Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss
-
0:00 - 0:03♪ [music] ♪
-
0:08 - 0:10- [Prof. Alex Tabarrok]
So far in our videos, -
0:10 - 0:14we've looked at the effect
of taxes on market prices, -
0:14 - 0:15but we haven't said much
-
0:15 - 0:18about why government levies taxes
in the first place, -
0:18 - 0:20namely to get revenues.
-
0:20 - 0:24So let's look at that and also
at the cost of raising revenues, -
0:24 - 0:26which is deadweight loss.
-
0:30 - 0:33We can show pretty much
everything we need to show -
0:33 - 0:34with a single diagram.
-
0:34 - 0:37So here is our initial equilibrium.
-
0:37 - 0:39The price with no tax is $2
-
0:39 - 0:43and the quantity exchanged
with no tax is 700 units. -
0:44 - 0:47Now, let's recall
that consumer surplus -
0:47 - 0:50is the consumer's
gain from exchange, -
0:50 - 0:52and it's this green area here,
-
0:52 - 0:54the area underneath the demand curve
-
0:54 - 0:56and above the price,
-
0:56 - 0:58up to the quantity exchanged.
-
0:58 - 1:01So it's the area
above the price of $2 -
1:01 - 1:05and up to the quantity exchanged
of 700 below the demand curve -- -
1:05 - 1:07this area right here.
-
1:07 - 1:11Producer surplus
is the producer's gain from exchange, -
1:11 - 1:13and it’s the area
above the supply curve, -
1:13 - 1:16up to the quantity exchanged
and below the price, -
1:16 - 1:18below the producer's price.
-
1:18 - 1:20Now, you may also recall
-
1:20 - 1:25that a free market maximizes
consumer plus producer surplus. -
1:25 - 1:28What we're going to show
is that when we have a tax, -
1:28 - 1:29this is no longer true.
-
1:29 - 1:31The intervention
into the free market -
1:31 - 1:33means that consumer
and producer surplus -
1:33 - 1:35are not maximized.
-
1:35 - 1:36Let's take a look.
-
1:37 - 1:40So suppose we have tax of $1,
-
1:40 - 1:42and using our wedge method,
-
1:42 - 1:46we can find what the new price
is going to be for the buyers. -
1:46 - 1:47It's going to be here.
-
1:47 - 1:50So the new price
for the buyers is say, $2.50. -
1:51 - 1:55Notice now, the consumer surplus
is not this large green area -
1:55 - 2:00since the price is now higher
and the quantity exchanged -
2:00 - 2:01has fallen.
-
2:01 - 2:06The quantity exchanged
falls from 700 units to 500 units. -
2:06 - 2:09So, the consumer surplus
with the tax -
2:09 - 2:13is this smaller green area here.
-
2:13 - 2:17Again, it's the area
above the buyer's price, -
2:17 - 2:20up to the quantity exchanged,
and below the demand. -
2:20 - 2:23So exactly the definition
hasn't changed, -
2:23 - 2:27but because of the tax
the price to the buyer changes, -
2:27 - 2:29and the quantity demanded exchanges,
-
2:29 - 2:32so the consumer surplus
changes as well. -
2:32 - 2:34In this case, it gets a lot smaller.
-
2:34 - 2:36What about producer surplus?
-
2:36 - 2:41Well, again, the price
which the sellers receive falls. -
2:41 - 2:45So producer surplus is no longer
this large blue area, -
2:45 - 2:49but is now just
this much smaller blue area. -
2:49 - 2:54So the tax reduces consumer surplus
and it reduces producer surplus. -
2:54 - 2:56Now, what about
this area in the middle? -
2:56 - 2:58Well, fortunately,
that's not wasted. -
2:58 - 3:01That, in fact, is tax revenues.
-
3:01 - 3:05So notice that the tax --
the height of the tax here -- is $1, -
3:05 - 3:08and there are 500 units exchanged,
-
3:08 - 3:13so the government gets $1
for each of those 500 units. -
3:13 - 3:16So this revenue,
tax revenue, is the area. -
3:16 - 3:20It's the height
of this box times the width, -
3:20 - 3:24and the height is the tax,
the width is the quantity exchanged. -
3:24 - 3:27So this is tax revenue.
-
3:27 - 3:30Now, what about
this final bit over here? -
3:30 - 3:33That used to be consumer
and producer surplus, -
3:33 - 3:36but now it's deadweight loss.
-
3:36 - 3:40Nobody gets that.
That is lost gains from trade. -
3:40 - 3:44So remember,
people used to trade 700 units. -
3:44 - 3:46Now they're only trading 500 units.
-
3:46 - 3:50Those units
were benefitting people, -
3:50 - 3:51but they're not anymore
-
3:51 - 3:54because these trades
are not occurring. -
3:54 - 3:56I'm going to explain that
in a little bit more detail -
3:56 - 3:58in the next slide.
-
3:59 - 4:01For now, just be sure
that you understand -
4:01 - 4:04how to label these areas.
-
4:04 - 4:07So this is the new consumer surplus,
-
4:07 - 4:10tax revenues,
the new producer surplus, -
4:10 - 4:13and this area is deadweight loss.
-
4:13 - 4:16Okay, let's explain deadweight loss
in a little bit more detail. -
4:16 - 4:20Here's the way
to think about deadweight loss. -
4:20 - 4:21Suppose that you're planning
a trip to New York -
4:21 - 4:24and you're going to take the bus.
-
4:24 - 4:28The benefit of the trip to you,
-
4:29 - 4:31the value of seeing
the sights in New York is $50. -
4:31 - 4:32The cost of the bus ticket is $40.
-
4:32 - 4:34So do you take the trip?
Is it a value? -
4:34 - 4:37Yes, you take the trip.
-
4:37 - 4:38The total value of the trip is $10,
it's a positive, -
4:38 - 4:40so you decide to take the trip.
-
4:40 - 4:41Trips is equal to one.
You make the trip. -
4:41 - 4:44Okay, no problem.
-
4:44 - 4:52Now, suppose there's a tax
of $20 on bus fares -
4:52 - 4:53and let's suppose
that raises the cost of the trip -
4:53 - 4:55from $40 to $60.
-
4:55 - 4:56It doesn't have to raise it
by exactly that amount, -
4:56 - 4:58by exactly the $20,
but let's suppose it does. -
4:58 - 5:04Okay, so the cost
of the trip is now $60. -
5:04 - 5:09The benefit is still $50.
-
5:09 - 5:10So do you take the trip? No.
-
5:10 - 5:12The benefit is less than the cost.
-
5:12 - 5:17So now, no trip.
Trips are equal to zero. -
5:17 - 5:18Does the government
raise any revenue from you? -
5:18 - 5:20No.
-
5:20 - 5:25Since you don't take the trip,
the government makes no revenue. -
5:25 - 5:29Is there a deadweight loss?
Yes. -
5:29 - 5:32You have lost
the value of the trip. -
5:32 - 5:36You used to, when there was no tax,
you took the trip, it was worth $10, -
5:36 - 5:42so the world was better off
by that $10 of value. -
5:43 - 5:47Now with the tax,
you don't take the trip, -
5:47 - 5:48so that $10 is a deadweight loss.
-
5:48 - 5:50It's gone. And notice that it's
not made up for by revenue. -
5:50 - 5:56There's no revenue.
-
5:56 - 5:59So deadweight loss
is the value of the trips not made -
5:59 - 6:00because of the tax,
-
6:00 - 6:03and there's no revenue
on trips which aren't made. -
6:03 - 6:05Government only makes revenue
-
6:05 - 6:08on the trips
which continue to occur. -
6:08 - 6:11So deadweight loss
-
6:11 - 6:14is the value of the trips
not made because of the tax. -
6:14 - 6:17Now, to return this
to a more general case, -
6:17 - 6:20instead of trips,
let's just replace that with trades. -
6:20 - 6:24Deadweight loss
-
6:24 - 6:27is the value of the trades not made
because of the tax. -
6:27 - 6:33Very quickly,
here's our diagram again. -
6:33 - 6:38Before the tax,
there were 700 trades. -
6:38 - 6:39After the tax,
there were 500 trades. -
6:39 - 6:41So these are the 200 trades
which are not made -
6:41 - 6:44because of the tax.
-
6:44 - 6:45And the value
of those 200 trades occurs -
6:45 - 6:47because for these trades,
-
6:47 - 6:52the demanders value them
-
6:52 - 6:55more than it costs the suppliers
to provide those trades. -
6:55 - 6:59So the demanders value the trades
as given by the demand curve, -
6:59 - 7:02the height of the demand curve,
-
7:02 - 7:05the suppliers are willing
to supply those trades, -
7:05 - 7:09the cost to them is given
by the height of the supply curve, -
7:09 - 7:12so the value,
the value minus the costs, -
7:12 - 7:17if you like, is given by this triangle.
-
7:17 - 7:20Because those trades
no longer occur, -
7:20 - 7:25that value is no longer produced,
that's deadweight loss, -
7:25 - 7:27the value of the trades
which don't occur because of the tax. -
7:27 - 7:30Here's one more important point
about deadweight loss. -
7:30 - 7:32Deadweight losses are larger
-
7:32 - 7:35the more elastic the demand curve
holding revenues constant. -
7:35 - 7:41So for example, which of these
goods would we more like to tax -- -
7:42 - 7:46the one on the left
where the demand curve is elastic -
7:47 - 7:48or the one on the right
-
7:48 - 7:49where the demand curve
is more inelastic? -
7:49 - 7:52Notice that tax revenues
are the same. -
7:52 - 7:57So if we have a choice,
which good do we want to tax? -
7:57 - 7:59Well, pretty clearly, we want to tax
the good with the inelastic demand -
7:59 - 8:02because the deadweight losses,
the lost gains from trade, -
8:02 - 8:06are much smaller over here
than they are over here. -
8:06 - 8:12So the tax on the good
with the elastic demand -- -
8:12 - 8:14it's creating a lot of waste
in order to get this revenue. -
8:14 - 8:17Over here, the tax on the good
with the inelastic demand -- -
8:17 - 8:22there's only a little bit of waste
for the same amount of revenue. -
8:22 - 8:26The intuition here is pretty simple.
-
8:26 - 8:29If the demand curve is inelastic,
then a tax won't deter many trades. -
8:29 - 8:31And that's what we don't want.
-
8:31 - 8:34We don't want
to deter a lot of trades, -
8:34 - 8:38because it's the lost gains
from trade -
8:38 - 8:41which create the problem.
-
8:41 - 8:45We don't get any tax revenue
when we deter a trade. -
8:45 - 8:48There's no tax revenue
when you deter an exchange. -
8:48 - 8:50So we want to make sure
-
8:50 - 8:53that we deter
as few exchanges as possible -
8:53 - 8:56and that will maximize our revenue
compared to our loss. -
8:56 - 8:59Now, sometimes economists
are laughed at or derided -
8:59 - 9:03because this implies, for example,
that you ought to tax insulin, -
9:04 - 9:09a good with a very inelastic demand.
-
9:09 - 9:10Now, there are many reasons
-
9:10 - 9:11for taxing some goods
and not other goods, -
9:11 - 9:13depending upon
who uses the insulin, -
9:13 - 9:17whether it's poor people
or rich people -
9:17 - 9:20or how important
health is and so forth. -
9:20 - 9:23Nevertheless, as a general rule,
-
9:23 - 9:26it is better to tax goods
with an inelastic demand -
9:26 - 9:28than goods with an elastic demand.
-
9:28 - 9:29That's important,
-
9:29 - 9:31and let me give you
an illustration of that. -
9:31 - 9:32Here's something
-
9:32 - 9:34which you might think
would be a good idea to tax --- -
9:34 - 9:35luxury yachts.
-
9:35 - 9:36They're only bought by the rich,
-
9:36 - 9:38so you're not really
harming people very much, right? -
9:38 - 9:42Well, maybe so.
-
9:42 - 9:43However, in 1990,
-
9:43 - 9:45the federal government
actually applied a 10% luxury tax -
9:45 - 9:50to many luxury goods,
including pleasure boats or yachts -
9:50 - 9:54with a sales price above $100,000.
-
9:54 - 9:57They expected tax revenue
of $31 million. -
9:57 - 9:59The reality, however,
was quite different. -
9:59 - 10:02The tax revenues
were only $16.6 million. -
10:02 - 10:05That was because sales of yachts
fell tremendously. -
10:05 - 10:08Perhaps the yacht buyers decided,
-
10:08 - 10:12well, they could wait a year or two
before buying their yacht, -
10:12 - 10:13see what happens.
-
10:13 - 10:14Or maybe they decided
-
10:14 - 10:16they could buy their yachts
in other countries. -
10:16 - 10:18Yachts are pretty easy
to move around the world. -
10:18 - 10:21After all, that's what they're for.
-
10:21 - 10:25The net result, in fact,
-
10:25 - 10:28was a loss of 7,000 jobs
in the yacht industry. -
10:28 - 10:30Indeed, the federal government
ended up paying out more -
10:30 - 10:32in unemployment benefits
to unemployed yacht workers -
10:32 - 10:40than it collected
in tax revenues from yachts. -
10:40 - 10:46Because of this, the federal tax
was repealed in 1993. -
10:46 - 10:47The lesson here --
-
10:47 - 10:48don't tax goods
which have really elastic demands. -
10:48 - 10:50You're not going to get
a lot of revenue, -
10:50 - 10:52you're going to deter
a lot of trades, -
10:52 - 10:55and that will create
a lot of deadweight loss, -
10:55 - 10:56and perhaps,
secondary losses for other people, -
10:56 - 10:59such as the workers.
-
10:59 - 11:02That's it actually for taxes.
-
11:02 - 11:05The only thing
we have left to do is subsidies. -
11:05 - 11:06We can actually do that
in the next lecture pretty quickly -
11:06 - 11:09because subsidies
are just negative taxes. -
11:09 - 11:11So everything
we've said about taxes, -
11:11 - 11:14with just a few changes
to our language, -
11:14 - 11:15will go through
with subsidies as well. -
11:15 - 11:17Thanks.
-
11:17 - 11:20- [Narrator]
If you want to test yourself, -
11:20 - 11:23click “Practice Questions.”
-
11:23 - 11:26Or, if you're ready to move on,
just click “Next Video.” -
11:26 - 11:28♪ [music] ♪
- Title:
- Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss
- Description:
-
Why do taxes exist? What are the effects of taxes? We discuss how taxes affect consumer surplus and producer surplus and discuss the concept of deadweight loss at length. We’ll also look at a real-world example of deadweight loss: taxing luxury yachts in the 1990s.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics
Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/deadweight-loss-definition-yacht-tax#QandA
Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/subsidies-definition-subsidy-wedge
- Video Language:
- English
- Team:
- Marginal Revolution University
- Project:
- Micro
- Duration:
- 11:31
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
Cindy Hurlow edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss | ||
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Tax Revenue and Deadweight Loss |