< Return to Video

Demand and Supply Shocks in the AD-AS Model

  • 0:00 - 0:01
    - [Instructor] In our last video,
  • 0:01 - 0:04
    we talked about the states
    of short run equilibrium
  • 0:04 - 0:06
    that a country's economy could experience.
  • 0:06 - 0:10
    We showed in AD/AS graphs,
    what positive output gaps
  • 0:10 - 0:13
    and what negative output gaps look like.
  • 0:13 - 0:15
    In this video, we're going
    to actually step back
  • 0:15 - 0:17
    a little bit and talk about the factors
  • 0:17 - 0:20
    that could cause positive and
    negative output gaps to occur
  • 0:20 - 0:21
    in a country.
  • 0:21 - 0:23
    The term we're gonna be
    talking about in this video
  • 0:23 - 0:27
    is shocks to aggregate
    demand and aggregate supply.
  • 0:27 - 0:29
    We're gonna use some graphs to illustrate
  • 0:29 - 0:33
    both positive and negative
    demand and supply shocks
  • 0:33 - 0:35
    and talk about how a
    country's economy will adjust
  • 0:35 - 0:38
    in the short run to a new
    equilibrium following a shock
  • 0:38 - 0:41
    to either AD or AS.
  • 0:41 - 0:43
    Let's start with the
    definition of demand shocks.
  • 0:43 - 0:46
    We'll actually define
    positive demand shocks first,
  • 0:46 - 0:47
    and then we'll show the effect
  • 0:47 - 0:49
    that a positive demand shock would have
  • 0:49 - 0:51
    on a country's economy.
  • 0:51 - 0:54
    A positive demand shock occurs
    anytime there is an increase
  • 0:54 - 0:59
    in AD resulting from an
    increase in either consumption,
  • 0:59 - 1:02
    investment, government
    spending, or net exports.
  • 1:02 - 1:04
    If aggregate demand
    increases due to an increase
  • 1:04 - 1:07
    in one of the different
    national expenditures,
  • 1:07 - 1:09
    we can show the effect that
    this will have in the short run
  • 1:09 - 1:11
    in our AD/AS graph.
  • 1:11 - 1:15
    So let's assume that due to an
    increase in household wealth
  • 1:15 - 1:17
    as a result of rising home prices,
  • 1:17 - 1:20
    households decide to consume
    more goods and services
  • 1:20 - 1:22
    at every price level.
  • 1:22 - 1:26
    This causes an increase in
    aggregate demand to AD1.
  • 1:27 - 1:29
    Now, let's look at the
    effect that this would have
  • 1:29 - 1:31
    on the nation's economy,
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    assuming there is no
    change in the price level
  • 1:34 - 1:36
    and then assuming the price level adjusts
  • 1:36 - 1:37
    to the new level of aggregate demand.
  • 1:37 - 1:39
    This will look quite
    familiar to any student
  • 1:39 - 1:41
    who has already studied microeconomics
  • 1:41 - 1:44
    and knows that if demand for
    a particular good increases
  • 1:44 - 1:46
    and there is no corresponding
    increase in the price
  • 1:46 - 1:48
    of that good, then we will have
  • 1:48 - 1:51
    what's called a disequilibrium
    in the short run.
  • 1:51 - 1:53
    And the same is true on
    a macroeconomic level.
  • 1:53 - 1:55
    If aggregate demand
  • 1:55 - 1:57
    due to increased household
    wealth and consumption
  • 1:57 - 2:00
    and there is no increase in prices,
  • 2:00 - 2:03
    there will be a quantity
    of output demanded
  • 2:03 - 2:05
    that is greater than the
    quantity of output supplied.
  • 2:05 - 2:09
    So here we have a disequilibrium.
    There will be a shortage.
  • 2:09 - 2:12
    This would be a shortage
    of goods and services
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    in the United States if
    aggregate demand increases
  • 2:15 - 2:18
    and there is no corresponding
    increase in the price level.
  • 2:18 - 2:19
    So just like in microeconomics,
  • 2:19 - 2:22
    if there is a disequilibrium in a market,
  • 2:22 - 2:24
    that market must adjust
  • 2:24 - 2:27
    in the form of rising prices in this case.
  • 2:27 - 2:31
    So demand pull inflation will result
  • 2:31 - 2:34
    from a positive demand shock.
  • 2:34 - 2:37
    Demand pull inflation is
    a rise in the price level
  • 2:37 - 2:41
    resulting from an increase
    in aggregate demand.
  • 2:41 - 2:42
    Here we can see that here
  • 2:42 - 2:45
    we have a new equilibrium
    price level of PL2.
  • 2:45 - 2:47
    The higher price level
    of goods and services
  • 2:47 - 2:51
    incentivizes businesses
    to increase the quantity
  • 2:51 - 2:53
    of output that they produce,
  • 2:53 - 2:57
    and it reduces the quantity of
    output demanded by households
  • 2:57 - 2:59
    who previously had increased
    the amount of output
  • 2:59 - 3:01
    they demanded due to rising wealth.
  • 3:01 - 3:04
    And we achieve a new
    equilibrium, I'll call this YE1,
  • 3:05 - 3:08
    a new equilibrium at
    the intersection of SRAS
  • 3:08 - 3:09
    and aggregate demand.
  • 3:09 - 3:11
    In the short run, an
    increase in aggregate demand
  • 3:11 - 3:14
    will cause an increase in
    output beyond full employment
  • 3:14 - 3:17
    and an increase in the
    average price level,
  • 3:17 - 3:20
    this is called demand pull inflation
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    and an increase in the
    quantity of output demanded
  • 3:24 - 3:26
    and supplied in the economy.
  • 3:27 - 3:28
    A positive demand shock occurs
  • 3:28 - 3:30
    when aggregate demand increases.
  • 3:30 - 3:33
    That of course, means that
    a negative demand shock
  • 3:33 - 3:35
    when there is a decrease in AD
  • 3:35 - 3:40
    resulting from a decrease
    in consumption, investment,
  • 3:40 - 3:43
    government spending, or net exports.
  • 3:43 - 3:45
    Let's assume, for example,
  • 3:45 - 3:47
    that interest rates rise in the economy
  • 3:47 - 3:49
    leading firms to demand
  • 3:49 - 3:52
    less new capital equipment and technology
  • 3:52 - 3:55
    causing a decrease in
    private sector investment.
  • 3:55 - 3:58
    Falling investment means
    that at every price level,
  • 3:58 - 4:01
    there will be a smaller quantity of goods
  • 4:01 - 4:04
    and services demanded by the
    nation's firms and households.
  • 4:04 - 4:06
    So what happens if the price level remains
  • 4:06 - 4:08
    at the original price level of PLE?
  • 4:10 - 4:13
    Well, there would be, once
    again a disequilibrium.
  • 4:13 - 4:17
    The quantity of output
    demanded, I'll call that YD,
  • 4:17 - 4:19
    would be less than the
    quantity of output supplied,
  • 4:19 - 4:23
    resulting in a surplus of
    goods and services produced
  • 4:23 - 4:24
    in this country.
  • 4:24 - 4:26
    To restore equilibrium,
  • 4:26 - 4:29
    the equilibrium price level must fall
  • 4:29 - 4:32
    leading to an increase in the
    quantity of output demanded
  • 4:32 - 4:35
    by households and firms and
    the government and foreigners,
  • 4:35 - 4:38
    and a decrease in the
    quantity of outputs supplied
  • 4:38 - 4:39
    by the nation's producers.
  • 4:39 - 4:41
    As the price level falls,
  • 4:41 - 4:44
    we're gonna see a new equilibrium at PL2
  • 4:46 - 4:48
    and a new equilibrium
    level of output at YE1.
  • 4:52 - 4:56
    A negative demand shock
    causes what we call deflation.
  • 4:56 - 4:58
    This is a fall in the average price level
  • 5:00 - 5:03
    or, depending on the level of
    inflation at full employment,
  • 5:03 - 5:05
    this might just be a fall
    in the inflation rate,
  • 5:05 - 5:07
    which is known as disinflation.
  • 5:07 - 5:08
    In other words, if
    inflation is still positive,
  • 5:08 - 5:10
    but it's just lower than it was
  • 5:10 - 5:12
    while the economy is at full employment,
  • 5:12 - 5:13
    then we don't see prices actually fall,
  • 5:13 - 5:15
    we just see lower rates of inflation.
  • 5:15 - 5:19
    A negative demand shock
    causes a decrease in output,
  • 5:19 - 5:21
    a decrease in the price level,
  • 5:21 - 5:24
    and a new equilibrium
    level of national output
  • 5:24 - 5:25
    below the original equilibrium.
  • 5:25 - 5:28
    And of course, this economy
    now has a recessionary gap.
  • 5:28 - 5:32
    We talked about recessionary
    gaps in the previous video.
  • 5:32 - 5:33
    So recessionary gaps can be caused
  • 5:33 - 5:35
    by negative demand shock,
  • 5:35 - 5:38
    inflationary gaps can be caused
    by a positive demand shock.
  • 5:39 - 5:40
    Alright, let's move on and talk about
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    aggregate supply shocks.
  • 5:42 - 5:43
    This time, we're gonna start
  • 5:43 - 5:45
    with negative aggregate supply shocks.
  • 5:45 - 5:49
    A negative aggregate supply shock
  • 5:50 - 5:52
    occurs whenever there is an increase
  • 5:52 - 5:55
    in the costs of production in a country
  • 5:56 - 5:59
    which causes a decrease in
    short run aggregate supply.
  • 6:01 - 6:03
    So assume, for example,
    there's an unexpected increase
  • 6:03 - 6:05
    in energy prices.
  • 6:05 - 6:07
    All businesses, no matter
    what they're producing,
  • 6:07 - 6:09
    depend on electricity.
  • 6:09 - 6:11
    So if electricity prices go up,
  • 6:11 - 6:14
    we would expect to see an inward shift
  • 6:14 - 6:16
    of the short run aggregate supply curve
  • 6:17 - 6:20
    as it costs more to produce
    all goods and services.
  • 6:20 - 6:23
    Now, if the price level were
    to remain the same, at PLE,
  • 6:25 - 6:27
    there would be shortages
  • 6:27 - 6:29
    of goods and services in this country
  • 6:29 - 6:33
    as the quantity of output
    supplied, I'll call that YS,
  • 6:33 - 6:36
    is less than the quantity
    of output demanded.
  • 6:36 - 6:40
    This would represent a
    shortage of goods and services.
  • 6:40 - 6:42
    However, the economy should adjust
  • 6:42 - 6:44
    to a new equilibrium price level
  • 6:44 - 6:45
    and level of national output.
  • 6:45 - 6:48
    And it does so by prices rising.
  • 6:48 - 6:51
    We should see a new
    equilibrium price level,
  • 6:51 - 6:53
    which causes an increase
    in the quantity supplied
  • 6:53 - 6:57
    from what would occur at the
    original price level of PLE,
  • 6:57 - 6:59
    and a decrease in quantity
    of output demanded,
  • 6:59 - 7:03
    and we achieve a new equilibrium
    at a higher price level.
  • 7:03 - 7:04
    This is inflation,
  • 7:04 - 7:06
    just like we saw in the
    positive demand shock
  • 7:08 - 7:09
    section of this video.
  • 7:09 - 7:11
    However, this is not
    demand pull inflation.
  • 7:11 - 7:16
    This type of inflation is what
    we call cost push inflation.
  • 7:16 - 7:20
    Cost push inflation
    results from an increase
  • 7:20 - 7:22
    in the costs of production in a country
  • 7:22 - 7:25
    and a decrease in aggregate supply.
  • 7:25 - 7:27
    This cost push inflation causes a decrease
  • 7:27 - 7:31
    in national output, and we
    have a new equilibrium at YE1.
  • 7:33 - 7:35
    Now we do have a recessionary
    gap here as well.
  • 7:36 - 7:38
    However, this recessionary
    gap is not caused
  • 7:38 - 7:40
    by decreasing demand
    for goods and services,
  • 7:40 - 7:42
    rather decreasing supply.
  • 7:42 - 7:46
    Now of course, there can
    be positive supply shocks,
  • 7:46 - 7:48
    positive supply shock.
  • 7:48 - 7:52
    This would be when
    aggregate supply increases
  • 7:52 - 7:56
    due to falling costs of production.
  • 7:56 - 7:58
    Assume for example, that the government
  • 7:58 - 8:01
    enacts a massive policy of deregulation
  • 8:01 - 8:02
    in the United States.
  • 8:02 - 8:04
    Firms can now produce in the cheapest,
  • 8:04 - 8:08
    most environmentally
    harmful manner imaginable
  • 8:08 - 8:10
    and as a result, at every price level,
  • 8:10 - 8:11
    firms in the United States wish to produce
  • 8:11 - 8:13
    a greater quantity of output.
  • 8:13 - 8:17
    So we see an increase in
    short run aggregate supply
  • 8:17 - 8:18
    to SRAS1.
  • 8:18 - 8:21
    Assume once again that
    the price level remains
  • 8:21 - 8:23
    at its original level of PLE.
  • 8:24 - 8:28
    If the price level did not
    fall following the increase
  • 8:28 - 8:29
    in aggregate supply,
  • 8:29 - 8:32
    we would have a quantity of
    output supplied, that's YS
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    that is greater than the
    quantity of output demanded,
  • 8:35 - 8:37
    we would have surplus output.
  • 8:37 - 8:38
    Just like in microeconomics,
  • 8:38 - 8:41
    if there is a surplus
    of goods being produced,
  • 8:41 - 8:42
    the price must fall.
  • 8:42 - 8:45
    In macro, the price level must fall.
  • 8:45 - 8:47
    And as it does, households, firms,
  • 8:47 - 8:48
    the government and foreigners will demand
  • 8:48 - 8:50
    a greater quantity of output
  • 8:50 - 8:52
    and will achieve a new equilibrium.
  • 8:52 - 8:57
    So this is the new
    equilibrium. Call that PL2.
  • 8:57 - 8:59
    Here we see, once again, prices falling.
  • 8:59 - 9:00
    This could be deflation
  • 9:02 - 9:03
    or depending on the rate of inflation
  • 9:03 - 9:06
    before the positive supply
    shock, it could be disinflation,
  • 9:06 - 9:08
    a lower inflation rate.
  • 9:10 - 9:13
    And as price levels fall,
    we achieve a new equilibrium
  • 9:13 - 9:16
    level of national output at YE1.
  • 9:18 - 9:20
    Alright, we've just walked
    through four different scenarios.
  • 9:20 - 9:22
    We talked about a positive demand shock,
  • 9:22 - 9:24
    which causes an increase
    in aggregate demand,
  • 9:24 - 9:26
    leading to demand pull inflation,
  • 9:26 - 9:30
    and an increase in the
    equilibrium level of output.
  • 9:30 - 9:31
    We also talked about a
    negative demand shock,
  • 9:31 - 9:34
    which causes disinflation or deflation,
  • 9:34 - 9:36
    and a decrease in national output
  • 9:36 - 9:38
    resulting in a recessionary gap.
  • 9:38 - 9:40
    Next, we moved on to supply shocks.
  • 9:40 - 9:43
    A negative supply shock caused
    by an unexpected increase
  • 9:43 - 9:45
    in the costs of production in a country
  • 9:45 - 9:47
    causes cost push inflation.
  • 9:47 - 9:50
    That's higher prices
    and a recessionary gap
  • 9:50 - 9:52
    as the equilibrium output
    falls in a country.
  • 9:52 - 9:54
    A positive supply shock
  • 9:54 - 9:56
    caused by something like deregulation
  • 9:56 - 9:58
    or any other thing that
    causes the cost of production
  • 9:58 - 10:01
    in the country to fall causes
    deflation or disinflation
  • 10:01 - 10:04
    and an increase in the equilibrium
    level of national output.
  • 10:04 - 10:07
    So an increase in short
    aggregate supply is the best
  • 10:07 - 10:09
    of the four scenarios we
    outlined in this video
  • 10:09 - 10:10
    for a country.
  • 10:10 - 10:12
    It actually means that the
    country is experiencing
  • 10:12 - 10:14
    economic growth, increased output,
  • 10:14 - 10:16
    and price level stability.
  • 10:16 - 10:17
    In the next video, we're gonna talk about
  • 10:17 - 10:20
    long run adjustments to a
    country's aggregate output
  • 10:20 - 10:22
    in the AD/AS model.
  • 10:22 - 10:24
    (upbeat music)
    Here we go.
Title:
Demand and Supply Shocks in the AD-AS Model
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Duration:
10:30

English subtitles

Revisions