-
-
How the economic machine works, in 30 minutes.
-
The economy works like a simple machine.
-
But many people don't understand it
-
— or they don't agree on how it works
-
— and this has led to a lot of needless economic suffering.
-
I feel a deep sense of responsibility
-
to share my simple but practical economic template.
-
Though it's unconventional,
-
it has helped me to anticipate
and sidestep the global financial crisis,
-
and has worked well for me for over 30 years.
-
Let's begin.
-
Though the economy might seem complex,
it works in a simple, mechanical way.
-
It's made up of a few simple parts and a lot of simple transactions
-
that are repeated over and over again a zillion times.
-
These transactions are above all else driven by human nature,
-
and they create 3 main forces that drive the economy.
-
Number 1: Productivity growth
-
Number 2: The Short term debt cycle
-
and Number 3: The Long term debt cycle
-
We'll look at these three forces
and how laying them on top of each other
-
creates a good template for tracking economic movements
-
and figuring out what's happening now.
-
Let's start with the simplest part of the economy:
-
Transactions.
-
An economy is simply the sum
of the transactions that make it up
-
and a transaction is a very simple thing.
-
You make transactions all the time.
-
Every time you buy something
you create a transaction.
-
Each transaction consists of a buyer
-
exchanging money or credit
-
with a seller for goods,
services or financial assets.
-
Credit spends just like money,
-
so adding together the money spent
and the amount of credit spent,
-
you can know the total spending.
-
The total amount of spending
drives the economy.
-
If you divide the amount spent
-
by the quantity sold,
-
you get the price.
-
And that's it. That's a transaction.
-
It is the building block
of the economic machine.
-
All cycles and all forces
in an economy are driven by transactions.
-
So, if we can
understand transactions,
-
we can understand
the whole economy.
-
A market consists of all the buyers
-
and all the sellers
-
making transactions for the same thing.
-
For example,
there is a wheat market,
-
a car market,
-
a stock market
-
and markets
for millions of things.
-
An economy consists
of all of the transactions
-
in all of its markets.
-
If you add up
the total spending
-
and the total
quantity sold
-
in all of the markets,
-
you have everything
you need to know
-
to understand the economy.
-
It's just that simple.
-
People, businesses, banks and governments
-
all engage in transactions
the way I just described:
-
exchanging money and credit
for goods, services and financial assets.
-
The biggest buyer and seller
is the government,
-
which consists of two important parts:
-
a Central Government
that collects taxes and spends money...
-
...and a Central Bank,
-
which is different from other buyers
and sellers because it
-
controls the amount of money
and credit in the economy.
-
It does this by influencing
interest rates
-
and printing new money.
-
For these reasons,
as we'll see,
-
the Central Bank is an
important player in the flow
-
of Credit.
-
I want you to
pay attention to credit.
-
Credit is the most
important part of the economy,
-
and probably the least understood.
-
It is the most important part
because it is the biggest
-
and most volatile part.
-
Just like buyers and sellers
go to the market to make transactions,
-
so do lenders and borrowers.
-
Lenders usually want to
make their money into more money
-
and borrowers usually want to
buy something they can't afford,
-
like a house or car
-
or they want to invest in
something like starting a business.
-
Credit can help both lenders
-
and borrowers get what they want.
-
Borrowers promise to
repay the amount they borrow,
-
called the principal,
-
plus an additional amount, called interest.
-
When interest rates are high,
-
there is less borrowing
because it's expensive.
-
When interest rates are low,
-
borrowing increases
because it's cheaper.
-
When borrowers promise to repay
-
and lenders believe them,
-
credit is created.
-
Any two people can agree
to create credit out of thin air!
-
That seems simple enough
but credit is tricky
-
because it has different names.
-
As soon as credit is created,
-
it immediately turns into debt.
-
Debt is both an asset to the lender,
-
and a liability to the borrower.
-
In the future,
-
when the borrower repays the loan,
plus interest,
-
the asset and liability disappear
-
and the transaction is settled.
-
So, why is credit so important?
-
Because when a borrower receives credit,
-
he is able to increase his spending.
-
And remember,
spending drives the economy.
-
This is because one person's spending
-
is another person's income.
-
Think about it,
every dollar you spend, someone else earns.
-
and every dollar you earn,
someone else has spent.
-
So when you spend more,
someone else earns more.
-
When someone's income rises
-
it makes lenders more willing
to lend him money
-
because now he's
more worthy of credit.
-
A creditworthy borrower
has two things:
-
the ability to repay and collateral.
-
Having a lot of income in relation to his debt gives him the ability to repay.
-
In the event that he can't repay, he has valuable assets to use as collateral that can be sold.
-
This makes lenders feel comfortable lending him money.
-
So increased income allows increased borrowing
-
which allows increased spending.
-
And since one person's spending is another person's income,
-
this leads to more increased borrowing and so on.
-
This self-reinforcing pattern leads to economic growth
-
and is why we have Cycles.
-
In a transaction, you have to give something in order to get something
-
and how much you get depends on how much
you produce
-
over time we learned
-
and that accumulated knowledge raises
are living standards
-
we call this productivity growth
-
those who were invented and hard-working raise
-
their productivity and their living
standards faster
-
than those who are complacent and lazy,
-
but that isn't necessarily true over the short run.
-
Productivity matters most in the long run, but credit matters most in the short run.
-
This is because productivity growth doesn't fluctuate much,
-
so it's not a big driver of economic swings.
-
Debt is — because it allows us to consume more than we produce when we acquire it
-
and it forces us to consume less than we produce when we pay it back.
-
Debt swings occur in two big cycles.
-
One takes about 5 to 10 years and the other takes about 75 to 100 years.
-
While most people feel the swings, they typically don't see them as cycles
-
because they see them too up close -- day by day, week by week.
-
In this chapter we are going to step back and look at these three big forces
-
and how they interact to make up our experiences.
-
As mentioned, swings around the line are not due to how much innovation or hard work there is,
-
they're primarily due to how much credit there is.
-
Let's for a second imagine an economy without credit.
-
In this economy, the only way I can increase my spending
-
is to increase my income,
-
which requires me to be more productive and do more work.
-
Increased productivity is the only way for growth.
-
Since my spending is another person's income,
-
the economy grows every time I or anyone else is more productive.
-
If we follow the transactions and play this out,
-
we see a progression like the productivity growth line.
-
But because we borrow, we have cycles.
-
This isn't due to any laws or regulation,
-
it's due to human nature and the way that credit works.
-
Think of borrowing as simply a way of pulling spending forward.
-
In order to buy something you can't afford, you need to spend more than you make.
-
To do this, you essentially need to borrow from your future self.
-
In doing so you create a time in the future
-
that you need to spend less than you make in order to pay it back.
-
It very quickly resembles a cycle.
-
Basically, anytime you borrow you create a cycle.?
-
This is as true for an individual as it is for the economy.
-
This is why understanding credit is so important
-
because it sets into motion
-
a mechanical, predictable series of events that will happen in the future.
-
This makes credit different from money.
-
Money is what you settle transactions with.
-
When you buy a beer from a bartender with cash,
-
the transaction is settled immediately.
-
But when you buy a beer with credit,
-
it's like starting a bar tab.
-
You're saying you promise to pay in the future.
-
Together you and the bartender create an asset and a liability.
-
You just created credit. Out of thin air.
-
It's not until you pay the bar tab later
-
that the asset and liability disappear,
-
the debt goes away
-
and the transaction is settled.
-
The reality is that most of what people call money is actually credit.
-
The total amount of credit in the United States is about $50 trillion
-
and the total amount of money is only about $3 trillion.
-
Remember, in an economy without credit:
-
the only way to increase your spending is to produce more.
-
But in an economy with credit,
-
you can also increase your spending by borrowing.
-
As a result, an economy with credit has more spending
-
and allows incomes to rise faster than productivity over the short run,
-
but not over the long run.
-
Now, don't get me wrong,
-
credit isn't necessarily something bad that just causes cycles.
-
It's bad when it finances over-consumption that can't be paid back.
-
However, it's good when it efficiently allocates resources
-
and produces income so you can pay back the debt.
-
For example, if you borrow money to buy a big TV,
-
it doesn't generate income
for you to pay back the debt.
-
But, if you borrow money
to buy a tractor —
-
and that tractor let's you harvest
more crops and earn more money
-
— then, you can pay back your debt
-
and improve your living standards.
-
In an economy with credit,
-
we can follow the transactions
-
and see how credit creates growth.
-
Let me give you an example:
-
Suppose you earn $100,000 a year and have no debt.
-
You are creditworthy enough to borrow $10,000 dollars
-
- say on a credit card
-
- so you can spend $110,000 dollars
-
even though you only earn $100,000 dollars.
-
Since your spending is another person's income,
-
someone is earning $110,000 dollars.
-
The person earning $110,000 dollars
-
with no debt can borrow $11,000 dollars,
-
so he can spend $121,000 dollars
-
even though he has only earned $110,000 dollars.
-
His spending is another person's income
-
and by following the transactions
-
we can begin to see how this process
-
works in a self-reinforcing pattern.
-
But remember, borrowing creates cycles
-
and if the cycle goes up, it eventually needs to come down.
-
This leads us into the Short Term Debt Cycle.
-
As economic activity increases, we see an expansion
-
- the first phase of the short term debt cycle.
-
Spending continues to increase and prices start to rise.
-
This happens because the increase in spending is fueled by credit
-
- which can be created instantly out of thin air.
-
When the amount of spending and incomes grow faster than the production of goods:
-
prices rise.
-
When prices rise, we call this inflation.
-
The Central Bank doesn't want too much inflation
-
because it causes problems.
-
Seeing prices rise, it raises interest rates.
-
With higher interest rates, fewer people can afford to borrow money.
-
And the cost of existing debts rises.
-
Think about this as the monthly payments
on your credit card going up.
-
Because people borrow less and have higher debt repayments,
-
they have less money leftover to spend, so spending slows
-
...and since one person's spending is another person's income,
-
incomes drop...and so on and so forth.
-
When people spend less, prices go down.
-
We call this deflation.
-
Economic activity decreases and we have a recession.
-
If the recession becomes too severe
-
and inflation is no longer a problem,
-
the central bank will lower interest rates to cause everything to pick up again.
-
With low interest rates,
-
debt repayments are reduced
-
and borrowing and spending pick up
-
and we see another expansion.
-
As you can see, the economy works like a machine.
-
In the short term debt cycle,
spending is constrained only by the willingness of
-
lenders and borrowers to provide and receive credit.
-
When credit is easily available,
there's an economic expansion.
-
When credit isn't easily available,
there's a recession.
-
And note that this cycle is controlled primarily by the central bank.
-
The short term debt cycle typically lasts 5 - 8 years
-
and happens over and over again for decades.
-
But notice that the bottom and
-
top of each cycle finish
-
with more growth than the previous cycle and with more debt.
-
Why?
-
Because people push it
-
— they have an inclination to borrow
and spend more instead of paying back debt.
-
It's human nature.
-
Because of this,
-
over long periods of time,
-
debts rise faster than incomes
-
creating the Long Term Debt Cycle.
-
Despite people becoming more indebted,
-
lenders even more freely extend credit.
-
Why?
-
Because everybody thinks things are going great!
-
People are just focusing on what's been happening lately.
-
And what has been happening lately?
-
Incomes have been rising!
-
Asset values are going up!
-
The stock market roars!
-
It's a boom!
-
It pays to buy goods, services, and financial assets
-
with borrowed money!
-
When people do a lot of that, we call it a bubble.
-
So even though debts have been growing,
-
incomes have been growing nearly as fast to offset them.
-
Let's call the ratio of debt-to-income the debt burden.
-
So long as incomes continue to rise,
-
the debt burden stays manageable.
-
At the same time asset values soar.
-
People borrow huge amounts of money
-
to buy assets as investments
-
causing their prices to rise even higher.
-
People feel wealthy.
-
So even with the accumulation of lots of debt,
-
rising incomes and asset values
help borrowers remain creditworthy for a long time.
-
But this obviously can not continue forever.
-
And it doesn't.
-
Over decades, debt burdens slowly increase
creating larger and larger debt repayments.
-
At some point, debt repayments start growing faster than incomes
-
forcing people to cut back on their spending.
-
And since one person's spending is another person's income,
-
incomes begin to go down...
-
...which makes people less creditworthy
causing borrowing to go down.
-
Debt repayments continue to rise
-
which makes spending drop even further...
-
...and the cycle reverses itself.
-
This is the long term debt peak.
-
Debt burdens have simply become too big.
-
For the United States, Europe and much of the rest of the world this
-
happened in 2008.
-
It happened for the same reason it happened in Japan in 1989
-
and in the United States back in 1929.
-
Now the economy begins Deleveraging.
-
In a deleveraging; people cut spending,
-
incomes fall, credit disappears,
-
assets prices drop, banks get squeezed,
-
the stock market crashes, social tensions rise
-
and the whole thing starts to feed on itself the other way.
-
As incomes fall and debt repayments rise,
-
borrowers get squeezed.
No longer creditworthy,
-
credit dries up and borrowers can no longer borrow
enough money to make their
-
debt repayments.
-
Scrambling to fill this hole, borrowers are forced to sell assets.
-
The rush to sell assets floods the market
-
This is when the stock market collapses,
-
the real estate market tanks and banks get into trouble.
-
As asset prices drop, the value of the collateral borrowers can put up drops.
-
This makes borrowers even less creditworthy.
-
People feel poor.
-
Credit rapidly disappears.
Less spending ›
-
less income ›
-
less wealth ›
-
less credit ›
-
less borrowing and so on.
-
It's a vicious cycle.
-
This appears similar to a recession but the difference here
-
is that interest rates can't be lowered to save the day.
-
In a recession, lowering interest rates works to stimulate the borrowing.
-
However, in a deleveraging, lowering interest rates doesn't work because
-
interest rates are already
-
low and soon hit 0% - so the stimulation ends.
-
Interest rates in the United States hit 0% during the deleveraging of
-
the 1930s
-
and again in 2008.
-
The difference between a recession
-
and a deleveraging is that in a deleveraging borrowers' debt burdens have
-
simply gotten too big
-
and can't be relieved by lowering interest rates.
-
Lenders realize that debts have become too large to ever be fully paid back.
-
Borrowers have lost their ability to repay and their collateral has lost value.
-
They feel crippled by the debt - they don't even want more!
-
Lenders stop lending.
Borrowers stop borrowing.
-
Think of the economy as being not-creditworthy,
-
just like an individual.
-
So what do you do about a deleveraging?
-
The problem is debt burdens are too high and they must come down.
-
There are four ways this can happen.
-
1. people, businesses, and governments cut their spending.
-
2. debts are reduced through defaults and restructurings.
-
3. wealth is redistributed from the 'haves' to the 'have nots'.
-
and finally, 4. the central bank prints new money.
-
These 4 ways have happened in every deleveraging in modern history.
-
Usually, spending is cut first.
-
As we just saw, people, businesses, banks and even governments tighten their belts and
-
cut their spending so that they can pay down their debt.
-
This is often referred to as austerity.
-
When borrowers stop taking on new debts,
-
and start paying down old debts, you might expect the debt burden to decrease.
-
But the opposite happens!
Because spending is cut
-
- and one man's spending is another man's income - it causes
-
incomes to fall.
They fall faster than debts are repaid
-
and the debt burden actually gets worse.
As we've seen,
-
this cut in spending is deflationary and painful.
-
Businesses are forced to cut costs...
-
which means less jobs and higher unemployment.
-
This leads to the next step: debts must be reduced!
-
Many borrowers find themselves unable to repay their loans
-
— and a borrower's debts are a lender's assets.
-
When borrowers don't repay the bank,
people get nervous that the bank won't
-
be able to repay them
-
so they rush to withdraw their money from the bank.
Banks get squeezed and
-
people,
-
businesses and banks default on their debts.
This severe
-
economic contraction is a depression.
-
A big part of a depression is people discovering much of what they thought
-
was their wealth isn't really there.
-
Let's go back to the bar.
-
When you bought a beer and put it on a bar tab,
-
you promised to repay the bartender.
Your promise became an asset of the bartender.
-
But if you break your promise
- if you don't pay him back and essentially default
-
on your bar tab -
-
then the 'asset' he has isn't really worth anything.
-
It has basically disappeared.
-
Many lenders don't want their assets to disappear and agree to debt
-
restructuring.
-
Debt restructuring means lenders get paid back
-
less or get paid back over a longer time frame
-
or at a lower interest rate that was first agreed.
Somehow
-
a contract is broken in a way that reduces debt.
Lenders would rather have a
-
little of something than all of nothing.
-
Even though debt disappears, debt restructuring causes
-
income and asset values to disappear
faster,
-
so the debt burden continues to gets worse.
-
Like cutting spending, debt reduction
-
is also painful and deflationary.
-
All of this impacts the central government because lower incomes and less employment
-
means the government collects fewer taxes.
-
At the same time it needs to increase its spending because unemployment has risen.
-
Many of the unemployed have inadequate savings
-
and need financial support from the government.
-
Additionally, governments create stimulus plans
-
and increase their spending to make up for the decrease in the economy.
-
Governments' budget deficits explode in a
-
deleveraging because they spend more than they earn in taxes.
-
This is what is happening when you hear about the budget deficit on the news.
-
To fund their deficits, governments need to either raise taxes
-
or borrow money.
But with incomes falling and so many unemployed,
-
who is the money going to come from?
The rich.
-
Since governments need more money and since wealth is heavily concentrated in
-
the hands of a small percentage of the people,
-
governments naturally raise taxes on the wealthy
-
which facilitates a redistribution of wealth in the economy -
-
from the 'haves' to the 'have nots'.
The 'have-nots,' who are suffering, begin to
-
resent the wealthy 'haves.'
-
The wealthy 'haves,' being squeezed by the weak economy, falling asset prices,
-
higher taxes, begin to resent the 'have nots.'
-
If the depression continues social disorder can break out.
-
Not only do tensions rise within countries,
-
they can rise between countries - especially debtor and creditor countries.
-
This situation can lead to political change
-
that can sometimes be extreme.
-
In the 1930s, this led to Hitler coming to power,
-
war in Europe, and depression in the United States. Pressure to do something
-
to end the depression increases.
-
Remember, most of what people thought was money was actually credit.
-
So, when credit disappears, people don't have enough money.
-
People are desperate for money and you remember who can print money?
-
The Central Bank can.
-
Having already lowered its interest rates to nearly 0
-
- it's forced to print money. Unlike cutting spending,
-
debt reduction, and wealth redistribution,
-
printing money is inflationary and stimulative. Inevitably, the central bank
-
prints new money
-
— out of thin air — and uses it to buy financial assets
-
and government bonds. It happened in the United States during the Great Depression
-
and again in 2008, when the United States' central bank —
-
the Federal Reserve — printed over two trillion dollars.
-
Other central banks around the world that could,
printed a lot of money, too.
-
By buying financial assets with this money,
-
it helps drive up asset prices which makes people more creditworthy.
-
However, this only helps those who own financial assets.
-
You see, the central bank can print money but it can only buy financial assets.
-
The Central Government, on the other hand,
-
can buy goods and services and put money in the hands of the people
-
but it can't print money. So, in order to stimulate the economy, the two
-
must cooperate.
-
By buying government bonds, the Central Bank essentially lends money to the
-
government,
-
allowing it to run a deficit and increase spending
-
on goods and services through its stimulus programs
-
and unemployment benefits. This increases people's income
-
as well as the government's debt. However,
-
it will lower the economy's total debt burden.
-
This is a very risky time. Policy makers need to balance the four ways that debt
-
burdens come down.
-
The deflationary ways need to balance with the inflationary ways in
-
order to maintain stability.
-
If balanced correctly, there can be a
-
Beautiful Deleveraging.
-
You see, a deleveraging can be ugly or it can be beautiful.
-
How can a deleveraging be beautiful?
-
Even though a deleveraging is a difficult situation,
-
handling a difficult situation in the best possible way is beautiful.
-
A lot more beautiful than the debt-fueled, unbalanced excesses of the
-
leveraging phase.
In a beautiful deleveraging,
-
debts decline relative to income, real economic growth is positive,
-
and inflation isn't a problem.
It is achieved by having the right balance.
-
The right balance requires a certain mix
-
of cutting spending, reducing debt, transferring wealth
-
and printing money so that economic and social stability can be maintained.
-
People ask if printing money will raise inflation.
-
It won't if it offsets falling credit.
Remember, spending is what matters.
-
A dollar of spending paid for with money has the same effect on price as a dollar
-
of spending paid for with credit.
-
By printing money, the Central Bank can make up for the disappearance of credit
-
with an increase in the amount of money.
-
In order to turn things around, the Central Bank needs to not only pump up
-
income growth
-
but get the rate of income growth higher than the rate of interest on the
-
accumulated debt.
-
So, what do I mean by that? Basically,
-
income needs to grow faster than debt grows. For example:
-
let's assume that a country going through a deleveraging has a debt-to-
-
income ratio of 100%.
-
That means that the amount of debt it has is the same as the amount of income the
-
entire country makes in a year.
-
Now think about the interest rate on that debt,
-
let's say it is 2%.
-
If debt is growing at 2% because of that interest rate and
-
income
-
is only growing at around only 1%, you will never reduce the debt burden.
-
You need to print enough money to get the rate of income growth above the
-
rate of interest.
-
However, printing money can easily be abused because it's so easy to do and
-
people prefer it to the alternatives.
-
The key is to avoid printing too much money
-
and causing unacceptably high inflation, the way Germany did during its
-
deleveraging in the 1920's.
-
If policymakers achieve the right balance, a deleveraging isn't so dramatic.
-
Growth is slow but debt burdens go down.
-
That's a beautiful deleveraging.
-
When incomes begin to rise, borrowers begin to appear more creditworthy.
-
And when borrowers appear more creditworthy,
-
lenders begin to lend money again.
Debt burdens finally begin to fall.
-
Able to borrow money, people can spend more. Eventually, the economy begins to
-
grow again,
-
leading to the reflation phase of the long term debt cycle.
-
Though the deleveraging process can be horrible if handled badly,
-
if handled well, it will eventually fix the problem.
-
It takes roughly a decade or more
-
for debt burdens to fall and economic activity to get back to normal
-
- hence the term 'lost decade.'
-
Of course, the economy is a little more complicated than this template
-
suggests.
-
However, laying the short term debt cycle on top of the long term debt cycle
-
and then laying both of them on top of the productivity growth line
-
gives a reasonably good template for seeing where we've been,
-
where we are now and where we are probably headed.
-
So in summary, there are three rules of thumb that I'd like you to take away
-
from this:
-
First:
Don't have debt rise faster than income,
-
because your debt burdens will eventually crush you.
-
Second:
Don't have income rise faster than productivity,
-
because you will eventually become uncompetitive.
-
And third:
Do all that you can to raise your productivity,
-
because, in the long run, that's what matters most.
-
This is simple advice for you and it's simple advice for policy makers.
-
You might be surprised but most people — including most policy makers — don't pay enough attention
-
to this.
-
This template has worked for me and I hope that it'll work for you.
-
Thank you.