Return to Video

Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance

  • 0:02 - 0:06
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:14 - 0:15
    - [Professor Tyler Cowen]
    In the previous video,
  • 0:15 - 0:18
    we introduced the ideas
    of asymmetric information,
  • 0:18 - 0:21
    and adverse selection
    and we applied those ideas
  • 0:21 - 0:23
    to the used car market.
  • 0:23 - 0:25
    Let's take those same
    basic concepts,
  • 0:25 - 0:29
    and build a basic model
    of health insurance.
  • 0:29 - 0:31
    Suppose that potential
    health insurance consumers
  • 0:31 - 0:34
    come in a range of states of health.
  • 0:34 - 0:36
    For instance,
    the least healthy people
  • 0:36 - 0:39
    might cost about $30,000 a year.
  • 0:39 - 0:41
    That's these folks here.
  • 0:41 - 0:44
    The most healthy might cost
    nothing in healthcare.
  • 0:44 - 0:46
    That's these folks over here.
  • 0:46 - 0:49
    Now consumers know this information,
  • 0:49 - 0:51
    but by assumption, insurers don't.
  • 0:51 - 0:53
    From the insurer point of view,
  • 0:53 - 0:56
    everyone is of the same
    average health.
  • 0:56 - 0:59
    Here again, we have
    asymmetric information.
  • 0:59 - 1:01
    That is consumers of healthcare
  • 1:01 - 1:03
    have more information about
  • 1:03 - 1:05
    their health status
    than insurers do.
  • 1:05 - 1:09
    In this scenario, insurers have to
    price the coverage
  • 1:09 - 1:12
    based on the average cost
    among all consumers,
  • 1:12 - 1:14
    namely, $15,000.
  • 1:15 - 1:19
    But if the insurance costs $15,000,
    then a portion of the market,
  • 1:19 - 1:21
    the relatively healthy people,
  • 1:21 - 1:23
    they will choose not
    to buy insurance as
  • 1:23 - 1:26
    the cost of that insurance
    is greater to them
  • 1:26 - 1:28
    than the expected benefit.
  • 1:28 - 1:31
    So only part of this market
    will buy insurance.
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    The average cost of those
    who actually will buy
  • 1:34 - 1:39
    is then not $15,000 but $22,500.
  • 1:39 - 1:42
    In that case,
    the insurance company,
  • 1:42 - 1:46
    if it tries to price at $15,000,
    loses money.
  • 1:46 - 1:51
    If the insurance company instead
    raises the price to $22,500,
  • 1:51 - 1:55
    well, the same dynamic
    is actually going to kick in again.
  • 1:55 - 1:57
    That is relatively healthy people
  • 1:57 - 1:59
    won't find it worth
    paying that price.
  • 1:59 - 2:01
    The sicker people still will buy,
  • 2:01 - 2:03
    and that will raise
    the expected costs
  • 2:03 - 2:06
    to the insurer,
    and thus the price even further.
  • 2:07 - 2:10
    This dynamic continues
    until the individual insurance firm
  • 2:10 - 2:13
    finds there is no price
    at which it can attract
  • 2:13 - 2:16
    a set of customers with
    healthcare costs
  • 2:16 - 2:18
    lower than the price of insurance.
  • 2:19 - 2:23
    This is the same death spiral
    we saw before with used cars
  • 2:23 - 2:25
    and it leads to a market failure.
  • 2:26 - 2:28
    As we saw in the used car market,
  • 2:28 - 2:31
    there are several reasons
    why reality may differ
  • 2:31 - 2:32
    from the simple model.
  • 2:32 - 2:36
    First, the model we laid out would
    predict that the healthy people,
  • 2:36 - 2:38
    those who exercise,
    eat their veggies,
  • 2:38 - 2:41
    and buckle their seatbelts would
    not buy insurance,
  • 2:41 - 2:45
    while the model is predicting that
    the smokers, the mountain climbers,
  • 2:45 - 2:49
    and the motorcycle riders would
    buy insurance.
  • 2:49 - 2:51
    Is this true? Mostly no.
  • 2:51 - 2:53
    The people who buy health insurance
  • 2:53 - 2:56
    actually turn out to be
    the healthier people as well.
  • 2:56 - 2:58
    Why is that?
  • 2:58 - 3:01
    Well, those who try to avoid risk
    by eating well
  • 3:01 - 3:05
    also try to avoid risk
    by buying health insurance.
  • 3:05 - 3:06
    Our initial assumption that
  • 3:06 - 3:08
    everyone calculates
    costs and benefits
  • 3:08 - 3:11
    in exactly the same way
    is too simple.
  • 3:11 - 3:13
    Once you account for the fact that
  • 3:13 - 3:16
    people have differential
    tolerances for risk,
  • 3:16 - 3:18
    you can end up having
    the healthier people be
  • 3:18 - 3:21
    those who choose to buy
    the health insurance.
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    This is called
    “propitious selection”
  • 3:24 - 3:27
    where the people who buy
    the health insurance are healthier,
  • 3:27 - 3:29
    not sicker than average.
  • 3:29 - 3:33
    This can keep costs low,
    and prevent the death spiral.
  • 3:34 - 3:37
    Another possible response
    to the adverse selection problem
  • 3:37 - 3:39
    in health insurance
    might seem familiar.
  • 3:39 - 3:42
    If you recall,
    we saw that services such as
  • 3:42 - 3:45
    CARFAX and Certified Inspections
  • 3:45 - 3:48
    can alleviate
    the asymmetric information problem
  • 3:48 - 3:50
    when buying a used car.
  • 3:50 - 3:53
    These services allow
    the buyer of the car
  • 3:53 - 3:54
    to have similar information
  • 3:54 - 3:57
    to that possessed
    by the seller of the car.
  • 3:58 - 4:00
    The result of this information
    is that better cars
  • 4:00 - 4:04
    can sell for more,
    and lemons can sell for less.
  • 4:04 - 4:07
    Is there an analogous approach
    for people in health insurance?
  • 4:07 - 4:08
    Well, yes.
  • 4:08 - 4:10
    The health of people
    can be inspected
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    just as cars are inspected.
  • 4:12 - 4:15
    So while consumers initially
    may have more information
  • 4:15 - 4:18
    about their health than what
    the insurance companies have,
  • 4:18 - 4:21
    a checkup will allow
    the insurance firms
  • 4:21 - 4:24
    to get a better idea of
    the consumer's expected
  • 4:24 - 4:25
    healthcare costs.
  • 4:25 - 4:27
    And that allows
    the insurance companies
  • 4:27 - 4:32
    to charge healthy consumers less
    and sicker consumers more.
  • 4:32 - 4:33
    In the used car market,
  • 4:33 - 4:35
    that seemed like
    a pretty good solution.
  • 4:35 - 4:38
    After all, better cars
    should sell for more,
  • 4:38 - 4:40
    and lemons should sell for less.
  • 4:40 - 4:42
    In the health insurance market,
  • 4:42 - 4:43
    that solution might work,
  • 4:43 - 4:46
    but some people feel it is
    doubly unfair.
  • 4:46 - 4:48
    Not only are the sick sick,
  • 4:48 - 4:50
    but now they also have
    to pay more
  • 4:50 - 4:52
    for their health insurance.
  • 4:52 - 4:53
    Another problem
    with inspection is that
  • 4:53 - 4:56
    it might reveal
    too much information,
  • 4:56 - 4:59
    thereby rendering health insurance
    no longer viable.
  • 4:59 - 5:02
    For instance, let's say there's
    a very good diagnostic test,
  • 5:02 - 5:05
    and it determines that
    a patient A has cancer
  • 5:05 - 5:10
    and then B we know that cancer
    will cost $1 million to treat.
  • 5:10 - 5:12
    Well, to insure against that cancer,
  • 5:12 - 5:15
    the price of the policy
    has to be about $1 million,
  • 5:15 - 5:17
    but that's no longer insurance.
  • 5:17 - 5:19
    That's just presenting the patient
    with the bill.
  • 5:19 - 5:23
    Insurance is protecting against
    unexpected states of affairs,
  • 5:23 - 5:25
    and it's a kind of risk pooling,
  • 5:25 - 5:28
    a kind of protecting yourself
    against the high bill.
  • 5:28 - 5:30
    But if you're getting the high bill
    no matter what when you're sick,
  • 5:30 - 5:34
    well, then we've lost
    those benefits of insurance.
  • 5:35 - 5:37
    Another solution to
    the adverse selection problem
  • 5:37 - 5:40
    when used extensively
    in the United States
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    is group health insurance
    through employers.
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    Most people in America
    don't purchase insurance directly.
  • 5:46 - 5:48
    Instead, their employer
    purchases it for them
  • 5:48 - 5:50
    as part of a group plan.
  • 5:50 - 5:54
    The benefit of the system is that
    the insurance company
  • 5:54 - 5:57
    doesn't have to worry about
    adverse selection so much
  • 5:57 - 6:00
    The employer doesn't know much
    more about its employees' health
  • 6:00 - 6:02
    than does the insurance firm.
  • 6:02 - 6:04
    Furthermore, the employer is
    going to be buying
  • 6:04 - 6:08
    health insurance for the employees
    regardless of their health.
  • 6:08 - 6:11
    So for these reasons,
    the adverse selection problem is
  • 6:11 - 6:14
    much weaker with
    group health insurance.
  • 6:14 - 6:18
    Group health insurance, however,
    does cause other problems.
  • 6:18 - 6:21
    If you lose your job,
    you can lose your health insurance.
  • 6:21 - 6:23
    And what we do about retirees?
  • 6:24 - 6:26
    In the United States,
    various laws have made
  • 6:26 - 6:29
    health insurance more affordable,
  • 6:29 - 6:31
    and furthermore retirees are insured
    by the government
  • 6:31 - 6:33
    under Medicare.
  • 6:33 - 6:37
    So, there are some solutions,
    albeit imperfect ones as usual.
  • 6:38 - 6:41
    The most recent approach
    to the adverse selection problem
  • 6:41 - 6:43
    was implemented
    in the Affordable Care Act,
  • 6:43 - 6:46
    otherwise known as Obamacare.
  • 6:46 - 6:48
    Under the Affordable Care Act,
  • 6:48 - 6:51
    everyone is supposed to buy
    health insurance.
  • 6:51 - 6:54
    If you don't,
    you will be fined by law.
  • 6:54 - 6:58
    The idea here is to force
    all the healthy people into the pool
  • 6:58 - 6:59
    of those who buy insurance
  • 6:59 - 7:02
    that will moderate the cost
    of health insurance,
  • 7:02 - 7:04
    and we will avoid the death spiral.
  • 7:04 - 7:06
    As you can see, although
  • 7:06 - 7:09
    the adverse selection model
    is pretty simple,
  • 7:09 - 7:10
    it has lots of applications
  • 7:10 - 7:13
    to some pretty complex
    real-world problems.
  • 7:13 - 7:17
    Next up we'll tackle moral
    hazard. See you then.
  • 7:17 - 7:19
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 7:19 - 7:20
    - [Announcer] If you want
    to test yourself,
  • 7:20 - 7:22
    click “Practice Questions."
  • 7:22 - 7:26
    Or, if you're ready to move on,
    just click “Next Video.”
Title:
Asymmetric Information and Health Insurance
Description:

In this video, we discuss asymmetric information, adverse selection, and propitious selection in relation to the market for health insurance. Health insurance consumers come in a range of health, but to insurance companies, everyone has the same average health. Consumer have more information about their health than do insurers. How does this affect the price of health insurance? Why would some consumers prefer to not buy health insurance at all? And how does this all relate to the Affordable Care Act? Let’s dive in.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://www.mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/lemons-problem-asymmetric-information-health-insurance#QandA

Next video: http://www.mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/moral-hazard-adverse-selection

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
07:31

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions