1 00:00:02,425 --> 00:00:04,628 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:09,596 --> 00:00:13,855 - [Alex] In previous videos, we've emphasized that a price is a signal 3 00:00:14,000 --> 00:00:19,180 wrapped up in an incentive and that prices coming out of free markets coordinate 4 00:00:19,300 --> 00:00:25,748 individual actions in just such a way that the outcome looks as if it were created by 5 00:00:25,748 --> 00:00:31,640 a benevolent invisible hand. We've shown how price controls can impede the price 6 00:00:31,820 --> 00:00:36,950 and what we want to show now is that even with the free market sometimes the price 7 00:00:37,130 --> 00:00:42,660 isn't right. In particular, when we have externalities, external cost, and external 8 00:00:42,840 --> 00:00:48,490 benefits, which I'll define more in just a few minutes, then the price isn't right. 9 00:00:48,670 --> 00:00:53,160 So what we want to do in this video is show both the causes and the consequences 10 00:00:53,340 --> 00:00:57,838 of external costs and external benefits. Let's get going. 11 00:01:01,240 --> 00:01:05,650 Let's begin with the rise of the super bugs. These are bacteria which are now 12 00:01:05,830 --> 00:01:12,500 resistant to our antibiotics. Before the age of the antibiotic, even a simple skin 13 00:01:12,680 --> 00:01:17,870 cut or a bruise or scrape could kill people due to the infection. And people 14 00:01:18,050 --> 00:01:23,020 who are more seriously injured, for example, in battle most of them died not 15 00:01:23,200 --> 00:01:27,440 because of their battle wounds, but because of infection which took place 16 00:01:27,620 --> 00:01:30,130 after the wound, because of the wound. 17 00:01:30,310 --> 00:01:35,750 In the 20th century, the miracle of antibiotics meant that far, far fewer 18 00:01:35,930 --> 00:01:41,810 people died from these infections. But that miracle is now coming to an end, as 19 00:01:41,990 --> 00:01:48,940 our antibiotics are no longer as effective as they once were. Why is this happening? 20 00:01:49,120 --> 00:01:54,680 Part of the problem is that no antibiotic is always 100% effective. And 21 00:01:54,860 --> 00:01:59,100 bacteria, like people, are diverse. They have different strengths and different 22 00:01:59,280 --> 00:02:00,503 weaknesses. 23 00:02:00,530 --> 00:02:05,420 The bacteria which are not killed by an antibiotic which happen to have certain 24 00:02:05,600 --> 00:02:10,669 characteristics which make them strong against that antibiotic. Those bacteria 25 00:02:10,850 --> 00:02:17,070 propagate and survive and become more dominant. So, the evolutionary process has 26 00:02:17,250 --> 00:02:19,910 led to resistance. 27 00:02:20,090 --> 00:02:25,600 We however, are not entirely innocent in this process. Resistance has been helped 28 00:02:25,780 --> 00:02:33,100 by the overuse of antibiotics. So why are antibiotics overused? The fundamental 29 00:02:33,280 --> 00:02:37,410 reason is that users get all the benefits but do not bear all of the 30 00:02:37,590 --> 00:02:43,550 costs of antibiotic use. Each use of an antibiotic creates a small increase in 31 00:02:43,730 --> 00:02:48,400 bacterial resistance, at least in a probabilistic sense. But bacteria don't 32 00:02:48,580 --> 00:02:53,210 stay in one place or one body, they spread throughout the environment and indeed 33 00:02:53,390 --> 00:02:58,030 throughout that world. So an increase that cost, that increase in bacterial 34 00:02:58,210 --> 00:03:04,850 resistance is a cost borne by everyone, not just the user of the antibiotic. 35 00:03:05,030 --> 00:03:09,640 We can think of using an antibiotic as creating a little bit of pollution, of 36 00:03:09,820 --> 00:03:14,900 polluting the environment with more resistant and stronger bacteria. This is 37 00:03:15,080 --> 00:03:19,560 true when somebody, for example, uses an antibiotic when they have a virus which 38 00:03:19,740 --> 00:03:24,090 the antibiotic doesn't help with rather than when they have bacteria. That's a 39 00:03:24,270 --> 00:03:30,520 cost. It's a cost because that use of the antibiotic then generates more resistance 40 00:03:30,700 --> 00:03:36,060 and that resistance spreads around the world. Farmers who use antibiotics not to 41 00:03:36,240 --> 00:03:42,180 combat disease in their livestock but to help the livestock grow faster, also 42 00:03:42,360 --> 00:03:48,810 create more bacterial resistance. But that resistance is something they don't include 43 00:03:48,990 --> 00:03:53,640 in their calculus of cost. They don't pay attention to those costs which are borne 44 00:03:53,820 --> 00:03:55,770 by other people. 45 00:03:55,950 --> 00:04:00,550 When antibiotic users ignore the external cost 46 00:04:00,840 --> 00:04:06,450 of their choices we get overuse. Since some costs are ignored by the decision 47 00:04:06,630 --> 00:04:12,490 makers we get overuse of antibiotics. Okay, well, with that as an introduction, 48 00:04:12,670 --> 00:04:15,220 let's define some terms. Private cost: 49 00:04:15,400 --> 00:04:20,600 this is the cost paid by the consumer or the producer. External cost: 50 00:04:20,779 --> 00:04:26,150 this is a cost paid by bystanders, by people other than the consumer or the 51 00:04:26,330 --> 00:04:32,010 producer. It's a cost paid by people other than those who are buying or selling in 52 00:04:32,190 --> 00:04:35,260 this particular market. The social cost 53 00:04:35,440 --> 00:04:40,830 is the cost to everyone. The cost when we take into account consumers, producers 54 00:04:41,010 --> 00:04:48,140 and bystanders. In other words, it's the private cost plus the external cost. 55 00:04:48,320 --> 00:04:49,260 Externalities: 56 00:04:49,440 --> 00:04:54,360 this is simply another word for external cost or external benefits. We'll talk 57 00:04:54,540 --> 00:04:59,090 more about external benefits in a future talk. In other words, externalities is 58 00:04:59,270 --> 00:05:04,980 just another word for cost or benefits that fall on bystanders. 59 00:05:05,160 --> 00:05:10,230 When there are significant external costs or external benefits a market will not 60 00:05:10,410 --> 00:05:15,260 maximize social surplus. Now, remember we showed earlier that a market maximizes 61 00:05:15,440 --> 00:05:21,140 consumer surplus plus producer surplus. That's always true for a free market. 62 00:05:21,320 --> 00:05:26,540 However, what we've just learned is that an external cost is a cost that falls on 63 00:05:26,720 --> 00:05:33,240 bystanders, not on consumers or producers. So, social surplus which is consumer 64 00:05:33,420 --> 00:05:38,340 surplus plus producer surplus plus bystander surplus. That's ultimately 65 00:05:38,520 --> 00:05:42,330 really what we care about. We care about not just about consumers and producers, we 66 00:05:42,510 --> 00:05:49,390 care about everyone including bystanders. So we want to maximize social surplus. 67 00:05:49,570 --> 00:05:53,590 However, when there are significant external costs or benefits, the market is 68 00:05:53,770 --> 00:05:58,460 not going to maximize social surplus. It's going to maximize consumer surplus plus 69 00:05:58,640 --> 00:06:01,750 producer surplus. But that's not everything. When the 70 00:06:02,000 --> 00:06:08,290 costs and the benefits to bystanders are not counted, then we're not going to 71 00:06:08,470 --> 00:06:13,480 maximize social surplus. In fact, we can say things a little bit more precisely, 72 00:06:13,660 --> 00:06:18,330 and we'll do that next with a supply and demand diagram. Okay, here's our standard 73 00:06:18,510 --> 00:06:22,290 diagram with the quantity of antibiotics on the horizontal axis and prices and 74 00:06:22,470 --> 00:06:27,040 costs on the vertical axis. As usual, the equilibrium is found where demand 75 00:06:27,220 --> 00:06:32,200 intersects supply, where quantity demanded is equal to quantity supplied. Now the key 76 00:06:32,380 --> 00:06:37,500 point here is that the supply curve is based on private cost, basically the 77 00:06:37,680 --> 00:06:42,260 cost of producing the antibiotic. But there's another cost. 78 00:06:42,440 --> 00:06:48,720 Every time an antibiotic is produced and consumed there's a cost of bacterial 79 00:06:48,900 --> 00:06:55,150 resistance. A cost borne by all of us, by bystanders. There's an external cost and 80 00:06:55,330 --> 00:07:01,600 that is not taken into account by the suppliers. So this external cost doesn't 81 00:07:01,780 --> 00:07:07,760 go into the price. Nevertheless, what we really care about is the social cost of 82 00:07:07,940 --> 00:07:12,960 antibiotic use, not just the cost of producing the antibiotic but also the cost 83 00:07:13,140 --> 00:07:18,860 of actually using it, including the external cost. So, the market equilibrium, 84 00:07:19,040 --> 00:07:23,910 the market quantity, is found where the market demand and supply curves intersect. 85 00:07:24,090 --> 00:07:29,630 But the true efficient equilibrium, the equilibrium we would like to be at, is 86 00:07:29,810 --> 00:07:34,830 where the demand curve intersects the social cost curve. So, the efficient 87 00:07:35,010 --> 00:07:41,900 quantity is less than the market quantity, thus we have overuse. 88 00:07:42,080 --> 00:07:48,770 The market doesn't take into account all of the costs of antibiotic use so we get 89 00:07:48,950 --> 00:07:54,590 overuse relative to the efficient equilibrium. Now we can actually show this 90 00:07:54,770 --> 00:08:00,250 in another way. Let's look at the value of the marginal unit, 91 00:08:00,500 --> 00:08:05,180 the value of the unit, the market unit, the last unit the market produces. What's 92 00:08:05,360 --> 00:08:09,740 the private value, what's the value of this unit? Well, it's given by the height 93 00:08:09,920 --> 00:08:15,810 of the demand curve. Now, what is the cost of that marginal unit, of that last unit 94 00:08:15,990 --> 00:08:21,280 consumed? Well, the private cost is given by the private supply curve, but the 95 00:08:21,460 --> 00:08:29,000 social cost is given by the much higher social cost curve. So notice on that last 96 00:08:29,180 --> 00:08:36,000 unit, the cost of that last unit is much larger than the value. That's the sense in 97 00:08:36,179 --> 00:08:37,860 which we have overuse. 98 00:08:38,039 --> 00:08:43,559 We don't really want to produce this last unit because the cost is greater than the 99 00:08:43,740 --> 00:08:49,270 value. Indeed, if we don't want to produce this unit, we don't to produce any unit 100 00:08:49,450 --> 00:08:55,360 where the social cost is greater than the value. So in other words, this area right 101 00:08:55,540 --> 00:09:02,200 here is a deadweight loss. These are the units for which the social cost is greater 102 00:09:02,380 --> 00:09:06,440 than the private value, therefore, these are the units we don't want to produce. 103 00:09:06,620 --> 00:09:14,380 This is the deadweight loss and this is the overuse of the antibiotic. 104 00:09:14,560 --> 00:09:18,610 What conclusions can we make? When there are external costs, output should be 105 00:09:18,790 --> 00:09:24,120 reduced to maximize social surplus. Another way of thinking about this is, for 106 00:09:24,300 --> 00:09:29,190 determining the efficient level of output. Who bears the cost is irrelevant. The fact 107 00:09:29,370 --> 00:09:33,790 that these costs are borne by bystanders is irrelevant, we want to take into 108 00:09:33,970 --> 00:09:39,950 account all costs not just the cost of the suppliers. The problem is, is that when 109 00:09:40,130 --> 00:09:45,260 other people bear some of the cost of production, the price is too low. 110 00:09:45,440 --> 00:09:52,030 Not all of the costs are reflected in the price. As a result, the price is sending 111 00:09:52,210 --> 00:09:57,480 the wrong signal. It's incentivizing too much production. Because the price is too 112 00:09:57,660 --> 00:10:04,060 low, antibiotic users purchase too many antibiotics and we get overuse. 113 00:10:04,240 --> 00:10:09,370 The solution to this or one solution to this is in what's called a Pigouvian tax. 114 00:10:09,550 --> 00:10:16,030 A tax on a good with external costs. Let's take a look at how that works. The idea of 115 00:10:16,210 --> 00:10:19,630 a Pigouvian tax after the economist Arthur Pigou, first talked about these 116 00:10:19,810 --> 00:10:25,110 ideas is pretty simple. The market equilibrium is down here. The efficient 117 00:10:25,290 --> 00:10:31,900 equilibrium is here. The problem is that the suppliers aren't taking into account 118 00:10:32,080 --> 00:10:36,190 all the costs of their production. They're not taking into account these external 119 00:10:36,370 --> 00:10:42,030 costs. So how could we get these suppliers to take into account all of the costs of 120 00:10:42,210 --> 00:10:49,390 their production? Well, one way of doing it is to tax them, a Pigouvian tax equal 121 00:10:49,570 --> 00:10:55,530 to the external cost makes the private cost plus the tax, the total private cost, 122 00:10:55,710 --> 00:10:58,050 equal to the social cost. 123 00:10:58,230 --> 00:11:02,520 Let's remember how we can analyze a tax. Remember that one of the ways to analyze a 124 00:11:02,700 --> 00:11:09,460 tax is to shift the supply curve up by the amount of the tax. So, if we impose a tax 125 00:11:09,640 --> 00:11:16,150 on the suppliers equal to the external cost the supply curve will shift up until 126 00:11:16,330 --> 00:11:23,800 the private cost plus the tax is equal to the social cost. In this case, we will now 127 00:11:23,980 --> 00:11:29,290 have the efficient equilibrium will be the same as the market equilibrium. The market 128 00:11:29,470 --> 00:11:35,900 will internalize the externality. All of the costs, private cost plus the tax equal 129 00:11:36,080 --> 00:11:40,940 to the external cost will come to be reflected in the price, and because all of 130 00:11:41,120 --> 00:11:45,980 the costs are reflected in the price consumers will buy the efficient quantity 131 00:11:46,160 --> 00:11:47,570 of the good. 132 00:11:47,750 --> 00:11:53,720 So, that's one way to handle an external cost problem. In the next couple of 133 00:11:53,900 --> 00:11:57,540 lectures, we'll be talking about external benefits and we'll also illustrate some 134 00:11:57,720 --> 00:12:00,700 other ways in which externalities can be handled 135 00:12:00,880 --> 00:12:06,890 - [male] If you want to test yourself click Practice Questions. Or, if you're 136 00:12:07,070 --> 00:12:09,614 ready to move on just click Next Video. 137 00:12:09,614 --> 00:12:11,756 ♪ [music] ♪