0:00:02.425,0:00:04.628 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.596,0:00:13.855 - [Alex] In previous videos, we've[br]emphasized that a price is a signal 0:00:14.000,0:00:19.180 wrapped up in an incentive and that prices[br]coming out of free markets coordinate 0:00:19.300,0:00:25.748 individual actions in just such a way that[br]the outcome looks as if it were created by 0:00:25.748,0:00:31.640 a benevolent invisible hand. We've shown[br]how price controls can impede the price 0:00:31.820,0:00:36.950 and what we want to show now is that even[br]with the free market sometimes the price 0:00:37.130,0:00:42.660 isn't right. In particular, when we have[br]externalities, external cost, and external 0:00:42.840,0:00:48.490 benefits, which I'll define more in just a[br]few minutes, then the price isn't right. 0:00:48.670,0:00:53.160 So what we want to do in this video is[br]show both the causes and the consequences 0:00:53.340,0:00:57.838 of external costs and external benefits.[br]Let's get going. 0:01:01.240,0:01:05.650 Let's begin with the rise of the super[br]bugs. These are bacteria which are now 0:01:05.830,0:01:12.500 resistant to our antibiotics. Before the[br]age of the antibiotic, even a simple skin 0:01:12.680,0:01:17.870 cut or a bruise or scrape could kill[br]people due to the infection. And people 0:01:18.050,0:01:23.020 who are more seriously injured, for[br]example, in battle most of them died not 0:01:23.200,0:01:27.440 because of their battle wounds, but[br]because of infection which took place 0:01:27.620,0:01:30.130 after the wound, because of the wound. 0:01:30.310,0:01:35.750 In the 20th century, the miracle of[br]antibiotics meant that far, far fewer 0:01:35.930,0:01:41.810 people died from these infections. But[br]that miracle is now coming to an end, as 0:01:41.990,0:01:48.940 our antibiotics are no longer as effective[br]as they once were. Why is this happening? 0:01:49.120,0:01:54.680 Part of the problem is that no antibiotic[br]is always 100% effective. And 0:01:54.860,0:01:59.100 bacteria, like people, are diverse. They[br]have different strengths and different 0:01:59.280,0:02:00.503 weaknesses. 0:02:00.530,0:02:05.420 The bacteria which are not killed by an[br]antibiotic which happen to have certain 0:02:05.600,0:02:10.669 characteristics which make them strong[br]against that antibiotic. Those bacteria 0:02:10.850,0:02:17.070 propagate and survive and become more[br]dominant. So, the evolutionary process has 0:02:17.250,0:02:19.910 led to resistance. 0:02:20.090,0:02:25.600 We however, are not entirely innocent in[br]this process. Resistance has been helped 0:02:25.780,0:02:33.100 by the overuse of antibiotics. So why are[br]antibiotics overused? The fundamental 0:02:33.280,0:02:37.410 reason is that users get all the benefits[br]but do not bear all of the 0:02:37.590,0:02:43.550 costs of antibiotic use. Each use of an[br]antibiotic creates a small increase in 0:02:43.730,0:02:48.400 bacterial resistance, at least in a[br]probabilistic sense. But bacteria don't 0:02:48.580,0:02:53.210 stay in one place or one body, they spread[br]throughout the environment and indeed 0:02:53.390,0:02:58.030 throughout that world. So an increase that[br]cost, that increase in bacterial 0:02:58.210,0:03:04.850 resistance is a cost borne by everyone,[br]not just the user of the antibiotic. 0:03:05.030,0:03:09.640 We can think of using an antibiotic as[br]creating a little bit of pollution, of 0:03:09.820,0:03:14.900 polluting the environment with more[br]resistant and stronger bacteria. This is 0:03:15.080,0:03:19.560 true when somebody, for example, uses an[br]antibiotic when they have a virus which 0:03:19.740,0:03:24.090 the antibiotic doesn't help with rather[br]than when they have bacteria. That's a 0:03:24.270,0:03:30.520 cost. It's a cost because that use of the[br]antibiotic then generates more resistance 0:03:30.700,0:03:36.060 and that resistance spreads around the[br]world. Farmers who use antibiotics not to 0:03:36.240,0:03:42.180 combat disease in their livestock but to[br]help the livestock grow faster, also 0:03:42.360,0:03:48.810 create more bacterial resistance. But that[br]resistance is something they don't include 0:03:48.990,0:03:53.640 in their calculus of cost. They don't pay[br]attention to those costs which are borne 0:03:53.820,0:03:55.770 by other people. 0:03:55.950,0:04:00.550 When antibiotic users ignore the external[br]cost 0:04:00.840,0:04:06.450 of their choices we get overuse. Since[br]some costs are ignored by the decision 0:04:06.630,0:04:12.490 makers we get overuse of antibiotics.[br]Okay, well, with that as an introduction, 0:04:12.670,0:04:15.220 let's define some terms. Private cost: 0:04:15.400,0:04:20.600 this is the cost paid by the consumer or[br]the producer. External cost: 0:04:20.779,0:04:26.150 this is a cost paid by bystanders, by[br]people other than the consumer or the 0:04:26.330,0:04:32.010 producer. It's a cost paid by people other[br]than those who are buying or selling in 0:04:32.190,0:04:35.260 this particular market. The social cost 0:04:35.440,0:04:40.830 is the cost to everyone. The cost when[br]we take into account consumers, producers 0:04:41.010,0:04:48.140 and bystanders. In other words, it's the[br]private cost plus the external cost. 0:04:48.320,0:04:49.260 Externalities: 0:04:49.440,0:04:54.360 this is simply another word for external[br]cost or external benefits. We'll talk 0:04:54.540,0:04:59.090 more about external benefits in a future[br]talk. In other words, externalities is 0:04:59.270,0:05:04.980 just another word for cost or benefits[br]that fall on bystanders. 0:05:05.160,0:05:10.230 When there are significant external costs[br]or external benefits a market will not 0:05:10.410,0:05:15.260 maximize social surplus. Now, remember we[br]showed earlier that a market maximizes 0:05:15.440,0:05:21.140 consumer surplus plus producer surplus.[br]That's always true for a free market. 0:05:21.320,0:05:26.540 However, what we've just learned is that[br]an external cost is a cost that falls on 0:05:26.720,0:05:33.240 bystanders, not on consumers or producers.[br]So, social surplus which is consumer 0:05:33.420,0:05:38.340 surplus plus producer surplus plus[br]bystander surplus. That's ultimately 0:05:38.520,0:05:42.330 really what we care about. We care about[br]not just about consumers and producers, we 0:05:42.510,0:05:49.390 care about everyone including bystanders.[br]So we want to maximize social surplus. 0:05:49.570,0:05:53.590 However, when there are significant[br]external costs or benefits, the market is 0:05:53.770,0:05:58.460 not going to maximize social surplus. It's[br]going to maximize consumer surplus plus 0:05:58.640,0:06:01.750 producer surplus. But that's not[br]everything. When the 0:06:02.000,0:06:08.290 costs and the benefits to bystanders[br]are not counted, then we're not going to 0:06:08.470,0:06:13.480 maximize social surplus. In fact, we can[br]say things a little bit more precisely, 0:06:13.660,0:06:18.330 and we'll do that next with a supply and[br]demand diagram. Okay, here's our standard 0:06:18.510,0:06:22.290 diagram with the quantity of antibiotics[br]on the horizontal axis and prices and 0:06:22.470,0:06:27.040 costs on the vertical axis. As usual, the[br]equilibrium is found where demand 0:06:27.220,0:06:32.200 intersects supply, where quantity demanded[br]is equal to quantity supplied. Now the key 0:06:32.380,0:06:37.500 point here is that the supply curve is[br]based on private cost, basically the 0:06:37.680,0:06:42.260 cost of producing the antibiotic. But[br]there's another cost. 0:06:42.440,0:06:48.720 Every time an antibiotic is produced and[br]consumed there's a cost of bacterial 0:06:48.900,0:06:55.150 resistance. A cost borne by all of us, by[br]bystanders. There's an external cost and 0:06:55.330,0:07:01.600 that is not taken into account by the[br]suppliers. So this external cost doesn't 0:07:01.780,0:07:07.760 go into the price. Nevertheless, what we[br]really care about is the social cost of 0:07:07.940,0:07:12.960 antibiotic use, not just the cost of[br]producing the antibiotic but also the cost 0:07:13.140,0:07:18.860 of actually using it, including the[br]external cost. So, the market equilibrium, 0:07:19.040,0:07:23.910 the market quantity, is found where the[br]market demand and supply curves intersect. 0:07:24.090,0:07:29.630 But the true efficient equilibrium, the[br]equilibrium we would like to be at, is 0:07:29.810,0:07:34.830 where the demand curve intersects the[br]social cost curve. So, the efficient 0:07:35.010,0:07:41.900 quantity is less than the market quantity,[br]thus we have overuse. 0:07:42.080,0:07:48.770 The market doesn't take into account all[br]of the costs of antibiotic use so we get 0:07:48.950,0:07:54.590 overuse relative to the efficient[br]equilibrium. Now we can actually show this 0:07:54.770,0:08:00.250 in another way. Let's look at the value of[br]the marginal unit, 0:08:00.500,0:08:05.180 the value of the unit, the market unit,[br]the last unit the market produces. What's 0:08:05.360,0:08:09.740 the private value, what's the value of[br]this unit? Well, it's given by the height 0:08:09.920,0:08:15.810 of the demand curve. Now, what is the cost[br]of that marginal unit, of that last unit 0:08:15.990,0:08:21.280 consumed? Well, the private cost is given[br]by the private supply curve, but the 0:08:21.460,0:08:29.000 social cost is given by the much higher[br]social cost curve. So notice on that last 0:08:29.180,0:08:36.000 unit, the cost of that last unit is much[br]larger than the value. That's the sense in 0:08:36.179,0:08:37.860 which we have overuse. 0:08:38.039,0:08:43.559 We don't really want to produce this last[br]unit because the cost is greater than the 0:08:43.740,0:08:49.270 value. Indeed, if we don't want to produce[br]this unit, we don't to produce any unit 0:08:49.450,0:08:55.360 where the social cost is greater than the[br]value. So in other words, this area right 0:08:55.540,0:09:02.200 here is a deadweight loss. These are the[br]units for which the social cost is greater 0:09:02.380,0:09:06.440 than the private value, therefore, these[br]are the units we don't want to produce. 0:09:06.620,0:09:14.380 This is the deadweight loss and this is[br]the overuse of the antibiotic. 0:09:14.560,0:09:18.610 What conclusions can we make? When there[br]are external costs, output should be 0:09:18.790,0:09:24.120 reduced to maximize social surplus.[br]Another way of thinking about this is, for 0:09:24.300,0:09:29.190 determining the efficient level of output.[br]Who bears the cost is irrelevant. The fact 0:09:29.370,0:09:33.790 that these costs are borne by bystanders[br]is irrelevant, we want to take into 0:09:33.970,0:09:39.950 account all costs not just the cost of the[br]suppliers. The problem is, is that when 0:09:40.130,0:09:45.260 other people bear some of the cost of[br]production, the price is too low. 0:09:45.440,0:09:52.030 Not all of the costs are reflected in the[br]price. As a result, the price is sending 0:09:52.210,0:09:57.480 the wrong signal. It's incentivizing too[br]much production. Because the price is too 0:09:57.660,0:10:04.060 low, antibiotic users purchase too many[br]antibiotics and we get overuse. 0:10:04.240,0:10:09.370 The solution to this or one solution to[br]this is in what's called a Pigouvian tax. 0:10:09.550,0:10:16.030 A tax on a good with external costs. Let's[br]take a look at how that works. The idea of 0:10:16.210,0:10:19.630 a Pigouvian tax after the economist[br]Arthur Pigou, first talked about these 0:10:19.810,0:10:25.110 ideas is pretty simple. The market[br]equilibrium is down here. The efficient 0:10:25.290,0:10:31.900 equilibrium is here. The problem is that[br]the suppliers aren't taking into account 0:10:32.080,0:10:36.190 all the costs of their production. They're[br]not taking into account these external 0:10:36.370,0:10:42.030 costs. So how could we get these suppliers[br]to take into account all of the costs of 0:10:42.210,0:10:49.390 their production? Well, one way of doing[br]it is to tax them, a Pigouvian tax equal 0:10:49.570,0:10:55.530 to the external cost makes the private[br]cost plus the tax, the total private cost, 0:10:55.710,0:10:58.050 equal to the social cost. 0:10:58.230,0:11:02.520 Let's remember how we can analyze a tax.[br]Remember that one of the ways to analyze a 0:11:02.700,0:11:09.460 tax is to shift the supply curve up by the[br]amount of the tax. So, if we impose a tax 0:11:09.640,0:11:16.150 on the suppliers equal to the external[br]cost the supply curve will shift up until 0:11:16.330,0:11:23.800 the private cost plus the tax is equal to[br]the social cost. In this case, we will now 0:11:23.980,0:11:29.290 have the efficient equilibrium will be the[br]same as the market equilibrium. The market 0:11:29.470,0:11:35.900 will internalize the externality. All of[br]the costs, private cost plus the tax equal 0:11:36.080,0:11:40.940 to the external cause will come to be[br]reflected in the price, and because all of 0:11:41.120,0:11:45.980 the costs are reflected in the price[br]consumers will buy the efficient quantity 0:11:46.160,0:11:47.570 of the good. 0:11:47.750,0:11:53.720 So, that's one way to handle an external[br]cost problem. In the next couple of 0:11:53.900,0:11:57.540 lectures, we'll be talking about external[br]benefits and we'll also illustrate some 0:11:57.720,0:12:00.700 other ways in which externalities can be[br]handled 0:12:00.880,0:12:06.890 - [male] If you want to test yourself[br]click Practice Questions. Or, if you're 0:12:07.070,0:12:09.614 ready to move on just click Next Video. 0:12:09.614,0:12:11.756 ♪ [music] ♪