - 13:02
    that bundling is actually
    good for consumers
  • 13:02 - 13:06
    and certainly not bad for consumers
    or not very bad for consumers.
  • 13:06 - 13:09
    We don't want to follow
    the naive theory.
  • 13:09 - 13:11
    Okay, let's make one more point.
  • 13:13 - 13:15
    Here's an interesting prediction
    from bundling theory.
  • 13:15 - 13:18
    Music is currently sold
    in two different ways.
  • 13:18 - 13:24
    iTunes sells more or less by the song,
    while something like Spotify
  • 13:24 - 13:29
    or similar services, they sell you
    a whole package or a whole bundle.
  • 13:29 - 13:33
    Bundling theory says that Spotify
    is going to win this competition --
  • 13:33 - 13:36
    that the profits are much
    greater for the bundler.
  • 13:36 - 13:41
    This is not only because
    of the price discrimination reasons
  • 13:41 - 13:42
    which we've been talking so far,
  • 13:42 - 13:46
    but in this case the transactions
    costs really do matter.
  • 13:46 - 13:50
    So when iTunes sells by the song,
    and it's 99 cents per song,
  • 13:50 - 13:54
    the cost of the credit card
    transaction can be
  • 13:54 - 13:57
    as much as a dollar,
    or a $1.20 or 50 cents.
  • 13:57 - 13:59
    It can be a significant cost,
  • 13:59 - 14:03
    significant percentage
    of the value of the song.
  • 14:03 - 14:08
    iTunes tries to handle this
    by only charging you, you know,
  • 14:08 - 14:10
    for every five songs,
    or every two or three days.
  • 14:10 - 14:14
    They try and combine
    as many purchases as possible,
  • 14:14 - 14:19
    but still the transactions costs
    of micropayments are quite large,
  • 14:19 - 14:22
    and that's another reason which is
    pushing the music business,
  • 14:22 - 14:24
    in my opinion, to Spotify.
  • 14:24 - 14:26
    So that's a little bit
    of investment advice.
  • 14:26 - 14:30
    Don't blame me if it doesn't work,
    but I think that the bundling
  • 14:30 - 14:32
    is going to win out.
  • 14:33 - 14:35
    Here's some places
    for further reading.
  • 14:35 - 14:38
    Adams and Yellen have a classic
    on commodity bundling.
  • 14:38 - 14:40
    You can easily find that on the web.
  • 14:40 - 14:45
    A favorite of mine, the Bakos
    and Brynjolfsson paper --
  • 14:45 - 14:47
    these authors actually wrote
    two papers on the subject --
  • 14:47 - 14:50
    either of them is
    certainly worth reading.
  • 14:50 - 14:56
    For a modern look at combining
    bundling and bargaining theory,
  • 14:56 - 14:59
    you can take a look
    at Crawford and Yurukoglu.
  • 14:59 - 15:02
    It's quite a complicated paper,
    putting together the industrial
  • 15:02 - 15:04
    organization of these two topics.
  • 15:04 - 15:07
    You may also want to go
    to Marginal Revolution,
  • 15:07 - 15:10
    my blog with Tyler,
    and search for cable TV bundling.
  • 15:10 - 15:13
    Both Tyler and I have short
    interesting posts on this topic.
  • 15:14 - 15:15
    Thanks.
  • 15:16 - 15:19
    - [Announcer] If you want to test
    yourself, click "Practice questions."
  • 15:19 - 15:24
    Or if you're ready to move on,
    just click "Next video."
  • 15:24 - 15:26
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Bundling
Description:

Bundling refers to when two or more goods are sold together as a package. Microsoft Office, Cable TV, Lexis-Nexis, and Spotify all provide examples of bundling. What if there were no bundling and you had to pay for Cable TV by channel rather than purchasing channels in bundles? Would you end up paying more or less? We explore this question and others in this video.

Microeconomics Course:http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomic

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/bundling-economics-examples#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/labor-economics-marginal-product-labor

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
15:29
Marilia_PM edited English subtitles for Bundling
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Bundling
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Bundling
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Bundling
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Bundling
Kirstin Cosper edited English subtitles for Bundling
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Bundling
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Bundling

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions