-
Male: In the last video,
we began our exploration
-
of what a consumption function is.
-
It's a fairly straightforward idea.
-
It's a function that describes how
-
aggregate income can drive
aggregate consumption.
-
We started with a fairly
simple model of this,
-
a fairly simple consumption function.
-
It was a linear one.
-
You had some base level of consumption,
-
regardless of aggregate income,
-
and then you had some level of consumption
-
that was essentially induced by having
-
some disposable income.
-
When we plotted this linear
model, we got a line.
-
We got a line right over here.
-
I pointed out in the last video
-
this does not have to be the only way
-
that a consumption
function can be described.
-
You might use some fancier
mathematical tools.
-
Maybe you can construct
a consumption function.
-
You have an argument.
-
You would argue that
the marginal propensity
-
to consume is higher at lower levels
-
of disposable income and
that it kind of tapers out
-
as disposable income, as aggregate
-
disposable income goes up.
-
You might think that maybe you should have
-
a fancier consumption function
-
that when you graph it
would look like this
-
and then you would have to use things
-
fancier than just what
we used right over here.
-
What I want to do in this video
-
is focus more on a linear model.
-
The reason why I'm going to focus on
-
a linear model is because,
one, it's simpler.
-
It'll be easier to manipulate.
-
It's also the model that tends to be used
-
right when people are starting to digest
-
things like consumption functions
-
and building on them to learn about things
-
like, and we'll do this in a few videos,
-
the Keynesian Cross.
-
What I'm going to do is,
I'm going to do two things.
-
I'm going to generalize this linear
-
consumption function,
and I'm going to make it
-
a function not just of disposal income,
-
not just of aggregate disposable income,
-
which is what we did in the last video,
-
but as a function of
income, of aggregate income.
-
Then we will plot that generalized one
-
based on the variables.
-
It's really going to be the same thing.
-
We're just not going to use these numbers.
-
We're going to use
variables in their place.
-
Let's give ourselves a
linear consumption function.
-
We can say that aggregate consumption
-
where we're going to have some base level
-
of consumption no matter
what, even if people
-
have no aggregate income,
they need to survive.
-
They need food on the table.
-
Maybe they'll have to dig
in savings somehow to do it.
-
So, some base level of consumption.
-
I'll call that lower case c sub zero.
-
Or lowercase c with a subscript
of zero right over there.
-
That's the base level
of aggregate consumption
-
or it's sometimes referred
to as autonomous consumption.
-
This is autonomous
consumption because people
-
will do it on their own, or in aggregate
-
they will do it on their
own, even if they have
-
no aggregate income.
-
Then we will have the part that is due,
-
directly due, to having
some aggregate income.
-
We call that the induced consumption,
-
because you can view it as being induced
-
by having some aggregate income.
-
Above and beyond what the
base level of consumption,
-
people are going to consume some fraction
-
of their disposable income.
-
So we'll say disposable income.
-
They're not going to consume all
-
of their disposable income.
-
They might save some of it.
-
So they're going to consume the fraction
-
that's essentially their
marginal propensity to consume.
-
This right over here, I'll
do that in this orange color.
-
Marginal propensity to consume.
-
Hopefully this makes intuitive sense.
-
This says, look, if this was 100,
-
people are going to
consume 100 no matter what,
-
100 billion whatever
your unit of currency is.
-
Now, if their marginal propensity
-
to consume is, let's say, it is 1/3.
-
You have now above and beyond this
-
people have disposable
income of let's say 900,
-
this is saying that
they want to consume 1/3
-
of that disposable income they're getting.
-
That is, if you give them 900 of extra
-
disposable income, they're propensity
-
to consume that incremental income,
-
they're going to consume 1/3 of it.
-
So this would be 1/3, so it would be 900.
-
Let me give an example.
-
If you had a situation,
you could have a situation,
-
where c-nought is equal to 100.
-
If you have disposable
income is equal to 900,
-
and c1 is equal to 1/3, or we could say
-
0.333 repeating forever, c1 is 1/3.
-
Then this makes sense.
-
On their own people
would consume this much,
-
but now they have this disposable income.
-
Their marginal propensity to consume
-
if you give them 900 extra of income,
-
they're going to consume 1/3 of that.
-
So then you're going to
have, your consumption
-
is going to be equal to, for
this case right over here,
-
your consumption is going to
be 100 plus 1/3 times 900.
-
So your consumption in this situation,
-
your induced consumption, 1/3 times 900,
-
would be 300, maybe it's
in billions of dollars,
-
300 billion dollars.
-
Then your autonomous
consumption would be 100.
-
They would add up to 400.
-
Once again, this is autonomous
and this is induced.
-
Autonomous, this right over
here is induced consumption.
-
Now, I did write it in general terms.
-
I'm using variables here
instead of, or constants, really
-
instead of using the numbers
we saw in the last example.
-
But I also said that I would express
-
aggregate consumption
as a function not just
-
of disposable income
but of aggregate income;
-
not just of aggregate disposable income
-
but aggregate income.
-
The relationship is fairly simple between
-
disposable income and overall income.
-
We saw over here, in
aggregate, you have income,
-
but the government in
most modern economies
-
takes some fraction of that out for taxes.
-
What's left over is disposable income.
-
Just a reminder, income in aggregate,
-
aggregate income is the same thing as
-
aggregate expenditures,
-
which is the same thing
as aggregate output.
-
This right over here is GDP.
-
So this right over here is, let me do this
-
in a color, I've used
almost all my colors.
-
This is equal to GDP.
-
Disposable income is essentially GDP,
-
or you could say aggregate
income, minus taxes.
-
I'm going to do the taxes
in a different color.
-
Minus taxes.
-
So we can express disposable income
-
as aggregate income, this right over here
-
is the same thing as
aggregate income minus taxes.
-
We could rewrite our
whole thing over again.
-
Aggregate consumption is equal
to autonomous consumption
-
plus the marginal propensity to consume
-
times aggregate income,
which is the same thing
-
as GDP, times aggregate
income minus taxes.
-
We fully generalized
our consumption function
-
and now we've written it as a
function of aggregate income,
-
not just aggregate disposable income.
-
To make you comfortable
that this is still a line
-
if we were to plot it as a function
-
of aggregate income instead
of disposable income,
-
let me manipulate this thing a little bit.
-
We could distribute c1, which is our
-
marginal propensity to consume, and we get
-
aggregate consumption is equal
to autonomous consumption
-
and then we're going to distribute this,
-
plus c, so we're going to multiply it
-
times both of these terms,
-
plus our marginal propensity to consume
-
times aggregate income,
-
and then minus our marginal
propensity to consume
-
times our taxes.
-
Since we want it as a
function of aggregate income,
-
everything else here is really a constant.
-
We're assuming that those
aren't going to change.
-
Those are constant variables.
-
What we could do is we could rewrite this
-
in a form that you're
probably familiar with.
-
Back in algebra class
you probably remember
-
you can write it in the form y=mx+b where
-
x is the independent variable,
-
y is the dependent variable.
-
If you were to plot this,
-
on the horizontal axis is your x axis,
-
your vertical axis is your y axis.
-
This right over here
would have a y intercept,
-
or your vertical axis intercept
of b, right over there.
-
Then it would be a line with slope m.
-
If you were to take your
rise divided by your run,
-
or how much you move up
when you move to the right
-
a certain amount, that gives you your m.
-
Slope is equal to m.
-
The same analogy is here.
-
We can rewrite this in that form,
-
where our dependent
variable is no longer y.
-
Our dependent variable
is aggregate consumption.
-
Our independent variable is
not x, it is aggregate income.
-
So let's write it in that form.
-
We can write it as dependent variable, c,
-
which we'll plot on the vertical axis,
-
is equal to the marginal
propensity to consume
-
times aggregate income,
-
I'll do that purple color,
-
times aggregate income,
-
plus autonomous consumption,
-
minus marginal propensity
to consume times taxes.
-
It looks all complicated, but you just
-
have to realize that this
part right over here,
-
this is all a constant.
-
It is analogous to the
b if you were to write
-
things in kind of
traditional slope intercept
-
form right over here.
-
When we plot the line, if you have no
-
aggregate income, this is what your
-
consumption is going to be.
-
Let me draw that.
-
Once again, our dependent
variable is aggregate consumption.
-
Our independent variable
in this is no longer
-
disposable income like
we did in the last video.
-
It is now aggregate income.
-
If there's no aggregate income,
-
this is the independent
variable right over here,
-
if there's no aggregate income,
-
then your consumption is just going to be
-
this value right over here.
-
So your consumption is just going to be
-
that value right over
there, which is c-nought
-
minus c1 times t.
-
Then as you have larger values of
-
aggregate income, c1, that fraction of it,
-
is what's going to contribute
to the induced consumption.
-
What you essentially
have is this is the slope
-
of our line, this right
over here is our slope.
-
Just to kind of draw the analogy,
-
if you were to say y
is equal to mx plus b.
-
Actually, maybe I'll write it like this.
-
If you were to write c is equal to m ...
-
and I don't want to
confuse you if this m and b
-
seem completely foreign.
-
It comes from kind of
a traditional algebra
-
grounding in slope and y intercept.
-
If I were to say c is equal to my plus b,
-
this is the slope.
-
This is our vertical or our
dependent variable intercept
-
right over here.
-
That's where we intercept the dependent
-
variable axis.
-
And this is our slope.
-
It's our marginal propensity to consume.
-
Our line will look something like this,
-
where the slope is equal to the marginal
-
propensity to consume,
which is equal to c1.
-
If people all of a sudden are more likely
-
to spend a larger
fraction of their income,
-
then the marginal propensity to consume
-
would be higher and our
slope would be higher.
-
We would have a line that looks like that.
-
We always assume that the marginal
-
propensity to consume will be less than 1.
-
So we'll never have a slope of 1.
-
We'll also never have a negative slope
-
because we assume that this is positive.
-
If people are more likely
to save than consume
-
when they have extra
income, then this line
-
might look something like that.
-
It might have a lower slope.