-
Hi, in this lecture we are going to look
at our fourth category of reasons about why
-
you'd want to take a course in modeling,
why modeling is so important. And that is
-
to help you make better decisions,
strategize better, and design things
-
better. So lets get started, this should
be a lot of fun. Alright, so first reason
-
why models are so useful. They are good
decision aides, they help you make better
-
decisions. Let me give you an example.
These get us going here. So what you see
-
is a whole bunch of different financial
institutions, these are companies like
-
Bear Sterns, AIG, CitiGroup, Morgan
Stanley and this represents the
-
relationship between these companies, in
terms of how one of their economic success
-
depends on another. Now imagine you are
the federal government and you've got a
-
financial crisis. So a lot of these
companies, or some of these companies are
-
starting to fail and you've got to decide
okay do I bail them out, do I save one of
-
these companies? Well now lets use one of
these very simple models to help make that
-
decision. So to do that we need a little
more of an understanding of what
-
these numbers represent. So lets look at
AIG which is right here. And JP Morgan
-
which is right here So now we see a number
of 466 between the two of those. What that
-
number represents is how correlated JP
Morgan success is with AIG success. In
-
particular how correlated their failures are. So if
AIG has a bad day, how likely is it that
-
JP Morgan has a bad day? And we see that
it is a really big number. Now if you look
-
up here at this 94, this represents the link between Wells
Fargo and Lehman Brothers. What that tells
-
us is that Lehman Brothers has a bad day,
well it only has a small effect on Wells
-
Fargo and vice versa. So now you are the
government and you got to decide, okay who do I
-
want to bail out? Nobody or somebody? Lets
look at Lehman Brothers. There's only
-
three lines going in and out of Lehman
Brothers and one is a 94. I guess four
-
lines, one is a 103, one is a 158 and one
is a 155. Those are relatively small
-
numbers. So if you're the government you
say, okay Lehman Brothers has been around
-
a long time and its an important company,
these numbers are pretty small, if they
-
fail it doesn't look like these other
companies would fail. But now lets look at
-
AIG. We've got a 466, we've got a 441,
we've got a 456, we've got a 390 and a
-
490. So there are huge numbers associated
with AIG. Because there is a huge number
-
you basically have to figure, you know
what we probably have to prop AIG back up.
-
Even if you don't want to because if you
don't there is the possibility that this
-
whole system will fail. So what we see
here is the incredible power of models,
-
right to help us make a better decision.
The government did let Lehman Brothers
-
fail, and terrible for Lehman
Brothers, but the economy sort of
-
soldiered on. They didn't let AIG fail and
we don't know for sure that it would've
-
and we don't know for sure that the whole
financial you know apparatus United
-
States, they propped up AIG and you know
we made it, the country made it. It looks
-
they've made a reasonable decision.
Alright so that is big financial
-
decisions. Lets look at something more
fun. This is a simple sort of logic puzzle
-
that will help us see how models can be
useful. Now this is a game called, The
-
Monty Hall Problem and its named after
Monty Hall was the host of a game show
-
called, Lets Make a Deal that aired during
the 1970's. Now the problem I'm going to
-
describe to you is a characterization of a
event that could happen on the show. Its
-
one of several scenarios on the show.
Here's basically how it works. There's
-
three doors. Behind one of these doors is
a prize, behind the other two doors there's some, you
-
know, silly thing like a goat right, or a
woman dressed up in a ballerinas outfit.
-
So one of them had something fantastic
like a new car or a washing machine. Now
-
what you get to do is you pick one door.
So maybe you pick door number one, right,
-
so you pick door number one. Now Monty
knows where the prize is so the two doors
-
you didn't pick, one of those always has
to go behind it, where you know, silly
-
prize behind it. So because one of us
always has a silly prize behind it, he
-
can always show you one of those other two
doors. So you pick door number one, right,
-
and what Monty does, you picked one and
what Monty does is he then opens up door
-
number three and says, here's a goat, then
he says, hey, do you want to switch to
-
door number two? Well, do you? Alright,
that's a hard problem so let's first try
-
to get the logic right then we'll right
down a formal model. So, it's easier to
-
see the logic for this problem by
increasing the number of doors. So let's
-
suppose there's five doors, and now
there's five doors, let's suppose you pick
-
this blue door, this bright blue door. The
probability that you're correct is 1/5th.
-
Right, one of the doors has prize, the
probability you're correct is 1/5th. So
-
the probability that you're not correct Is
4/5ths. So, there's a 1/5th chance you're
-
correct. There's a 4/5ths chance you're
not. Now let's suppose that Monty
-
[inaudible] is also playing this game,
because he knows again, he knows the
-
answer. So Monty is thinking, okay, well,
you know what, I'm gonna show you that
-
it's not behind the yellow door. And then
he says, you know what else I'm going to
-
show you, that it's not behind the pink
door. [inaudible]. I'm gonna be nice, I'm
-
gonna show you it's not behind the green
door. Now he says, do you want to switch
-
to the light blue door to the dark blue
door. Well in this case, you should start
-
thinking, you know initially the
probability I was right was only 1/5th And
-
he revealed all those other doors that
doesn't seem to have the prize. It seems
-
much more likely that this is the correct
door than mine's the correct door and in
-
fact it is much more [inaudible]. The
probability is 4/5ths it's behind that
-
dark blue door and only 1/5th it's behind
your door. So you should switch and you
-
should also switch in the case of two. Now
let's formalize this. This isn't so much,
-
this is, we'll use the simple decision
three model. To show why in fact you
-
should switch. Alright, so let's start
out, we'll just do some basic probability.
-
There's three doors, you pick door number
one, the probability you're right is a
-
third and the probability that it's door
number two is a third and the probability
-
that it's door number three is a third.
Now, what we want to do is break this into
-
two sets. There's a 1/3rd chance that
you're right and there's a 2/3rds chance
-
that you're wrong. After you pick door
number one, the prize can't be moved. So
-
it's either behind door number two, number
three or if you got it right, it's behind
-
door number one. So let's think about what
Monty can do. Monty can basically show you
-
if it's behind door number one or door
number two, he can show you door number
-
three. He can say look, there's the goat.
Well if he does that, because he can
-
always show you one of these doors,
nothing happened to your probability of
-
1/3rd. There's a 1/3rd chance you were
right before since he can always show you
-
a door, there's still only a 1/3rd chance
you're right. Right, alternatively,
-
suppose that, It was behind door number
three well then he can show you door
-
number two. He can say the goat's here.
So, it's still the case that nothing
-
happens to your probability. The reason
why when you think about these two sets,
-
you didn't learn anything. You learn
nothing about this other set right here,
-
the 2/3rds chance you're wrong because he
can always show you a goat. So your
-
initial chan-, your initial probability
being correct was 1/3rd, your final chance
-
of being correct was probably 1/3rd. So
just this sort of idea of drawing circles
-
and writing probabilities allows us to see
that the correct The correct decision on
-
the [inaudible] problem is to switch,
right. Just like when we looked at that
-
financial decision that the Federal
Government had to make with the circles
-
and the arrows, you draw that out, and you
realize the best decision is to let the
-
[inaudible] fail. Bailout AIG. Alright so
lets move on a look sort of the next
-
reason that models can be helpful and that
is comparative statics. What do I mean by
-
that? Well here is a standard model from
economics, what we can think of is
-
comparative statics means you know you
move from one equilibrium to another. So
-
what you see here is that S is a supply
curve, that is a supply curve for some
-
good, and D, D1 and D2 are demand curves.
So what you see is demand shifting out. So
-
when this demand shifts out. In this way
what we get is that more goods are sold
-
the quantity goes up, and the price goes
up so people want more of something, more
-
is gonna get sold and the price is up. So
this is where you start seeing how the
-
equilibrium moves so this is again a
simple example of how. Models help us
-
understand how the world will change,
equilibrium world, just by drawing some
-
simple figures. Alright, reason number
three. Counter factuals, what do I mean by
-
that? Well you can think you only get to
run the world once, you only get to run
-
the tape one time. But if we write models
of the world we can sort of re-run the
-
tape using those models. So here is an
example, in April of 2009, The spring of
-
2009, the Federal Government decided to
implement a recovery plan. Well what you
-
see here is sort of the effect, this line
right here shows the effect with the
-
recovery plan, and this line shows, says,
this is what a model shows what would of
-
happened without the recovery plan. Now we
can't be sure that, that happened, but,
-
you know, at least we have some
understanding, perhaps, of what the effect
-
of recovery plan was, which is great. So
these counter factuals are not going to be
-
exact, there going to be approximate, but
still they help us figure out. After the
-
fact whether a policy was a good policy or
not. Reason number four. To identify and
-
rank levers. So what we are going to do is
look at a simple model of contagion of
-
failure, so this is a model where one
country might fail, so in this case that
-
country is going to be England. Then we
can ask what happens over time, so you can
-
see that initially after England fails, we
see Ireland and Belgium fail, and after
-
that we see France fail. And after that we
see Germany fail. So what this tells us is
-
that in terms of its effect on the worlds
financial system, London is a big lever,
-
so London is something we care about a
great deal. Now lets take another policy
-
issue, climate change. One of the big
things in climate change is the carbon
-
cycle, its one of the models that you use
all the time, simple carbon models. We
-
know that total amount of carbon is fixed,
that can be up in the air or down on the
-
earth, if it is down on the earth it is
better because it doesn't contribute to
-
global warming So if you want to think
about, where do you intervene, you wanna
-
ask, where in this cycle are there big
numbers? Right, so you look here in terms
-
of surface radiation. That's a big number.
Where you think of solar radiation coming
-
in, that's a big number coming in. So, you
wanna, you think about where you want to
-
have a policy in fact, you want to think
about it in terms of where those numbers
-
are large. So if you look at number, the
amount of [inaudible] reflected by the
-
surface, that's only a 30, that's not a
very big leber. Okay reason five,
-
experimental design. Now, what i mean by
experimental design, well, suppose you
-
want to come up with some new policies.
For example, when the Federal Government,
-
when they wanted to, when they were trying
to decide how to auction off the federal
-
airwaves, right, for cell phones, they
wanted raise as much money as possible.
-
Well to test auction designer were best
they ran some experiments. Well the thing
-
you want to do, you want to think about,
so here is the example of the experiment
-
and what you see is, this is a round from
some auction and these are different
-
bidders and, you know, the cost for. That
they paid. What you can do, you want to
-
think, how do I run the best possible
experiment, the most informative possible
-
experiment? And one way to do that, right,
is to construct some simple models.
-
Alright, six, reason six. Institutional
design, now this is a biggie and this is
-
one that means a lot to me. The person you
see at the top here, this is Stan Rider he
-
was one of my advisors in graduate school
and the man at the bottom is Leo Herwicks,
-
he was one of my mentors in graduate
school and Leo won the nobel prize in
-
economics. Leo won the nobel prize for,
which is A field known as mechanism
-
design. Now this diagram is called the
Mount Rider, named after Stan Rider in the
-
previous picture and Ken Mount, one of his
co-authors. And let me explain this
-
diagram to you because it's very
important. What you see here is this
-
theta, here. What this is supposed to
represent is the environment, the set of
-
technologies, people's preferences, those
types of things. X over here represents
-
the outcomes, what we want to have happen.
So how we want to sort of use our
-
technologies and use our labor and use you
know, whatever we have at our disposal to
-
create good outcomes. Now this arrow here
is sort of , it's what we desire, it's
-
like if we could sit around and decide
collectively what kind of outcomes we'd
-
like to have given the technology, this is
what we collectively decide, this is
-
something called a social choice
correspondence or a social choice
-
function. Sort of, what would be the ideal
outcome for society? The thing is that
-
[inaudible] doesn't get the ideal outcome
because what happens is [inaudible] wants
-
though. Because the thing is to get those
outcomes you have to use mechanisms and
-
that what this m stands for, mechanisms.
So a mechanism might be something like a
-
market, a political institution, it might
be a bureaucracy. What we want to ask is,
-
is the outcome we get to the mechanism,
right, which goes like this is that equal
-
to the outcome that we would get, right,
ideally and the better mechanism is, the
-
closer it is to equal to what we ideally
want. Example: so my with my undergraduate
-
students for a homework assignment one
time I said, suppose we allocated classes
-
by a market So, you know, if you had to
bid for classes, would that be a good
-
thing or a bad thing? Well, currently the
way we do it is there's a hierarchy. So
-
seniors, you know fourth year students
register first and then juniors then
-
sophomores and then freshmen. And the
students were asking, should we have a
-
market? And their first reaction is yes,
because markets work. Right. You have
-
this, you know, you have a market, what
you get here is sort of what you expect to
-
get. Right, what you'd like to get, so
it's sort of equal. But when they thought
-
about choosing classes, everybody goes,
wait a minute, markets may not work well
-
and the reason why is, you need to
graduate. And so seniors need specific
-
courses and that's why we let seniors
register first and if people could bid for
-
courses then the fraction that had a lot
of money might bid away the courses from
-
seniors and people might never graduate
from college so a good institution markets
-
may be good in some settings they may not
be in others. The way we figure that out
-
is by using models. Reason seven: To help
choose among policies in institutions.
-
Simple example. Suppose [inaudible] a
market for pollution permits or a cap and
-
trade system. We can write down simple
model and you can tell us which one is
-
going to work better. Or here is another
example, this is picture of the city of
-
Ann Arbor and if you look here you see
some green areas, right, what these green
-
things are... Is green spaces. Their is a
question should the city of Ann Arbor
-
create more green spaces. You might think
of course, green space is a good thing.
-
The problem is when you, if you buy up a
bunch of green space like this area here
-
is all green. What can happen is people
could say lets move next to that, lets
-
build little houses all around here
because it is always going to be green,
-
and that can actually lead to more sprawl.
So what can seem like really good simple
-
ideas may not be good ideas if you
actually construct a model to think
-
through it. [sound] okay, we've covered a
lot. So, let's give a quick summary here.
-
How can models help us? Well first thing
they can do is become real time decision
-
makers. They can help us figure out when
we intervene and when we don't intervene.
-
Second, they can help us with comparative
status. We can figure out, you know what,
-
what's likely to happen, right, if we make
this choice. Third, they can help us with
-
counter-factuals, they can you know
appresent a policy, we can sort of run a
-
model and think about what would have
happened if we hadn't chosen that policy
-
Fourth, we can use them to identify and
rank levers. Often as you've got lots of
-
choices to make models can figure out
which choice might be the best or the most
-
influenced. Fifth, they can help us with
experimental design. They can help us
-
design experiments in order to develop
better policies and better strategies.
-
Sixth, they can help us design
institutions themselves figuring out if we
-
have a market here, should we have a
democracy, should we use a bureaucracy.
-
And seventh, finally, they can help us
choose among policies and institutions so
-
if we are thinking about one policy or
another policy we can use models to decide
-
among the two. All right. Thank you.