Return to Video

Lawrence Lessig Keynote - e-G8

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    [I'm using this English GB track to script audio descriptions - CA] [Innovation & its Enemies]
  • 0:03 - 0:05
    [<1>]
  • 0:05 - 0:05
    So, I apologize that I am going to introduce these
  • 0:05 - 0:07
    ideas so early in the morning,
  • 0:07 - 0:09
    after such a late night last night.
  • 0:09 - 0:14
    But I'll like you to think of an alcoholic.
  • 0:14 - 0:14
    [photo of drunk sleeping on the earth]
  • 0:15 - 0:15
    And I don't mean the kind of drop-dead
  • 0:15 - 0:16
    drunken alcoholic,
  • 0:16 - 0:17
    [picture of AA meeting]
  • 0:17 - 0:20
    or somebody who is even recovering from AA.
  • 0:20 - 0:21
    [Bottles: vodka and other spirits]
  • 0:21 - 0:23
    I am thinking just of the regular alcoholic
  • 0:23 - 0:30
    who works hard to control the addiction he has.
  • 0:30 - 0:32
    But this particular alcoholic, I want you to
  • 0:32 - 0:36
    imagine that, in addition to the addiction to alcohol,
  • 0:36 - 0:39
    he has a second addiction as well.
  • 0:39 - 0:43
    Not the debilitating addiction that keeps him
  • 0:43 - 0:44
    down all day.
  • 0:44 - 0:46
    And not a recovered drug addict.
  • 0:46 - 0:48
    But an addiction nonetheless
  • 0:48 - 0:51
    that continues to pull him in another way,
  • 0:51 - 0:52
    away from what he wants to do.
  • 0:52 - 0:59
    A person with two addictions, pulling different ways,
  • 0:59 - 1:01
    making him vulnerable, making him dangerous,
  • 1:01 - 1:04
    as he is susceptible to the temptations of each.
  • 1:04 - 1:09
    And the trick for this soul is to control
  • 1:09 - 1:14
    and to regulate these addictions, to keep them under control.
  • 1:14 - 1:17
    Now I give you this picture because
  • 1:17 - 1:23
    I think it is a good picture of modern democratic government.
  • 1:23 - 1:26
    Modern democratic government too, is pulled
  • 1:26 - 1:28
    by these two separate kinds of addictions.
  • 1:28 - 1:31
    Constantly pulled by craziness.
  • 1:31 - 1:35
    Craziness to one side for the people, or at least wrongly,
  • 1:35 - 1:37
    as the people push the government to do what
  • 1:37 - 1:40
    is not in the public interest.
  • 1:40 - 1:41
    Think of Peronism,
  • 1:41 - 1:44
    or the kind of populism that drove the
  • 1:44 - 1:49
    banking and housing bubble in the United States.
  • 1:49 - 1:52
    Or in the other hand, an addiction to special interests,
  • 1:52 - 1:56
    let's call them "incumbents", constantly tempting the government
  • 1:56 - 1:59
    to do something crazy for public policy
  • 1:59 - 2:01
    in the name of benefiting the incumbents.
  • 2:01 - 2:04
    And here, in the United States at least, you can think about
  • 2:04 - 2:08
    just about every major policy issue where this addiction
  • 2:08 - 2:10
    has had its role.
  • 2:10 - 2:12
    Each of these pulling constantly,
  • 2:12 - 2:17
    constantly tempting, always the government is vulnerable.
  • 2:17 - 2:22
    Always, as libertarians insist, it is dangerous
  • 2:22 - 2:25
    because it can always be exploited
  • 2:25 - 2:30
    by one of these two sources at least,
  • 2:30 - 2:35
    the temptations of the incumbents.
  • 2:35 - 2:39
    OK now, the Internet is a platform,
  • 2:39 - 2:41
    it is an architecture,
  • 2:41 - 2:46
    it is an architecture with consequences.
  • 2:46 - 2:48
    It is an architecture that enables innovation,
  • 2:48 - 2:52
    or at least enables a certain kind of innovation.
  • 2:52 - 2:56
    Think of the history of innovation in the Internet.
  • 2:56 - 3:02
    Netscape, started by a drop-out from undergraduate university.
  • 3:02 - 3:04
    Hotmail, started by an Indian immigrant, sold to
  • 3:04 - 3:07
    Microsoft for 400 million dollars.
  • 3:07 - 3:11
    ICQ, started by an Israeli kid and then his father, who was here,
  • 3:11 - 3:14
    selling it to AOL for 400 million dollars.
  • 3:14 - 3:17
    Google, started by two Stanford dropouts.
  • 3:17 - 3:21
    Napster, started by a dropout and someone who
  • 3:21 - 3:22
    hadn't yet been able to be a dropout,
  • 3:22 - 3:24
    sitting on this panel, here, today.
  • 3:24 - 3:28
    Youtube, started by two Stanford students.
  • 3:28 - 3:35
    Kazaa and Skype, started by kids from Denmark and Sweden.
  • 3:35 - 3:38
    And then, of course, Facebook, and Twitter, started by kids.
  • 3:38 - 3:42
    What unites all of these innovations?
  • 3:42 - 3:48
    They were all done by kids, dropouts, and non-americans.
  • 3:48 - 3:50
    Outsiders.
  • 3:50 - 3:54
    Because this is what that architecture invited.
  • 3:54 - 3:58
    It invited outsider innovation.
  • 3:58 - 4:05
    Now, outsider innovation threatens the "incumbents".
  • 4:05 - 4:08
    Skype threatens telephone companies.
  • 4:08 - 4:11
    Youtube threatens television companies.
  • 4:11 - 4:13
    Netflix threatens cable companies.
  • 4:13 - 4:16
    Twitter threatens sanity -
  • 4:16 - 4:18
    not that sanity was ever an incumbent.
  • 4:18 - 4:25
    But then the threatened respond to this threat.
  • 4:25 - 4:30
    By turning to the addict, modern democratic government,
  • 4:30 - 4:34
    and using drug of choice (which in the United States at least
  • 4:34 - 4:37
    is an endless amount of campaign cash),
  • 4:37 - 4:42
    using that drug to secure the protection
  • 4:42 - 4:50
    against these threats that the incumbent faces.
  • 4:50 - 4:54
    Now this was the point that I think president Sarkozy missed yesterday,
  • 4:54 - 4:57
    and the question that Jeff Jarvis raised when he suggested
  • 4:57 - 5:00
    that the principle that should be carried to the G8
  • 5:00 - 5:03
    is that the government "do no harm".
  • 5:03 - 5:05
    President Sarkozy said, no, but we have important
  • 5:05 - 5:08
    policy issues to resolve. But here is the point.
  • 5:08 - 5:13
    We get that there are "hard policy" issues here.
  • 5:13 - 5:17
    From copyright, to privacy to security to the problem of monopoly. We get it.
  • 5:17 - 5:22
    The point is, is we don't trust the answers the
  • 5:22 - 5:24
    government gives.
  • 5:24 - 5:27
    And for good reasons we don't trust these answers,
  • 5:27 - 5:31
    because on issue after issue, the answer that
  • 5:31 - 5:35
    modern democratic government has given here,
  • 5:35 - 5:39
    is an answer that happens to benefit
  • 5:39 - 5:41
    the incumbents.
  • 5:41 - 5:45
    And ignores an answer that might actually
  • 5:45 - 5:49
    encourage more innovation.
  • 5:49 - 5:51
    So think for example about the matter of copyright.
  • 5:51 - 5:55
    Of course we need a system of copyright
  • 5:55 - 5:58
    that guarantees that creators get compensated
  • 5:58 - 6:01
    and secures their independence to create.
  • 6:01 - 6:05
    No one serious denies that we have to have
  • 6:05 - 6:08
    that system of protection.
  • 6:08 - 6:12
    The question is not whether copyright should be protected.
  • 6:12 - 6:16
    The question is how to protect copyright
  • 6:16 - 6:17
    in a digital era.
  • 6:17 - 6:19
    Whether the architecture of copyright,
  • 6:19 - 6:22
    built for the XIX century,
  • 6:22 - 6:25
    continues to make sense in the XXI.
  • 6:25 - 6:30
    And what is the architecture that would make sense in the XXI?
  • 6:30 - 6:36
    Now, is this the question the government is asking?
  • 6:36 - 6:38
    I think the answer to that is no.
  • 6:38 - 6:42
    Instead, what the government is proposing,
  • 6:42 - 6:45
    around the world, specially here,
  • 6:45 - 6:47
    and I apologize to my colleagues from France,
  • 6:47 - 6:49
    but this is a technical legal term.
  • 6:49 - 6:54
    The proposal suggested here is a "brain-dead"
  • 6:54 - 7:00
    3-strikes proposal that happens to benefit incumbents.
  • 7:01 - 7:05
    Ignoring the potential of innovation that could come from
  • 7:05 - 7:07
    a new architecture for securing copyright.
  • 7:07 - 7:11
    And you don't have to take my view for this.
  • 7:11 - 7:14
    The recent report from the conservative government in Britain,
  • 7:14 - 7:17
    the Hargreaves report, says of copyright:
  • 7:17 - 7:20
    "Could it be true that laws designed more than three centuries
  • 7:20 - 7:23
    ago with the express purpose of creating economic
  • 7:23 - 7:25
    incentives for innovation,
  • 7:25 - 7:27
    by protecting creators' rights
  • 7:27 - 7:31
    are today obstructing innovation and economic growth?"
  • 7:31 - 7:33
    The short answer is: "yes".
  • 7:33 - 7:37
    "In the case of copyright policy, there is no doubt
  • 7:37 - 7:40
    that the persuasive powers of celebrities and
  • 7:40 - 7:42
    important UK creative companies
  • 7:42 - 7:44
    have distorted policy outcomes."
  • 7:44 - 7:48
    And not just, I suggest, in the UK.
  • 7:48 - 7:50
    Think about the question of broadband policy.
  • 7:50 - 7:53
    Europe, has actually been quite successful,
  • 7:53 - 7:57
    in pushing competition in broadband,
  • 7:57 - 7:59
    and therefore pushing broadband growth.
  • 7:59 - 8:05
    The US has been a dismal failure in this respect.
  • 8:05 - 8:09
    As we watch the US going from number 1 in broadband penetration,
  • 8:09 - 8:12
    now to, depending on the scale,
  • 8:12 - 8:15
    number 18, 19, or 28.
  • 8:15 - 8:19
    And that change is because of policies that
  • 8:19 - 8:21
    effectively block competition
  • 8:21 - 8:25
    for broadband providers.
  • 8:25 - 8:28
    Their answer, these broadband providers brought to
  • 8:28 - 8:30
    our government, and got our government to impose
  • 8:30 - 8:36
    actually benefited them and destroyed the incentives
  • 8:36 - 8:38
    for them to compete in a way that would drive
  • 8:38 - 8:41
    broadband penetration.
  • 8:41 - 8:44
    I think in light of these examples,
  • 8:44 - 8:47
    it is completely fair to be skeptical
  • 8:47 - 8:50
    of the anwer modern democratic governments give.
  • 8:50 - 8:53
    We should say to modern democratic government,
  • 8:53 - 8:59
    you need to beware of incumbents bearing policy fixes.
  • 8:59 - 9:02
    Because their job, the job of the incumbents,
  • 9:02 - 9:06
    is not the same as your job, the job of the public policy maker.
  • 9:06 - 9:10
    Their job is profit for them.
  • 9:10 - 9:12
    Your job is the public good.
  • 9:12 - 9:15
    And it is completely fair, for us to say,
  • 9:15 - 9:19
    that until this addiction is solved, we should
  • 9:19 - 9:23
    insist on minimalism in what government does.
  • 9:23 - 9:26
    The kind of minimalism Jeff Jarvis spoke off when he
  • 9:26 - 9:28
    spoke of "do no harm".
  • 9:28 - 9:32
    An internet that embraces principles of open and free
  • 9:32 - 9:35
    access, a neutral network to guarantee
  • 9:35 - 9:41
    this open access, to protect the outsider.
  • 9:41 - 9:44
    But here is the one think we know about this meeting,
  • 9:44 - 9:48
    and its relationship to the future of the internet.
  • 9:48 - 9:50
    The future of the internet is not Twitter,
  • 9:50 - 9:53
    it is not Facebook, it is not Google,
  • 9:53 - 9:57
    it is not even Rupert Murdoch.
  • 9:57 - 10:01
    The future of the internet is not here.
  • 10:01 - 10:05
    It wasn't invited, it does not even know how to be invited,
  • 10:05 - 10:09
    because it doesn't yet focus on policies and fora like this.
  • 10:09 - 10:14
    The least we can do is to preserve the architecture
  • 10:14 - 10:17
    of this network that protects this future
  • 10:17 - 10:19
    that is not here.
  • 10:19 - 10:21
    Thank you very much.
Title:
Lawrence Lessig Keynote - e-G8
Description:

Paris, 25 May 2011: Keynote given at e-G8 conference, introducing Innovation panel. ;

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Claude Almansi edited English, British subtitles for Lawrence Lessig Keynote - e-G8
Claude Almansi added a translation

English, British subtitles

Incomplete

Revisions