< Return to Video

Generalized Linear Consumption Function

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    Male: In the last video,
    we began our exploration
  • 0:03 - 0:05
    of what a consumption function is.
  • 0:05 - 0:06
    It's a fairly straightforward idea.
  • 0:06 - 0:08
    It's a function that describes how
  • 0:08 - 0:12
    aggregate income can drive
    aggregate consumption.
  • 0:12 - 0:14
    We started with a fairly
    simple model of this,
  • 0:14 - 0:16
    a fairly simple consumption function.
  • 0:16 - 0:18
    It was a linear one.
  • 0:18 - 0:19
    You had some base level of consumption,
  • 0:19 - 0:21
    regardless of aggregate income,
  • 0:21 - 0:23
    and then you had some level of consumption
  • 0:23 - 0:25
    that was essentially induced by having
  • 0:25 - 0:27
    some disposable income.
  • 0:27 - 0:30
    When we plotted this linear
    model, we got a line.
  • 0:30 - 0:32
    We got a line right over here.
  • 0:32 - 0:33
    I pointed out in the last video
  • 0:33 - 0:35
    this does not have to be the only way
  • 0:35 - 0:37
    that a consumption
    function can be described.
  • 0:37 - 0:40
    You might use some fancier
    mathematical tools.
  • 0:40 - 0:42
    Maybe you can construct
    a consumption function.
  • 0:42 - 0:43
    You have an argument.
  • 0:43 - 0:45
    You would argue that
    the marginal propensity
  • 0:45 - 0:48
    to consume is higher at lower levels
  • 0:48 - 0:50
    of disposable income and
    that it kind of tapers out
  • 0:50 - 0:52
    as disposable income, as aggregate
  • 0:52 - 0:54
    disposable income goes up.
  • 0:54 - 0:56
    You might think that maybe you should have
  • 0:56 - 0:58
    a fancier consumption function
  • 0:58 - 1:00
    that when you graph it
    would look like this
  • 1:00 - 1:01
    and then you would have to use things
  • 1:01 - 1:04
    fancier than just what
    we used right over here.
  • 1:04 - 1:05
    What I want to do in this video
  • 1:05 - 1:08
    is focus more on a linear model.
  • 1:08 - 1:10
    The reason why I'm going to focus on
  • 1:10 - 1:13
    a linear model is because,
    one, it's simpler.
  • 1:13 - 1:14
    It'll be easier to manipulate.
  • 1:14 - 1:17
    It's also the model that tends to be used
  • 1:17 - 1:19
    right when people are starting to digest
  • 1:19 - 1:21
    things like consumption functions
  • 1:21 - 1:24
    and building on them to learn about things
  • 1:24 - 1:26
    like, and we'll do this in a few videos,
  • 1:26 - 1:27
    the Keynesian Cross.
  • 1:27 - 1:29
    What I'm going to do is,
    I'm going to do two things.
  • 1:29 - 1:31
    I'm going to generalize this linear
  • 1:31 - 1:33
    consumption function,
    and I'm going to make it
  • 1:33 - 1:35
    a function not just of disposal income,
  • 1:35 - 1:38
    not just of aggregate disposable income,
  • 1:38 - 1:39
    which is what we did in the last video,
  • 1:39 - 1:43
    but as a function of
    income, of aggregate income.
  • 1:43 - 1:46
    Then we will plot that generalized one
  • 1:46 - 1:47
    based on the variables.
  • 1:47 - 1:48
    It's really going to be the same thing.
  • 1:48 - 1:49
    We're just not going to use these numbers.
  • 1:49 - 1:51
    We're going to use
    variables in their place.
  • 1:51 - 1:54
    Let's give ourselves a
    linear consumption function.
  • 1:54 - 1:59
    We can say that aggregate consumption
  • 1:59 - 2:00
    where we're going to have some base level
  • 2:00 - 2:02
    of consumption no matter
    what, even if people
  • 2:02 - 2:05
    have no aggregate income,
    they need to survive.
  • 2:05 - 2:06
    They need food on the table.
  • 2:06 - 2:08
    Maybe they'll have to dig
    in savings somehow to do it.
  • 2:08 - 2:11
    So, some base level of consumption.
  • 2:11 - 2:14
    I'll call that lower case c sub zero.
  • 2:14 - 2:17
    Or lowercase c with a subscript
    of zero right over there.
  • 2:17 - 2:20
    That's the base level
    of aggregate consumption
  • 2:20 - 2:24
    or it's sometimes referred
    to as autonomous consumption.
  • 2:24 - 2:31
    This is autonomous
    consumption because people
  • 2:31 - 2:33
    will do it on their own, or in aggregate
  • 2:33 - 2:34
    they will do it on their
    own, even if they have
  • 2:34 - 2:36
    no aggregate income.
  • 2:36 - 2:40
    Then we will have the part that is due,
  • 2:40 - 2:42
    directly due, to having
    some aggregate income.
  • 2:42 - 2:45
    We call that the induced consumption,
  • 2:45 - 2:46
    because you can view it as being induced
  • 2:46 - 2:48
    by having some aggregate income.
  • 2:48 - 2:51
    Above and beyond what the
    base level of consumption,
  • 2:51 - 2:54
    people are going to consume some fraction
  • 2:54 - 2:56
    of their disposable income.
  • 2:56 - 3:04
    So we'll say disposable income.
  • 3:04 - 3:06
    They're not going to consume all
  • 3:06 - 3:07
    of their disposable income.
  • 3:07 - 3:08
    They might save some of it.
  • 3:08 - 3:09
    So they're going to consume the fraction
  • 3:09 - 3:13
    that's essentially their
    marginal propensity to consume.
  • 3:13 - 3:17
    This right over here, I'll
    do that in this orange color.
  • 3:17 - 3:22
    Marginal propensity to consume.
  • 3:22 - 3:24
    Hopefully this makes intuitive sense.
  • 3:24 - 3:25
    This says, look, if this was 100,
  • 3:25 - 3:28
    people are going to
    consume 100 no matter what,
  • 3:28 - 3:30
    100 billion whatever
    your unit of currency is.
  • 3:30 - 3:32
    Now, if their marginal propensity
  • 3:32 - 3:35
    to consume is, let's say, it is 1/3.
  • 3:35 - 3:37
    You have now above and beyond this
  • 3:37 - 3:41
    people have disposable
    income of let's say 900,
  • 3:41 - 3:44
    this is saying that
    they want to consume 1/3
  • 3:44 - 3:46
    of that disposable income they're getting.
  • 3:46 - 3:48
    That is, if you give them 900 of extra
  • 3:48 - 3:50
    disposable income, they're propensity
  • 3:50 - 3:53
    to consume that incremental income,
  • 3:53 - 3:54
    they're going to consume 1/3 of it.
  • 3:54 - 3:56
    So this would be 1/3, so it would be 900.
  • 3:56 - 3:58
    Let me give an example.
  • 3:58 - 4:01
    If you had a situation,
    you could have a situation,
  • 4:01 - 4:05
    where c-nought is equal to 100.
  • 4:05 - 4:15
    If you have disposable
    income is equal to 900,
  • 4:15 - 4:18
    and c1 is equal to 1/3, or we could say
  • 4:18 - 4:22
    0.333 repeating forever, c1 is 1/3.
  • 4:22 - 4:24
    Then this makes sense.
  • 4:24 - 4:26
    On their own people
    would consume this much,
  • 4:26 - 4:27
    but now they have this disposable income.
  • 4:27 - 4:29
    Their marginal propensity to consume
  • 4:29 - 4:31
    if you give them 900 extra of income,
  • 4:31 - 4:33
    they're going to consume 1/3 of that.
  • 4:33 - 4:35
    So then you're going to
    have, your consumption
  • 4:35 - 4:38
    is going to be equal to, for
    this case right over here,
  • 4:38 - 4:48
    your consumption is going to
    be 100 plus 1/3 times 900.
  • 4:48 - 4:50
    So your consumption in this situation,
  • 4:50 - 4:54
    your induced consumption, 1/3 times 900,
  • 4:54 - 4:57
    would be 300, maybe it's
    in billions of dollars,
  • 4:57 - 4:58
    300 billion dollars.
  • 4:58 - 5:01
    Then your autonomous
    consumption would be 100.
  • 5:01 - 5:05
    They would add up to 400.
  • 5:05 - 5:08
    Once again, this is autonomous
    and this is induced.
  • 5:08 - 5:16
    Autonomous, this right over
    here is induced consumption.
  • 5:16 - 5:18
    Now, I did write it in general terms.
  • 5:18 - 5:21
    I'm using variables here
    instead of, or constants, really
  • 5:21 - 5:26
    instead of using the numbers
    we saw in the last example.
  • 5:26 - 5:28
    But I also said that I would express
  • 5:28 - 5:31
    aggregate consumption
    as a function not just
  • 5:31 - 5:34
    of disposable income
    but of aggregate income;
  • 5:34 - 5:36
    not just of aggregate disposable income
  • 5:36 - 5:37
    but aggregate income.
  • 5:37 - 5:39
    The relationship is fairly simple between
  • 5:39 - 5:42
    disposable income and overall income.
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    We saw over here, in
    aggregate, you have income,
  • 5:46 - 5:48
    but the government in
    most modern economies
  • 5:48 - 5:50
    takes some fraction of that out for taxes.
  • 5:50 - 5:53
    What's left over is disposable income.
  • 5:53 - 5:57
    Just a reminder, income in aggregate,
  • 5:57 - 5:59
    aggregate income is the same thing as
  • 5:59 - 6:00
    aggregate expenditures,
  • 6:00 - 6:01
    which is the same thing
    as aggregate output.
  • 6:01 - 6:04
    This right over here is GDP.
  • 6:04 - 6:07
    So this right over here is, let me do this
  • 6:07 - 6:09
    in a color, I've used
    almost all my colors.
  • 6:09 - 6:11
    This is equal to GDP.
  • 6:11 - 6:15
    Disposable income is essentially GDP,
  • 6:15 - 6:21
    or you could say aggregate
    income, minus taxes.
  • 6:21 - 6:23
    I'm going to do the taxes
    in a different color.
  • 6:23 - 6:27
    Minus taxes.
  • 6:27 - 6:28
    So we can express disposable income
  • 6:28 - 6:32
    as aggregate income, this right over here
  • 6:32 - 6:37
    is the same thing as
    aggregate income minus taxes.
  • 6:37 - 6:39
    We could rewrite our
    whole thing over again.
  • 6:39 - 6:44
    Aggregate consumption is equal
    to autonomous consumption
  • 6:44 - 6:46
    plus the marginal propensity to consume
  • 6:46 - 6:52
    times aggregate income,
    which is the same thing
  • 6:52 - 6:59
    as GDP, times aggregate
    income minus taxes.
  • 6:59 - 7:01
    We fully generalized
    our consumption function
  • 7:01 - 7:04
    and now we've written it as a
    function of aggregate income,
  • 7:04 - 7:07
    not just aggregate disposable income.
  • 7:07 - 7:09
    To make you comfortable
    that this is still a line
  • 7:09 - 7:12
    if we were to plot it as a function
  • 7:12 - 7:14
    of aggregate income instead
    of disposable income,
  • 7:14 - 7:16
    let me manipulate this thing a little bit.
  • 7:16 - 7:19
    We could distribute c1, which is our
  • 7:19 - 7:22
    marginal propensity to consume, and we get
  • 7:22 - 7:27
    aggregate consumption is equal
    to autonomous consumption
  • 7:27 - 7:29
    and then we're going to distribute this,
  • 7:29 - 7:31
    plus c, so we're going to multiply it
  • 7:31 - 7:32
    times both of these terms,
  • 7:32 - 7:35
    plus our marginal propensity to consume
  • 7:35 - 7:39
    times aggregate income,
  • 7:39 - 7:42
    and then minus our marginal
    propensity to consume
  • 7:42 - 7:47
    times our taxes.
  • 7:47 - 7:50
    Since we want it as a
    function of aggregate income,
  • 7:50 - 7:52
    everything else here is really a constant.
  • 7:52 - 7:54
    We're assuming that those
    aren't going to change.
  • 7:54 - 7:55
    Those are constant variables.
  • 7:55 - 7:57
    What we could do is we could rewrite this
  • 7:57 - 7:59
    in a form that you're
    probably familiar with.
  • 7:59 - 8:01
    Back in algebra class
    you probably remember
  • 8:01 - 8:07
    you can write it in the form y=mx+b where
  • 8:07 - 8:10
    x is the independent variable,
  • 8:10 - 8:11
    y is the dependent variable.
  • 8:11 - 8:12
    If you were to plot this,
  • 8:12 - 8:18
    on the horizontal axis is your x axis,
  • 8:18 - 8:20
    your vertical axis is your y axis.
  • 8:20 - 8:22
    This right over here
    would have a y intercept,
  • 8:22 - 8:27
    or your vertical axis intercept
    of b, right over there.
  • 8:27 - 8:29
    Then it would be a line with slope m.
  • 8:29 - 8:33
    If you were to take your
    rise divided by your run,
  • 8:33 - 8:34
    or how much you move up
    when you move to the right
  • 8:34 - 8:38
    a certain amount, that gives you your m.
  • 8:38 - 8:40
    Slope is equal to m.
  • 8:40 - 8:42
    The same analogy is here.
  • 8:42 - 8:44
    We can rewrite this in that form,
  • 8:44 - 8:47
    where our dependent
    variable is no longer y.
  • 8:47 - 8:49
    Our dependent variable
    is aggregate consumption.
  • 8:49 - 8:53
    Our independent variable is
    not x, it is aggregate income.
  • 8:53 - 8:55
    So let's write it in that form.
  • 8:55 - 8:58
    We can write it as dependent variable, c,
  • 8:58 - 8:59
    which we'll plot on the vertical axis,
  • 8:59 - 9:03
    is equal to the marginal
    propensity to consume
  • 9:03 - 9:07
    times aggregate income,
  • 9:07 - 9:09
    I'll do that purple color,
  • 9:09 - 9:10
    times aggregate income,
  • 9:10 - 9:15
    plus autonomous consumption,
  • 9:15 - 9:22
    minus marginal propensity
    to consume times taxes.
  • 9:22 - 9:24
    It looks all complicated, but you just
  • 9:24 - 9:27
    have to realize that this
    part right over here,
  • 9:27 - 9:30
    this is all a constant.
  • 9:30 - 9:35
    It is analogous to the
    b if you were to write
  • 9:35 - 9:37
    things in kind of
    traditional slope intercept
  • 9:37 - 9:39
    form right over here.
  • 9:39 - 9:41
    When we plot the line, if you have no
  • 9:41 - 9:44
    aggregate income, this is what your
  • 9:44 - 9:46
    consumption is going to be.
  • 9:46 - 9:48
    Let me draw that.
  • 9:48 - 9:55
    Once again, our dependent
    variable is aggregate consumption.
  • 9:55 - 9:57
    Our independent variable
    in this is no longer
  • 9:57 - 9:59
    disposable income like
    we did in the last video.
  • 9:59 - 10:05
    It is now aggregate income.
  • 10:05 - 10:07
    If there's no aggregate income,
  • 10:07 - 10:08
    this is the independent
    variable right over here,
  • 10:08 - 10:10
    if there's no aggregate income,
  • 10:10 - 10:11
    then your consumption is just going to be
  • 10:11 - 10:13
    this value right over here.
  • 10:13 - 10:14
    So your consumption is just going to be
  • 10:14 - 10:17
    that value right over
    there, which is c-nought
  • 10:17 - 10:21
    minus c1 times t.
  • 10:21 - 10:26
    Then as you have larger values of
  • 10:26 - 10:29
    aggregate income, c1, that fraction of it,
  • 10:29 - 10:32
    is what's going to contribute
    to the induced consumption.
  • 10:32 - 10:35
    What you essentially
    have is this is the slope
  • 10:35 - 10:37
    of our line, this right
    over here is our slope.
  • 10:37 - 10:39
    Just to kind of draw the analogy,
  • 10:39 - 10:42
    if you were to say y
    is equal to mx plus b.
  • 10:42 - 10:44
    Actually, maybe I'll write it like this.
  • 10:44 - 10:50
    If you were to write c is equal to m ...
  • 10:50 - 10:52
    and I don't want to
    confuse you if this m and b
  • 10:52 - 10:53
    seem completely foreign.
  • 10:53 - 10:56
    It comes from kind of
    a traditional algebra
  • 10:56 - 10:58
    grounding in slope and y intercept.
  • 10:58 - 11:05
    If I were to say c is equal to my plus b,
  • 11:05 - 11:06
    this is the slope.
  • 11:06 - 11:10
    This is our vertical or our
    dependent variable intercept
  • 11:10 - 11:12
    right over here.
  • 11:12 - 11:14
    That's where we intercept the dependent
  • 11:14 - 11:15
    variable axis.
  • 11:15 - 11:16
    And this is our slope.
  • 11:16 - 11:18
    It's our marginal propensity to consume.
  • 11:18 - 11:21
    Our line will look something like this,
  • 11:21 - 11:25
    where the slope is equal to the marginal
  • 11:25 - 11:29
    propensity to consume,
    which is equal to c1.
  • 11:29 - 11:30
    If people all of a sudden are more likely
  • 11:30 - 11:33
    to spend a larger
    fraction of their income,
  • 11:33 - 11:37
    then the marginal propensity to consume
  • 11:37 - 11:39
    would be higher and our
    slope would be higher.
  • 11:39 - 11:40
    We would have a line that looks like that.
  • 11:40 - 11:42
    We always assume that the marginal
  • 11:42 - 11:44
    propensity to consume will be less than 1.
  • 11:44 - 11:46
    So we'll never have a slope of 1.
  • 11:46 - 11:48
    We'll also never have a negative slope
  • 11:48 - 11:49
    because we assume that this is positive.
  • 11:49 - 11:52
    If people are more likely
    to save than consume
  • 11:52 - 11:55
    when they have extra
    income, then this line
  • 11:55 - 11:56
    might look something like that.
  • 11:56 - 11:58
    It might have a lower slope.
Title:
Generalized Linear Consumption Function
Description:

Generalizing a linear consumption function as a function of aggregate income

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Duration:
11:59

English subtitles

Revisions