Return to Video

Arguments Against International trade

  • 0:01 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:13
    - [Alex] In our previous videos,
    we explained the benefits of trade.
  • 0:13 - 0:16
    Today we're going to evaluate
    some of the arguments
  • 0:16 - 0:19
    that one often hears
    about limiting international trade.
  • 0:25 - 0:28
    International trade is
    a controversial subject.
  • 0:28 - 0:30
    There's a lot of arguments
    surrounding it.
  • 0:30 - 0:32
    We're not going to go through all
    of them by any means.
  • 0:32 - 0:33
    But here are some
    of the most common:
  • 0:33 - 0:38
    That trade reduces the number
    of jobs in the United States.
  • 0:38 - 0:41
    That it's wrong to trade
    with countries that use child labor.
  • 0:41 - 0:46
    That we need to keep certain jobs
    at home for national security.
  • 0:46 - 0:48
    We need to keep certain
    key industries at home
  • 0:48 - 0:53
    because of beneficial spillovers
    onto other sectors of the economy.
  • 0:53 - 0:56
    And we can increase
    U.S. well-being, the argument goes,
  • 0:56 - 0:59
    with strategic trade protectionism.
  • 0:59 - 1:00
    So we're going to evaluate, say,
  • 1:00 - 1:03
    a few things about each one
    of these arguments.
  • 1:03 - 1:05
    Let's consider trade and jobs.
  • 1:05 - 1:08
    What happens when
    a tariff is lowered?
  • 1:08 - 1:11
    Well, imports will increase,
    and there will be fewer jobs
  • 1:11 - 1:14
    in the import competing industry.
  • 1:14 - 1:17
    For example, if we have a tariff
    on shoes and we reduce the tariff,
  • 1:17 - 1:21
    we'll have imports of more shoes
    from China and from Vietnam,
  • 1:21 - 1:23
    and that will mean fewer jobs
  • 1:23 - 1:26
    in the American
    shoe-producing industry.
  • 1:26 - 1:31
    That's what people see when
    they think about reducing a tariff.
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    They're worried about losing those
    jobs in the American industry.
  • 1:34 - 1:39
    However, we want to see
    the issue in a deeper way,
  • 1:39 - 1:45
    in a more fundamental way,
    and a key question to ask is,
  • 1:45 - 1:50
    "Why do people send us goods?
    Why would workers in China
  • 1:50 - 1:54
    and Vietnam work long hours
    to send us shoes?"
  • 1:54 - 1:57
    It's certainly not from
    the kindness of their heart.
  • 1:57 - 2:03
    Ultimately, they want goods
    in return, goods or services.
  • 2:04 - 2:08
    They are working -- they are
    producing in order to consume.
  • 2:08 - 2:12
    They are sending us goods
    because they want goods in return.
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    They are not doing it out
    of the goodness of their hearts,
  • 2:15 - 2:19
    but out of self-interest
    as Adam Smith said.
  • 2:20 - 2:25
    And that leads to a fundamental
    insight about international trade.
  • 2:26 - 2:31
    Namely, we pay
    for our imports with exports.
  • 2:31 - 2:38
    When we import more,
    we will ultimately export more
  • 2:38 - 2:43
    because we pay for our imports
    through our exports.
  • 2:44 - 2:50
    What this means is that trade
    doesn't destroy jobs overall.
  • 2:50 - 2:55
    Trade moves jobs
    from import-competing industries
  • 2:55 - 3:01
    to export industries, and overall,
    wages increase on average
  • 3:01 - 3:03
    because of comparative advantage.
  • 3:03 - 3:07
    Because we pay
    for our imports with exports,
  • 3:07 - 3:10
    when we import more,
    we will export more.
  • 3:11 - 3:16
    Jobs will reduce in the import
    competing industries and increase
  • 3:16 - 3:17
    in the export industries.
  • 3:18 - 3:21
    Now, this process is
    not always easy.
  • 3:21 - 3:25
    Problems can occur when we lose
    jobs in low-skill import-competing
  • 3:25 - 3:29
    sectors and gain jobs
    in high-skill export sectors.
  • 3:29 - 3:33
    Overall, when the United States
    imports goods, we typically
  • 3:33 - 3:37
    import goods produced by low-skill,
    because America on average
  • 3:37 - 3:40
    is a high-skill economy,
    has high-skilled workers
  • 3:40 - 3:44
    on a world level, but we do have
    some low-skill workers,
  • 3:44 - 3:48
    and imports tend to compete
    with the products
  • 3:48 - 3:50
    produced by low-skilled workers.
  • 3:50 - 3:54
    Everything will be fine
    if our education system is
  • 3:54 - 3:57
    working well, and if those
    low-skill workers can increase
  • 3:57 - 3:59
    their skills and move
    to high-tech --
  • 3:59 - 4:03
    or high-skill, not necessarily
    high-tech -- high-skill sectors.
  • 4:04 - 4:09
    Of course, that's a big "if,"
    and the transition can be difficult.
  • 4:09 - 4:12
    We have to put this
    in context, however.
  • 4:12 - 4:17
    In a growing economy, jobs are
    appearing and disappearing
  • 4:17 - 4:20
    all the time, not just
    or even fundamentally because
  • 4:20 - 4:22
    of international trade,
    but because of changes
  • 4:22 - 4:24
    in preferences
    and changes in technology.
  • 4:25 - 4:26
    Let's take a look at that.
  • 4:27 - 4:29
    It's important when thinking
  • 4:29 - 4:31
    about trade and jobs
    and jobs in general
  • 4:31 - 4:37
    that the American economy succeeds
    precisely because jobs are being
  • 4:37 - 4:40
    created and destroyed
    all the time.
  • 4:41 - 4:46
    Job destruction is often a sign
    of progress and growth.
  • 4:46 - 4:48
    Think about Thomas Edison.
  • 4:48 - 4:52
    He destroyed the whaling industry
    with his invention of the light bulb.
  • 4:53 - 4:56
    CDs -- some of you may not even
    remember compact discs --
  • 4:56 - 5:00
    they destroyed jobs
    in the record industry.
  • 5:00 - 5:04
    MP3s destroyed jobs
    in the CD industry.
  • 5:04 - 5:07
    This is the way progress
    often occurs.
  • 5:07 - 5:11
    Employment and the standard
    of living overall keep rising
  • 5:11 - 5:16
    over time, and the reason they're
    rising is precisely that old jobs
  • 5:16 - 5:19
    are being destroyed,
    new jobs are being created.
  • 5:19 - 5:26
    Overall, in the churn,
    there's a trend towards richer jobs,
  • 5:26 - 5:28
    higher-paying jobs, higher wages.
  • 5:28 - 5:33
    Overall technology, trade,
    these benefit the U.S. economy.
  • 5:35 - 5:37
    Child labor is something
    which no one wants,
  • 5:37 - 5:40
    but it's important to understand
    that child labor is something
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    which happens when people are poor.
  • 5:43 - 5:46
    Child labor was common
    in 19th century Great Britain
  • 5:46 - 5:47
    and the United States.
  • 5:47 - 5:50
    Child labor declined
    in the developed world
  • 5:50 - 5:52
    as people got richer.
  • 5:52 - 5:57
    Forces that reduced child labor
    in the developed world are also
  • 5:57 - 5:59
    at work in the developing countries.
  • 5:59 - 6:02
    As countries become richer,
    child labor declines.
  • 6:02 - 6:07
    What this graph shows is that
    as real GDP per capita increases,
  • 6:07 - 6:12
    the percent of children ages 10
    to 14 in the labor force decreases.
  • 6:12 - 6:15
    So increases in real GDP reduce
  • 6:15 - 6:18
    the percent of children
    in the labor force.
  • 6:18 - 6:23
    The circles, by the way, are
    proportional to the absolute number
  • 6:23 - 6:26
    of children in the labor force,
    so in China, for example,
  • 6:26 - 6:29
    there are about 12 percent
    of kids in the labor force,
  • 6:29 - 6:32
    but because there are so many
    Chinese children, that's
  • 6:32 - 6:36
    a large number of children
    in absolute numbers.
  • 6:36 - 6:38
    Again the key here is really
  • 6:38 - 6:41
    that economic growth
    reduces child labor.
  • 6:42 - 6:47
    So if you want to reduce child labor
    you want a country to become rich.
  • 6:47 - 6:52
    The question is, "Can one
    accelerate this process by banning
  • 6:52 - 6:59
    child labor or by refusing to trade
    with countries that use child labor?"
  • 6:59 - 7:03
    That's really refusing to trade
    with the poorest of countries.
  • 7:03 - 7:05
    Do we really want to do that?
  • 7:05 - 7:07
    Do we really want
    to say to poor countries,
  • 7:07 - 7:09
    "We're not going to trade with you."
  • 7:09 - 7:13
    There are many opportunities
    here for unintended consequences
  • 7:13 - 7:18
    of laws which may have been trying
    to do a good thing but backfire.
  • 7:18 - 7:22
    So, for example, when India
    banned child labor,
  • 7:22 - 7:27
    one of the effects of that was
    to reduce the wages of children
  • 7:27 - 7:29
    because now you have
    to hire them under the table.
  • 7:29 - 7:33
    Because their wages were lower,
    the families were poorer,
  • 7:33 - 7:35
    and because the families
    were poorer,
  • 7:35 - 7:38
    they had to rely
    even more on child labor.
  • 7:38 - 7:44
    So it is very easy to create
    a policy which backfires.
  • 7:45 - 7:52
    It is not, in my view, a good idea
    to use international trade
  • 7:52 - 7:57
    as a weapon or as a tool
    against child labor.
  • 7:57 - 8:01
    A much better idea would be
    to help poor countries,
  • 8:01 - 8:05
    would be to offer free schooling
    in poor countries,
  • 8:05 - 8:09
    to offer lunches for schools
    in poor countries.
  • 8:09 - 8:13
    This increases the incentive
    to send the children to school
  • 8:13 - 8:14
    because then they are fed.
  • 8:15 - 8:18
    So there are lots of things we can
    do to reduce child labor
  • 8:18 - 8:21
    in poorer countries,
    but to say to those countries,
  • 8:21 - 8:25
    "We're not going to trade with you
    because you're poor
  • 8:25 - 8:28
    and you're using child labor
    just exactly the same way
  • 8:28 - 8:30
    we did in the 19th century."
  • 8:31 - 8:35
    That is really not in my view
    a productive policy.
  • 8:36 - 8:39
    Trade and national security.
    Yeah, some industries probably
  • 8:39 - 8:42
    should be protected
    to protect national security.
  • 8:42 - 8:45
    The problem is this argument
    is subject to great abuse.
  • 8:45 - 8:48
    Almost every industry can
    and does make the claim
  • 8:48 - 8:51
    that they're essential
    for national security.
  • 8:51 - 8:53
    So let's give some examples.
    Vaccine production?
  • 8:53 - 8:58
    Yes, probably a good idea for us
    to have some domestic capability.
  • 8:58 - 9:02
    We don't always want to buy our
    vaccines from abroad, just in case.
  • 9:02 - 9:05
    Angora goat fleece? Am I serious?
  • 9:05 - 9:10
    Yes. Believe it or not,
    we have protected Angora goats
  • 9:10 - 9:13
    with the argument
    that their fleece is necessary
  • 9:13 - 9:16
    to produce military uniforms.
  • 9:16 - 9:19
    Yep, some people think goats
    are vital to national security.
  • 9:19 - 9:21
    I'm not kidding.
  • 9:22 - 9:26
    The key industries argument is very
    popular among the high-tech crowd.
  • 9:26 - 9:30
    The argument is, is that there are
    some industries, which for a variety
  • 9:30 - 9:34
    of reasons, are especially important
    for a nation to have a foothold in.
  • 9:34 - 9:37
    "Biology, microbiology is going
    to be the future,
  • 9:37 - 9:40
    therefore we need
    to have this type of industry."
  • 9:40 - 9:42
    Or, "Computers are the future,
  • 9:42 - 9:44
    therefore we need to have
    this type of industry."
  • 9:44 - 9:46
    The argument is that
    these industries create spillovers
  • 9:46 - 9:48
    for other industries.
  • 9:48 - 9:53
    They create learning, they create
    research, they create workers,
  • 9:53 - 9:57
    high-tech workers, which spread out
    to other areas of the economy
  • 9:57 - 10:03
    and benefit the economy in ways
    which go beyond the GDP
  • 10:03 - 10:05
    produced by those
    particular industries.
  • 10:05 - 10:07
    Ross Perot famously made
    this argument when he said,
  • 10:07 - 10:11
    "Producing computer chips is
    better than potato chips."
  • 10:11 - 10:13
    In some ways this may be true,
  • 10:13 - 10:16
    but it's overall not
    a compelling argument.
  • 10:16 - 10:19
    For example, today
    most computer chips are
  • 10:19 - 10:20
    cheap, mass-produced products.
  • 10:20 - 10:23
    They're not something we really
    want to be producing at all.
  • 10:23 - 10:25
    They're not even produced
    with a lot of labor.
  • 10:25 - 10:29
    They're mostly produced
    in big factories which don't
  • 10:29 - 10:31
    actually make lot of money.
  • 10:31 - 10:34
    Much better to design the product
    the way Apple does,
  • 10:34 - 10:38
    making lots of profit,
    than to buy the chips which Apple
  • 10:38 - 10:42
    uses in its iPhones, which don't
    make a lot of money at all.
  • 10:42 - 10:47
    In 1990, Walmart contributed
    more to the boom in productivity
  • 10:47 - 10:48
    than Silicon Valley.
  • 10:48 - 10:52
    So it's always difficult
    to say exactly which are
  • 10:52 - 10:55
    the most important industries.
  • 10:55 - 10:57
    You wouldn't think
    that Walmart retail is
  • 10:57 - 11:01
    a hugely important industry,
    and yet, Walmart is
  • 11:01 - 11:05
    the world's largest firm,
    and it has done a huge amount
  • 11:05 - 11:08
    to make the American economy
    more productive.
  • 11:09 - 11:11
    So no one really knows
    which industries are the ones
  • 11:11 - 11:14
    with the really important
    spillovers, and when we add
  • 11:14 - 11:19
    in political economy, the tendency
    for politics to often choose
  • 11:19 - 11:21
    based upon the wrong reasons --
  • 11:21 - 11:23
    this argument is really
    not very compelling.
  • 11:24 - 11:26
    Here's an argument
    which again works in theory,
  • 11:26 - 11:28
    but is less likely
    to work in practice.
  • 11:28 - 11:31
    It's possible for a country
    to use tariffs and quotas
  • 11:31 - 11:35
    to get a larger share
    of the gains from trade.
  • 11:35 - 11:40
    The argument here is that
    if you can limit or tax exports,
  • 11:40 - 11:44
    not tax imports, but tax exports,
  • 11:44 - 11:48
    then you can let domestic firms
    act as a cartel,
  • 11:48 - 11:52
    so it's a way of helping
    domestic firms to be more
  • 11:52 - 11:54
    like a monopoly,
    to act like a cartel.
  • 11:55 - 11:58
    So the government
    plus the domestic firms put --
  • 11:58 - 12:03
    creates a tax, or limits exports,
    in order to raise the price
  • 12:03 - 12:07
    of those exports on world markets
    and in order to grab up
  • 12:07 - 12:09
    more of the gains from trade.
  • 12:09 - 12:12
    It can work, especially
    if there are few substitutes
  • 12:12 - 12:14
    for U.S.-produced goods.
  • 12:14 - 12:17
    On the other hand, if there are
    substitutes for U.S.-produced goods,
  • 12:17 - 12:20
    or if we push the price
    of our goods up too high,
  • 12:20 - 12:23
    and that creates the substitutes,
    we may in the long run
  • 12:23 - 12:25
    really reduce our market.
  • 12:25 - 12:31
    Moreover, these arguments
    for strategic trade protectionism
  • 12:31 - 12:35
    are not such a great idea
    if other countries can retaliate.
  • 12:35 - 12:40
    If every country tries to do this,
    then world trade as a whole will
  • 12:40 - 12:43
    shrink and no country
    will be better off.
  • 12:43 - 12:47
    So in trying to grab up
    a larger slice of the pie,
  • 12:47 - 12:50
    we have to always be worried
    about making the pie smaller.
  • 12:51 - 12:53
    Again, the argument works in theory.
  • 12:53 - 12:58
    A very clever government might
    be able to do it, but in practice,
  • 12:58 - 13:00
    this is really not a very good
    reason for limiting trade.
  • 13:01 - 13:05
    So to sum up, restrictions
    on trade waste resources
  • 13:05 - 13:08
    by transferring production
    from low-cost foreign producers
  • 13:08 - 13:11
    to high-cost domestic producers.
  • 13:11 - 13:14
    Restrictions on trade
    also prevent domestic consumers
  • 13:14 - 13:17
    from exploiting all
    of the gains from trade.
  • 13:17 - 13:20
    There are some good arguments
    for restricting trade.
  • 13:20 - 13:22
    Some arguments are
    valid, but they're usually
  • 13:22 - 13:24
    of limited applicability.
  • 13:24 - 13:30
    Overall, I think free trade is
    a robust policy in the sense
  • 13:30 - 13:35
    of it's a policy which works
    well in most circumstances,
  • 13:35 - 13:37
    and protectionism will work well
  • 13:37 - 13:40
    only in a limited number
    of circumstances.
  • 13:40 - 13:42
    Thanks!
  • 13:43 - 13:46
    - [Narrator] If you want to test
    yourself, click "Practice Questions."
  • 13:46 - 13:50
    Or, if you're ready move on,
    just click "Next Video."
  • 13:50 - 13:53
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Arguments Against International trade
Description:

In this video, we discuss some of the most common arguments against international trade. Does trade harm workers by reducing the number of jobs in the U.S.? Is it wrong to trade with countries that use child labor? Is it important to keep a certain number of jobs at home for national security reasons? Can strategic protectionism increase well-being in the U.S.? Join us as we discuss these common concerns. - See more at: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/arguments-against-trade?

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/arguments-against-trade#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/introduction-externalities

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
13:56

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions