< Return to Video

The Economic Consequences of Internet Censorship (33c3)

  • 0:00 - 0:13
    33c3 pre-roll music
  • 0:13 - 0:15
    Herald: Err ...
  • 0:15 - 0:18
    H: ... a talk would be good, right?
  • 0:18 - 0:25
    applause
  • 0:26 - 0:27
    Do you want to give a talk?
  • 0:27 - 0:31
    Toni: Aah, it’s a little early
    but I’ll try.
  • 0:31 - 0:36
    Herald: Okay, guys, well, I found someone
    who’s willing to give a talk!
  • 0:36 - 0:42
    laughter and applause
  • 0:42 - 0:47
    That is most excellent.
    So, if you ever asked yourself,
  • 0:48 - 0:53
    I’ve got this big regime and
    I’m rolling out internet censorship,
  • 0:53 - 0:56
    what does my economy do?
  • 0:56 - 0:59
    There are people in here
    asking that question, right?
  • 0:59 - 1:03
    There’s always someone at Congress
    who’s asking some question.
  • 1:03 - 1:09
    Well, you came to the right place,
    and as part of her PhD thesis work
  • 1:09 - 1:15
    Toni is going answer that question,
    hopefully, to a satisfactory point.
  • 1:15 - 1:18
    Please give a warm round of applause!
    applause
  • 1:18 - 1:24
    Toni!
    ongoing applause
  • 1:24 - 1:28
    Toni: Okay, thanks everyone for being
    here, I hope you can all hear me
  • 1:28 - 1:33
    correctly. And I’m glad to be here
    and to be presenting
  • 1:33 - 1:36
    some part of my thesis to day.
    Now, this is ongoing work
  • 1:36 - 1:40
    so I’m really grateful for any kind of feedback
    that you guys would have
  • 1:40 - 1:43
    and I’m really only presenting this
    as kind of a first try,
  • 1:43 - 1:47
    because when I looked at the topic
    of internet censorship
  • 1:47 - 1:52
    and what that could mean for an economy,
    I really didn’t find anything academic
  • 1:52 - 1:56
    and I was quite surprised: it seemed
    like a very obvious question to me,
  • 1:56 - 2:01
    because I was looking mostly
    at China at the beginning.
  • 2:01 - 2:05
    And I read a lot of newspaper articles
    and I talked to a lot of businessmen
  • 2:05 - 2:08
    who told me: “Well, doing business
    in China is very difficult”
  • 2:08 - 2:11
    and I think China is really
    holding itself back by having
  • 2:11 - 2:15
    this big censorship thing going.
  • 2:15 - 2:21
    But no one really looked into
    how it is holding itself back
  • 2:21 - 2:24
    or if it is even holding itself back.
  • 2:24 - 2:27
    So there is really
    very, very little research.
  • 2:27 - 2:32
    And we don’t even have an agreement among
    economists or business studies people
  • 2:32 - 2:36
    about what impact the internet has
    on the economy. So if you want to ask:
  • 2:36 - 2:40
    “So what does internet censorship do
    to an economy?” it seems pretty obvious
  • 2:40 - 2:45
    to first ask: “What does the internet do to
    an economy?” and we don’t even know that.
  • 2:45 - 2:48
    That was quite surprising to me and I’m
    going to be talking about the reasons
  • 2:48 - 2:53
    for that a little bit later on. But in
    general, I was thinking of a research
  • 2:53 - 2:58
    question to ask which for me is: “Does
    internet censorship reduce economic welfare?”
  • 2:58 - 3:03
    Now, not all of you are economists,
    so some of you might think of welfare
  • 3:03 - 3:08
    more as the transfer payments
    that a state gives to its poorer people.
  • 3:08 - 3:13
    But for economists, economic welfare
    is defined as the consumer
  • 3:13 - 3:18
    and producer surplus. So basically, the
    difference between what something costs
  • 3:18 - 3:22
    and what you can sell it for
    is the producer surplus.
  • 3:22 - 3:25
    The difference between
    what you would be willing to pay
  • 3:25 - 3:28
    and what you’re actually paying
    is your consumer surplus.
  • 3:28 - 3:32
    Now let’s assume I have a laptop
    and I bought this.
  • 3:32 - 3:36
    And I would have been willing to pay
    € 1500 for this laptop because
  • 3:36 - 3:40
    I think it’s a very good product,
    it’s by Lenovo that makes good laptops.
  • 3:40 - 3:44
    But actually I got it for like €800
    or €900. That would mean
  • 3:44 - 3:49
    my personal consumer surplus
    is something like €600 or €700.
  • 3:49 - 3:53
    And if we add up everyone’s
    individual consumer surplus
  • 3:53 - 3:59
    we get the economic welfare surplus.
  • 3:59 - 4:03
    So first, I was trying to figure out
    what does the internet mean
  • 4:03 - 4:08
    for the economy. And I’ve said that there
    is really no good agreement on that.
  • 4:08 - 4:12
    Now, a very crude measure that I found is
    how much does "the Internet economy"
  • 4:12 - 4:18
    contribute to GDP?
    Now, what is "the internet economy"?
  • 4:18 - 4:22
    It wasn’t very clear in the research
    that I’ve read. It seems to be sort of
  • 4:22 - 4:28
    online retail, and possibly some other
    internet-enabled services?
  • 4:28 - 4:31
    Possibly but not necessarily
    internet advertisement revenue
  • 4:31 - 4:36
    is reflected in this. But because it was
    BCG, which is a big consulting agency
  • 4:36 - 4:41
    that basically published this research
    they weren’t very diligent about
  • 4:41 - 4:46
    their methods, basically.
    So we can see, well it seems that the UK
  • 4:46 - 4:50
    has a pretty big part of internet economy
    as part of GDP.
  • 4:50 - 4:54
    That’s probably mostly because of
    online retail which is bigger in the UK
  • 4:54 - 4:57
    than in most other countries we look at.
    And we see that there is
  • 4:57 - 5:02
    a small difference between
    developed and developing market averages
  • 5:02 - 5:07
    when looking only at the G20 countries.
    But this seems like a very
  • 5:07 - 5:10
    dissatisfactory answer because first
    of all, I don’t know the methods,
  • 5:10 - 5:13
    so I can’t really say
    whether this is actually good.
  • 5:13 - 5:16
    And secondly, GDP is actually
    not a good measure
  • 5:16 - 5:20
    for what we are trying to measure because
    a lot of the stuff that the internet creates,
  • 5:20 - 5:26
    a lot of the value the internet creates
    isn’t captured by GDP at all.
  • 5:26 - 5:30
    One example is free online courses.
    Most of the online courses you can take
  • 5:30 - 5:34
    on the web are actually free.
    And most of them are not ad-enabled.
  • 5:34 - 5:41
    So most of them don’t really have
    advertisements in the general sense.
  • 5:41 - 5:46
    So classical economics basically says:
    “Well, they don’t really create any value.”
  • 5:46 - 5:49
    But if you’ve ever taken
    one of these online courses,
  • 5:49 - 5:51
    and maybe you’ve been lucky
    and took a good one
  • 5:51 - 5:54
    you would actually… I would say that
    some of the courses I took,
  • 5:54 - 5:58
    they created some value for me.
    So one of the ways to look at this
  • 5:58 - 6:03
    is actually to think about time as
    something that has opportunity cost.
  • 6:03 - 6:06
    So if I’m spending my time doing this
    online course I’m not spending it
  • 6:06 - 6:11
    e.g. earning money. I’m also not
    spending it doing something leisurely
  • 6:11 - 6:18
    that is fun for me.
    And these guys, Brynjolfsson
  • 6:18 - 6:21
    – I’m sorry I don’t know
    how to pronounce it exactly,
  • 6:21 - 6:26
    he sounds Swedish, possibly –
    and ohh, in 2012
  • 6:26 - 6:33
    they tried to get an idea of
    how much consumer surplus
  • 6:33 - 6:39
    these online courses actually create.
    Which isn’t at all
  • 6:39 - 6:44
    reflected in the GDP.
    And you see that in some models
  • 6:44 - 6:50
    it would be 5% of GDP
    for these online courses alone.
  • 6:50 - 6:57
    Even if we take their more... most conservative
    model which is $4.18 billion
  • 6:57 - 7:00
    on average for the years 2008-2011,
  • 7:00 - 7:04
    that’s still a pretty significant chunk
    of economic welfare
  • 7:04 - 7:08
    that’s somehow being created
    that is not reflected in GDP
  • 7:08 - 7:12
    because GDP is only stuff
    that you actually pay money for.
  • 7:12 - 7:15
    Another example that we
    might think of is Wikipedia.
  • 7:15 - 7:19
    Now Wikipedia has a certain cost of
    operating: obviously the servers and stuff.
  • 7:19 - 7:23
    But because most people contributing
    to Wikipedia are actually volunteers
  • 7:23 - 7:26
    the cost of operating
    does not really reflect
  • 7:26 - 7:30
    the true value Wikipedia creates.
    And one of the…
  • 7:30 - 7:33
    even if you don’t want to say…
    even if you don’t agree
  • 7:33 - 7:37
    that time has opportunity cost, what
    about the money that you don’t spend
  • 7:37 - 7:44
    on encyclopedias? How many of you guys
    have encyclopedias at home?
  • 7:44 - 7:46
    OK, that’s more than I expected!
  • 7:46 - 7:49
    How many of you guys have
    recent encyclopedias at home?
  • 7:49 - 7:54
    That’s a little less, this is kind of more
    what I was expecting.
  • 7:54 - 7:58
    And now, my family also… we also have
    an encyclopedia at home.
  • 7:58 - 8:03
    I think it’s from 1985 or something.
    And before this encyclopedia
  • 8:03 - 8:06
    we would regularly update an encyclopedia,
    we would regularly go out and buy
  • 8:06 - 8:10
    a new encyclopedia because
    knowledge changed, obviously.
  • 8:10 - 8:14
    But ever since probably 1990,
    we just didn’t bother.
  • 8:14 - 8:21
    So, assuming an encyclopedia might,
    like a physical book, might cost €100.
  • 8:21 - 8:24
    And assuming sort of 2/3
    of all households in Germany
  • 8:24 - 8:28
    have had an encyclopedia at one point.
  • 8:28 - 8:32
    We’re looking at 13 million households
    at this point.
  • 8:32 - 8:36
    Now you don’t buy an encyclopedia
    every year but you might buy it
  • 8:36 - 8:41
    every ten years. So in order to simplify
    this we can say, every year
  • 8:41 - 8:46
    1.3 million households buy
    an encyclopedia on average.
  • 8:46 - 8:53
    1.3 million times €100,
    so we’re at €130 million
  • 8:53 - 8:58
    of economic welfare, of something that
    people were willing to spend money for
  • 8:58 - 9:01
    that they’re not spending money for anymore
    because of Wikipedia, because now that
  • 9:01 - 9:06
    we have Wikipedia most of the encyclopedias
    aren’t actually useful for us anymore
  • 9:06 - 9:10
    because the knowledge that we have,
    the knowledge that they would have
  • 9:10 - 9:19
    would be outdated very, very soon and
    Wikipedia tends to be more up to date.
  • 9:19 - 9:24
    Well, that was from the consumer’s side.
    But what about the business side?
  • 9:24 - 9:29
    There’s a lot of research on whether the
    internet actually increases productivity
  • 9:29 - 9:34
    for businesses or not. Well, I don’t really
    want to go into that debate because
  • 9:34 - 9:38
    it’s a really long tedious debate that is
    kind of focused on “Well, you did this
  • 9:38 - 9:42
    method wrong”, or “You did this wrong”,
    and “Well, I don’t think your argument
  • 9:42 - 9:47
    makes sense”. So it’s very… I don’t like
    this kind of debate. I really like to go
  • 9:47 - 9:52
    deeper in things. But one of the things
    that I found was that a lot of businesses
  • 9:52 - 9:59
    do rely on the internet by now. Now
    we can see on this graph that most firms,
  • 9:59 - 10:06
    overall about 70% of firms actually
    use the email to communicate.
  • 10:06 - 10:10
    Now email obviously only works
    if you have internet, so they need
  • 10:10 - 10:16
    some sort of access to internet in order
    for their current business model to work.
  • 10:16 - 10:22
    Now this was just some short ideas on
    sort of what can the internet mean for
  • 10:22 - 10:26
    the economy. And now I want to talk about
    Internet censorship, just a little bit.
  • 10:26 - 10:34
    Now, I’m not a censorship expert. I’m just
    someone who read a lot of papers about it,
  • 10:34 - 10:38
    and who was very interested in what kind
    of effects this has beyond sort of
  • 10:38 - 10:44
    the obvious “people don’t have access
    to political information”.
  • 10:44 - 10:48
    So first a definition. ‘Internet censorship’
    is the controller suppression
  • 10:48 - 10:51
    of what can be accessed, published
    or viewed on the Internet
  • 10:51 - 10:55
    enacted by regulators or on their own
    initiative. Now, in trying to conceptualize
  • 10:55 - 10:59
    internet censorship, for me, personally,
    there’s two dimensions that are
  • 10:59 - 11:04
    very important. One is how targeted
    is this internet censorship?
  • 11:04 - 11:12
    Now, you could, in theory, basically
    have internet censorship
  • 11:12 - 11:15
    that is very, very targeted,
    which you see in some cases.
  • 11:15 - 11:19
    Or you can have censorship
    that isn’t targeted at all, like in Egypt.
  • 11:19 - 11:24
    They just decided to close the internet
    down, basically, for a day.
  • 11:24 - 11:28
    That isn’t very targeted censorship,
    obviously. The other thing to look at
  • 11:28 - 11:33
    is how widespread is it? So if you are
    a business or if you’re a normal consumer
  • 11:33 - 11:39
    how probable is it that you would come (?)
    something that’s censored?
  • 11:39 - 11:43
    Now, obviously, if you’re in China it’s
    a lot more probable that you would
  • 11:43 - 11:47
    try to access something that’s censored
    than if you’re in Germany. Even though
  • 11:47 - 11:53
    Germany also does some censorship.
    And the way I like to conceptualize it is
  • 11:53 - 11:58
    to be kind of on a continuum. So I don’t
    look… I don’t say “Well, either
  • 11:58 - 12:02
    there’s censorship or there isn’t
    censorship”. What I’m trying to say is
  • 12:02 - 12:07
    “Censorship has a big spectrum
    of things that can happen”.
  • 12:07 - 12:13
    These are some types of Internet censorship
    that have different sort of implications.
  • 12:13 - 12:16
    I don’t want to go through them in detail
    because I think we’ve heard some really
  • 12:16 - 12:22
    interesting talks on Internet censorship
    already. But this is kind of
  • 12:22 - 12:27
    interesting or important for the model
    that I’m trying to build.
  • 12:27 - 12:30
    But before trying to build my model,
    first some more motivation.
  • 12:30 - 12:34
    I was trying to look at “is there any
    evidence that it would have
  • 12:34 - 12:40
    an economic impact?”. And there actually
    is a study that’s conducted by sort of
  • 12:40 - 12:46
    lobbying organizations, so obviously
    should be taken with a grain of salt.
  • 12:46 - 12:50
    But it is quite interesting, and it shows
    that there seems to be a correlation
  • 12:50 - 12:59
    between freedom and how good
    the economic impact of internet is.
  • 12:59 - 13:04
    This is just a simple correlation. You can
    see that there’s a really good line
  • 13:04 - 13:10
    going through it. They did do some
    controlling for GDP per capita, so
  • 13:10 - 13:17
    for development level. But it still seems
    quite rudimentary, to be honest.
  • 13:17 - 13:24
    The data that they use is quite bad
    because it is very, very…
  • 13:24 - 13:30
    it’s just not finally granular enough, and
    a lot of it is kind of… someone rating…
  • 13:30 - 13:35
    so “How do you think the economic…”,
    “How do you think Internet
  • 13:35 - 13:40
    impacts the economy in this country?”
    And then this is the data that they use,
  • 13:40 - 13:48
    to some degree. So it seemed very…
    it didn’t really seem like a good, final answer.
  • 13:48 - 13:54
    So I’m trying to set up my own model.
    And in my model I have a government
  • 13:54 - 13:58
    that chooses the type of censorship. And
    for this type of censorship that it chooses
  • 13:58 - 14:03
    it pays a cost. Because we all know
    censorship can be very expensive.
  • 14:03 - 14:10
    And in my model for now the only type of
    expenses that I calculate are actual
  • 14:10 - 14:17
    manpower and technology expenses. I don’t
    calculate reputation expenses at this point.
  • 14:17 - 14:24
    There is… there are firms in n industries.
    Now this n is kind of not a fixed number
  • 14:24 - 14:31
    but instead is a number that can fluctuate
    depending on the kind of country
  • 14:31 - 14:38
    I’m trying to model. And these industries
    distinguish themselves by their
  • 14:38 - 14:42
    information intensity, or what I like
    to call ‘information intensity’. Basically
  • 14:42 - 14:48
    I look at information as a commodity.
    And what I’m trying to decide, or
  • 14:48 - 14:52
    the way I distinguish different kinds of
    industry is how important is information
  • 14:52 - 14:56
    as a commodity, as opposed to other kinds
    of commodities that are important
  • 14:56 - 15:01
    for this industry. So let’s look at
    information intensity equals Zero.
  • 15:01 - 15:05
    Like if we don’t really… if information
    as a commodity really isn’t important,
  • 15:05 - 15:10
    especially sort of conveyed information,
    transmitted information. We can
  • 15:10 - 15:14
    think of traditional agriculture. Now
    I know today’s agriculture tends to be
  • 15:14 - 15:19
    large-scale, and there’s a lot of
    technology involved. But if you look at
  • 15:19 - 15:24
    very traditional agriculture that we
    still might see happening in some parts
  • 15:24 - 15:30
    of Africa there usually is very, very
    little information transmission involved.
  • 15:30 - 15:34
    And most of the information transmission
    that is involved is actually mostly through
  • 15:34 - 15:40
    word of mouth. So that would be a case of
    information intensity of very close to Zero.
  • 15:40 - 15:44
    And then if we look at information intensity
    of 1 where basically the internet is
  • 15:44 - 15:49
    the most… or information is the most
    important commodity. Internet businesses
  • 15:49 - 15:55
    themselves would… obviously qualify here,
    – sorry – like, let’s look at Facebook
  • 15:55 - 16:00
    and other kinds of businesses like this.
    And in between we have sort of industrial
  • 16:00 - 16:03
    companies in the modern world.
    Now if we’re closer to the Zero end
  • 16:03 - 16:08
    of the spectrum we might be
    at 0.2 .. 0.3, something like this,
  • 16:08 - 16:15
    we might be in traditional garment
    factories. They do have information needs,
  • 16:15 - 16:21
    they get their cuts and stuff from the
    Internet by now, or by email.
  • 16:21 - 16:25
    But once they have them they basically stay
    the same for a couple of weeks or months.
  • 16:25 - 16:30
    So there’s a very low information
    requirement. On the other side,
  • 16:30 - 16:36
    closer to 0.8 or something
    like that we have high-tech,
  • 16:36 - 16:41
    especially software manufacturing,
    so to speak. Information and being able
  • 16:41 - 16:45
    to transmit this information is very
    important. Now, in between we might look
  • 16:45 - 16:51
    at traditional industrial companies
    like automobile manufacturing
  • 16:51 - 16:56
    that might be somewhere in between.
    And before the game, or before…
  • 16:56 - 17:00
    or at the first run of the model
    ‘service level’ and ‘globalization level’
  • 17:00 - 17:06
    are randomly distributed. The information
    intensity of industries is also kind of
  • 17:06 - 17:12
    randomly distributed, but not in a true
    random fashion. Because when looking
  • 17:12 - 17:16
    in the wild, sort of what kind of
    economies exist, most of them…
  • 17:16 - 17:19
    the information intensity of one
    industry is kind of correlated with
  • 17:19 - 17:23
    information intensities of other industries
    in this country. Like in Germany
  • 17:23 - 17:29
    we’re very known for a certain type
    of industry that we have quite a lot of,
  • 17:29 - 17:35
    which is manufacturing, very high-technology
    manufacturing. So we have more industries
  • 17:35 - 17:40
    in this area but we have less traditional
    agriculture, for example.
  • 17:40 - 17:45
    So having a true random distribution
    wouldn’t work. In addition the service level
  • 17:45 - 17:50
    and the globalization level are randomly
    distributed as kind of external variables.
  • 17:50 - 17:55
    Obviously, this is a simplification because
    I can’t really start at the beginning like
  • 17:55 - 17:59
    I can’t say: “Oh well, I’ll start,
    I don’t know, 2000 BC
  • 17:59 - 18:04
    with a very blank economy, and then
    something happens and something happens
  • 18:04 - 18:08
    and something happens”. That’s just not
    realistic. So in order to get a better idea
  • 18:08 - 18:13
    of what happens with different types of
    economies, what I’m doing is I’m running
  • 18:13 - 18:19
    this game or this model again and again.
    And having these random parameters
  • 18:19 - 18:25
    basically changed everytime.
    So on average there should be…
  • 18:25 - 18:29
    there should be usable results.
  • 18:29 - 18:35
    Now what this is actually missing
    is the consumer as a labourer.
  • 18:35 - 18:40
    So I don’t really have ‘labour’ reflected
    in here. A more complete model would have
  • 18:40 - 18:44
    that reflected. But it’s not the most
    interesting aspect of my model, so
  • 18:44 - 18:50
    I’m not presenting this here, basically.
  • 18:50 - 18:56
    Now, let’s look at what this would
    mean for firms. In my model
  • 18:56 - 19:00
    what kind of things would I expect
    thinking through it logically which is
  • 19:00 - 19:05
    always the first step when trying to model
    something. First of all if we have
  • 19:05 - 19:10
    an information intensity of something
    greater than Zero but smaller than One.
  • 19:10 - 19:14
    Because the information intensity being
    close to One is kind of a special case
  • 19:14 - 19:19
    that I’ll be talking about later on.
    Internet censorship increases the cost
  • 19:19 - 19:22
    and uncertainty of information.
    And of course that is more important
  • 19:22 - 19:28
    the more important information is
    for this certain industry.
  • 19:28 - 19:34
    So for a traditional garment factory
    internet censorship might be a lot
  • 19:34 - 19:41
    less important than for a semiconductor
    factory that has to receive
  • 19:41 - 19:47
    new blueprints every day or every month
    or something. The second thing is
  • 19:47 - 19:52
    the more globalized the economy as a whole
    is the more costly internet censorship
  • 19:52 - 19:58
    will be. Similar reasoning.
  • 19:58 - 20:03
    And another thing for firms is the
    less focused the censorship
  • 20:03 - 20:08
    the higher the cost. Now this assumes that
    the censorship or the goal of censorship
  • 20:08 - 20:14
    usually isn’t to turn down firms or to
    make sure that firms don’t succeed.
  • 20:14 - 20:20
    So if censorship is very focused
    firms tend to be affected less
  • 20:20 - 20:25
    which makes their associated cost less.
    Now of course we can argue, well,
  • 20:25 - 20:29
    firms can circumvent censorship, and they
    can do that for sure. But it is expensive
  • 20:29 - 20:35
    to do that. If you’ve ever tried a VPN
    in China e.g., first, buying the VPN
  • 20:35 - 20:41
    is expensive. Then, having someone sort of
    make sure that the VPN works is expensive,
  • 20:41 - 20:44
    every couple of months you need to change
    it because the Chinese Government decides,
  • 20:44 - 20:53
    well, this VPN shouldn’t work anymore. So
    it’s a very expensive and uncertain thing,
  • 20:53 - 20:58
    really. For firms in
    ‘information intensity = 1’
  • 20:58 - 21:03
    it obviously also increases the cost
    of operating. Some of these firms actually
  • 21:03 - 21:08
    carry out some censorship for governments.
    We have seen that happening more recently.
  • 21:08 - 21:13
    But there might actually be some firms
    that have a relative advantage, especially
  • 21:13 - 21:17
    domestic firms often have a relative
    advantage due to the censorship because
  • 21:17 - 21:21
    they know the regulators better, they know
    how to deal with it, they might have
  • 21:21 - 21:25
    less need to circumvent, actually.
    And even if they do need to circumvent
  • 21:25 - 21:30
    it’s easier for them because
    they speak the language etc.
  • 21:30 - 21:34
    This is actually a special case that I’ll
    be talking about a little bit later as well.
  • 21:34 - 21:38
    For the government – I’ve said
    that censorship is costly. But moreover,
  • 21:38 - 21:43
    the more targeted and accurate censorship
    is the more manpower and technology intensive
  • 21:43 - 21:50
    it actually is. This is a finding by
    Leberknight et al. in a research paper.
  • 21:50 - 21:54
    I think they’re electrical engineers, and
    they calculated through different types
  • 21:54 - 22:00
    of censorships and how expensive it would
    be to scale them up. So that is actually
  • 22:00 - 22:03
    a really interesting finding because
    it shows that for governments
  • 22:03 - 22:10
    having sort of less targeted censorship
    is less costly. But this is the kind of
  • 22:10 - 22:17
    censorship that is actually most affecting
    in a negative way to firms,
  • 22:17 - 22:21
    in an economy. So that’s kind of not
    a result that we would really want
  • 22:21 - 22:25
    because the incentives don’t line up in
    that way. And economists love to talk
  • 22:25 - 22:29
    about incentives, obviously. Now for
    consumers, they would obviously get
  • 22:29 - 22:33
    less benefits through the internet, the
    benefits that I’ve talked about before.
  • 22:33 - 22:38
    And also businesses often pass on the cost
    to consumers.
  • 22:38 - 22:43
    Now however, some countries
    still benefit from internet censorship.
  • 22:43 - 22:46
    I’ve talked mostly
    about why it’s costly to do it,
  • 22:46 - 22:49
    and I think it is costly in most cases.
  • 22:49 - 22:53
    But developing countries that start out at
    low service and low globalization levels
  • 22:53 - 22:59
    usually have… in these kind of situations
    internet censorship has less of an impact,
  • 22:59 - 23:04
    less of a negative impact.
    And censorship can actually act
  • 23:04 - 23:09
    as protectionism. In information intensive
    industries governments can use this kind
  • 23:09 - 23:14
    of censorship to push domestic industries
    and enable catch-up growth. Now there
  • 23:14 - 23:17
    are a couple of further prerequisites.
    First of all, the country needs to be
  • 23:17 - 23:21
    large enough so that these
    information intensive industries
  • 23:21 - 23:24
    have a domestic market as well.
  • 23:24 - 23:27
    Obviously. And then also only
    targeted censorship can serve as
  • 23:27 - 23:32
    protectionism. The only other way would be
    if you decided on a domestic intranet and
  • 23:32 - 23:38
    basically closed your entire intranet off
    to the world. Which is kind of difficult.
  • 23:38 - 23:42
    But what about the long-term effects
    of that? Would they still be positive
  • 23:42 - 23:48
    for the government? Now, I’m using
    ‘positive’ in a very… sort of something
  • 23:48 - 23:52
    that should be taken with a grain of salt,
    obviously. And what I did is I looked
  • 23:52 - 23:57
    at China. Obviously, I’m a China watcher.
    So I’m really interested in China. And
  • 23:57 - 24:02
    this is kind of where my interest started.
    And I’m really trying to find a framework
  • 24:02 - 24:07
    where China isn’t the exception but
    instead China kind of fits into the model.
  • 24:07 - 24:13
    What we see is the Chinese government has
    outsourced much if its censorship to these
  • 24:13 - 24:19
    internet companies. Baidu, Sina weibo,
    Tencent probably would not exist by now,
  • 24:19 - 24:25
    actually, if the censorship didn’t exist.
    And what we actually see now is that
  • 24:25 - 24:30
    WeChat e.g. is going global. It has
    more functionality than Whatsapp
  • 24:30 - 24:36
    and they’re trying to get out. But as I’ll
    be talking about later on a little bit
  • 24:36 - 24:42
    the censorship is starting to be a problem
    for these companies that used to benefit.
  • 24:42 - 24:47
    There’s some things about Chinese… about
    the character of Chinese Internet censorship
  • 24:47 - 24:54
    that is relevant here. But what about
    the future? Now first it’s difficult to
  • 24:54 - 24:59
    innovate with this kind of censorship. And
    this kind of insular education that we see
  • 24:59 - 25:03
    also makes innovation, real innovation,
    very difficult. In China e.g. Github
  • 25:03 - 25:08
    is blocked most of the time. That makes
    kind of collaborating, especially in
  • 25:08 - 25:12
    coding environments, very, very hard.
  • 25:12 - 25:14
    Second, we see more global internet enabled
  • 25:14 - 25:20
    supply chains in the world. So if we have
    these global Internet-enabled supply chains
  • 25:20 - 25:26
    having internet censorship turns out to be
    more of a disadvantage the more globalized
  • 25:26 - 25:32
    these supply chains actually become. And
    information becomes the most important
  • 25:32 - 25:36
    commodity all throughout China. Now this
    of course also makes Internet censorship
  • 25:36 - 25:41
    more costly for the economy. What about
    possible positives? So what could work
  • 25:41 - 25:46
    in the Chinese government’s favour? First,
    the Chinese intranet is actually pretty
  • 25:46 - 25:50
    attractive to most people. Most people
    don’t try to go outside, even like
  • 25:50 - 25:55
    they don’t even know that they can’t. They
    just don’t want to do it. Second, the IoT,
  • 25:55 - 25:59
    where machines communicate with each other
    doesn’t need to be affected because
  • 25:59 - 26:05
    most of the censorship that we see
    happening could be reworked in a way
  • 26:05 - 26:09
    that doesn’t affect machine-to-machine
    communication. And that wouldn’t be
  • 26:09 - 26:14
    a problem for what the censorship intends
    to do which is sort of suppress political
  • 26:14 - 26:21
    opposition. And a third, the government
    wants an economy more focused on domestic
  • 26:21 - 26:24
    consumption. So if they want to do this
    then censorship might actually be good
  • 26:24 - 26:31
    for that. Now, for me, what I found out
    when doing this research is first,
  • 26:31 - 26:35
    standard economic models really aren’t
    suited for this kind of question. Because
  • 26:35 - 26:38
    they tend to use GDP, and I’ve told you
    why GDP really is not a good measure
  • 26:38 - 26:43
    for that. Second, the next step that
    I’ll be doing is agent-based modeling.
  • 26:43 - 26:49
    But I would really like to feed my models
    with some reliable data. And I can’t
  • 26:49 - 26:53
    really find any of that. I can find some
    data going back a couple of years
  • 26:53 - 26:58
    on, like, is there censorship, is there
    no censorship. But I can’t really find any
  • 26:58 - 27:02
    good data that distinguishes between
    different types of censorship, which would
  • 27:02 - 27:06
    be really important for the kind of
    research that I really want to carry out
  • 27:06 - 27:12
    in the future. Thank you, guys. If you
    have questions you can ask now or
  • 27:12 - 27:15
    you can come to me later, you can
    of course also send me an e-mail.
  • 27:15 - 27:19
    I’m always happy to talk about this topic.
  • 27:19 - 27:28
    applause
  • 27:28 - 27:32
    Herald: Thank you very much for this talk.
    We have six microphones at the floor level
  • 27:32 - 27:36
    here, so if you have questions we have
    a very brief amount of time.
  • 27:36 - 27:40
    Please line up at the microphones.
    We have microphone no. 2 over here.
  • 27:40 - 27:46
    Question: I want to mention one thing.
    Always when talking about China censorship
  • 27:46 - 27:51
    this censorship applies to China main
    land. So it’s not Hong Kong and not Taiwan.
  • 27:51 - 27:52
    Toni: Yes.
  • 27:52 - 27:56
    Question: And my question I want
    to ask is:
  • 27:56 - 27:59
    What do you think about productivity
    of work?
  • 27:59 - 28:05
    So e.g. if you shut down Facebook do you
    think this would increase working
  • 28:05 - 28:08
    productivity?
    Toni laughs
  • 28:08 - 28:13
    applause
    Toni: That’s a really interesting question,
  • 28:13 - 28:16
    and something that I haven’t seen anywhere
    in literature. There is a big literature
  • 28:16 - 28:22
    discussion about what the internet as such
    means for productivity, and that’s
  • 28:22 - 28:27
    kind of both ways. Now, one of the things
    to look at is that just because you
  • 28:27 - 28:31
    shut down Facebook doesn’t mean you
    shut down any sort of social network.
  • 28:31 - 28:36
    And I do think that if people use Facebook
    and suddenly aren’t able to use it anymore
  • 28:36 - 28:41
    they would probably spend their resources
    trying to find new ways to access Facebook
  • 28:41 - 28:49
    which would probably not exactly
    improve their productivity.
  • 28:49 - 28:52
    Herald: Next question
    from microphone no. 2.
  • 28:52 - 28:58
    Question: Would it make sense to have
    a model where firms use information
  • 28:58 - 29:02
    as an input to a production function and
    then model censorship as a kind of tax
  • 29:02 - 29:08
    on that. That will seem like standard new
    classical micro-econ one-on-one stuff?
  • 29:08 - 29:12
    Toni: That would make sense. I’ve actually
    looked at this. One of the problems with
  • 29:12 - 29:18
    doing that is that information
    as a commodity
  • 29:18 - 29:23
    is very difficult to be used in this new
    classical way because you usually assume
  • 29:23 - 29:28
    that everything is kind of friction-less.
    And if things are friction-less then
  • 29:28 - 29:32
    information can’t really be a commodity
    because you assume that information
  • 29:32 - 29:36
    basically gets transferred immediately,
    and without any sort of censorship. So
  • 29:36 - 29:40
    we can talk about this a little bit later.
    Maybe you have some ideas that
  • 29:40 - 29:44
    I haven’t found yet.
    It would be interesting.
  • 29:44 - 29:48
    Herald: And the next question,
    as well, from microphone no. 2.
  • 29:48 - 29:54
    Question: So, going the same direction:
    for GDP is rather defined what is
  • 29:54 - 29:59
    the optimization problem for a government.
    For your further approaches what would be
  • 29:59 - 30:05
    the optimization that a government like
    China does then. If you say e.g. Wikipedia
  • 30:05 - 30:09
    which leaks out to all over the world but
    what is the government optimizing then?
  • 30:09 - 30:15
    Toni: What I’m looking at is economic welfare
    as defined as producer and consumer surplus.
  • 30:15 - 30:23
    And I assume that the government’s goal
    is to optimize economic welfare for both
  • 30:23 - 30:28
    producers, consumers and also for itself
    as a producer and as a consumer.
  • 30:28 - 30:32
    Question: So your criticism is more like
    you don’t have a good proxy,
  • 30:32 - 30:34
    using GDP for economic welfare?
  • 30:34 - 30:37
    Toni: Yes, yes.
    Okay. Thank you.
  • 30:37 - 30:38
    Herald: I’m afraid we’re all out of time.
  • 30:38 - 30:40
    Please give a warm round
    of applause to Toni!
  • 30:40 - 30:44
    applause
  • 30:44 - 30:46
    post-roll music
  • 30:46 - 30:51
    Subtitles created by c3subtitles.de
    in the year 2017. Join, and help us!
Title:
The Economic Consequences of Internet Censorship (33c3)
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Duration:
31:08

English subtitles

Revisions