WEBVTT 00:00:12.500 --> 00:00:16.300 In previous videos, we've covered the basics of the demand curve. 00:00:16.300 --> 00:00:19.700 Now let's discuss what happens when the demand curve shifts 00:00:20.000 --> 00:00:23.026 due to increases or decreases in market demand. 00:00:23.026 --> 00:00:26.100 First, let's look at an increase in demand. 00:00:26.700 --> 00:00:28.057 An increase in demand 00:00:28.057 --> 00:00:31.600 means that the demand curve shifts up and to the right. 00:00:32.400 --> 00:00:35.250 Take the market for house plants, for instance. 00:00:35.250 --> 00:00:38.100 On the old demand curve at $20, 00:00:38.400 --> 00:00:41.572 the quantity demanded was five plants, 00:00:41.572 --> 00:00:44.991 but on the new demand curve at, again, $20, 00:00:44.991 --> 00:00:47.413 the quantity demanded is eight plants. 00:00:48.500 --> 00:00:52.200 At $16, we go from six plants to nine plants. 00:00:53.500 --> 00:00:57.500 At $12, we go from seven to ten plants, and so on. 00:00:57.900 --> 00:01:02.400 An increase in demand is a greater quantity demanded at every price. 00:01:03.000 --> 00:01:05.303 We can also read an increase in demand 00:01:05.303 --> 00:01:07.800 using what is called the vertical method. 00:01:08.000 --> 00:01:10.100 What that means is that for every quantity, 00:01:10.300 --> 00:01:13.200 there's a greater willingness to pay for that quantity. 00:01:13.500 --> 00:01:15.628 For instance, for the fifth unit, 00:01:15.628 --> 00:01:19.100 people had been willing to pay $20 for that unit. 00:01:19.300 --> 00:01:20.992 Now with the new demand curve, 00:01:20.992 --> 00:01:24.393 people are willing to pay $32 for that unit. 00:01:25.100 --> 00:01:27.500 In summary, an increase in demand 00:01:27.500 --> 00:01:30.136 means an increase in the quantity demanded 00:01:30.136 --> 00:01:32.148 at every market price, 00:01:32.148 --> 00:01:34.757 or equivalently, it means an increase 00:01:34.757 --> 00:01:38.273 in the maximum willingness to pay for a given quantity. 00:01:39.400 --> 00:01:40.700 A decrease in demand-- 00:01:40.800 --> 00:01:43.728 well, that's just the opposite of an increase in demand. 00:01:43.728 --> 00:01:46.000 It's a shift down and to the left. 00:01:46.600 --> 00:01:50.762 There's a decrease in quantity demanded at every price. 00:01:50.762 --> 00:01:55.200 Now at $20, people only want to buy two houseplants. 00:01:56.100 --> 00:02:00.300 At $16, we go from six to three house plants and so on. 00:02:01.100 --> 00:02:03.624 Similarly, this means a decrease 00:02:03.624 --> 00:02:06.400 in the willingness to pay for the same quantity. 00:02:06.800 --> 00:02:08.175 For the fifth unit, 00:02:08.175 --> 00:02:11.373 people were willing to pay $20 for that unit 00:02:11.373 --> 00:02:13.964 but now they're only going to fork over $8 00:02:13.964 --> 00:02:15.181 for that house plan. 00:02:16.500 --> 00:02:19.400 So what can cause a shift in demand? 00:02:20.000 --> 00:02:24.100 What would make consumers buy more or less of a good at every price? 00:02:24.800 --> 00:02:28.400 Take a moment to jot down some guesses. 00:02:29.994 --> 00:02:32.144 We'll go through these with a few examples. 00:02:32.144 --> 00:02:34.900 But the real goal is not to memorize this list 00:02:35.200 --> 00:02:36.606 but rather to understand 00:02:36.606 --> 00:02:39.600 what an increase or decrease in demand means 00:02:39.900 --> 00:02:42.500 so that you can recreate this list on your own. 00:02:43.000 --> 00:02:45.115 Let's now go through five factors 00:02:45.115 --> 00:02:48.057 that can increase or decrease market demand, 00:02:48.057 --> 00:02:51.817 namely income, population, tastes, 00:02:51.817 --> 00:02:53.803 the price of related goods, 00:02:53.803 --> 00:02:55.600 and finally, expectations. 00:02:56.600 --> 00:02:58.900 Let's start with changes in income. 00:02:59.500 --> 00:03:02.300 The effect of a change in income on demand, 00:03:02.400 --> 00:03:05.595 depends on the nature of the good in question. 00:03:05.595 --> 00:03:07.800 For most goods, as your income goes up, 00:03:07.900 --> 00:03:09.992 you demand more of the good. 00:03:09.992 --> 00:03:12.049 Think, for instance, fine dining. 00:03:12.049 --> 00:03:14.101 You need to be able to afford it, right? 00:03:14.800 --> 00:03:18.183 The demand curve then shifts up and to the right. 00:03:18.183 --> 00:03:20.400 These goods are called normal goods 00:03:20.800 --> 00:03:23.900 because the demand for them goes up when incomes go up, 00:03:23.900 --> 00:03:26.150 and indeed most goods are normal goods-- 00:03:26.150 --> 00:03:27.849 that's why we call them normal. 00:03:28.300 --> 00:03:30.029 And these same goods-- 00:03:30.029 --> 00:03:33.795 the demand for them goes down when incomes go down. 00:03:34.900 --> 00:03:36.400 There are also goods, however, 00:03:36.700 --> 00:03:38.950 for which, when your income goes up, 00:03:38.950 --> 00:03:41.200 your demand for them actually goes down. 00:03:41.700 --> 00:03:44.800 These are exceptions. We call them inferior goods. 00:03:45.200 --> 00:03:47.791 So, an example of such an inferior good 00:03:47.791 --> 00:03:49.779 might be instant ramen-- 00:03:49.779 --> 00:03:51.100 it's very cheap. 00:03:52.000 --> 00:03:54.600 As you make more money, you might buy, say, 00:03:54.600 --> 00:03:58.826 more caviar, more steak, and less instant ramen. 00:03:58.826 --> 00:03:59.840 No, thanks! 00:03:59.840 --> 00:04:02.367 Thus, the demand curve for instant ramen 00:04:02.367 --> 00:04:06.080 will shift down into the left as your income increases. 00:04:06.800 --> 00:04:10.759 Now let's move on to changes in population. 00:04:10.759 --> 00:04:13.400 If the population of an economy changes, 00:04:13.700 --> 00:04:18.479 the number of potential buyers of a good changes also. 00:04:18.479 --> 00:04:21.188 What would happen to the demand for hearing aids 00:04:21.188 --> 00:04:24.400 if the elderly population in your country increased? 00:04:24.600 --> 00:04:27.900 Well, very likely demand for hearing aids would increase. 00:04:28.300 --> 00:04:30.552 At any price for those hearing aids, 00:04:30.552 --> 00:04:33.100 there would be a higher quantity demanded. 00:04:38.900 --> 00:04:41.700 Can you think of a good that would decrease in demand 00:04:41.700 --> 00:04:44.000 if the birth rates in your country decreased? 00:04:45.200 --> 00:04:48.000 Now, we'll move on to changes in tastes. 00:04:48.300 --> 00:04:51.100 Tastes are subjective, and they're changing all the time. 00:04:51.400 --> 00:04:56.234 New information, fashions, and fads all can impact tastes. 00:04:56.234 --> 00:04:57.300 To give an example, 00:04:57.700 --> 00:05:00.000 what happens to the demand for hamburgers 00:05:00.000 --> 00:05:01.945 if low-carb diets, 00:05:01.945 --> 00:05:04.411 like the keto diet or the caveman diet 00:05:04.411 --> 00:05:05.600 become more popular? 00:05:06.200 --> 00:05:10.200 Well, people would want to go out and buy and eat more hamburgers, 00:05:10.200 --> 00:05:13.400 and so the demand for hamburgers would increase. 00:05:14.342 --> 00:05:17.471 Alternatively, what if a controversy surfaced 00:05:17.471 --> 00:05:20.600 that questioned the ethics of hamburger production? 00:05:21.100 --> 00:05:23.900 People might then feel bad about buying hamburgers, 00:05:24.100 --> 00:05:26.250 and then they would buy fewer hamburgers 00:05:26.250 --> 00:05:28.400 or maybe stop buying them altogether. 00:05:28.900 --> 00:05:31.900 The demand for hamburgers then would go down. 00:05:33.220 --> 00:05:37.089 Next, let's consider how the price of a related good 00:05:37.089 --> 00:05:41.022 can affect demand starting with substitute goods. 00:05:41.390 --> 00:05:45.206 Now substitutes are two goods that are roughly interchangeable. 00:05:45.206 --> 00:05:46.232 They're not the same 00:05:46.232 --> 00:05:49.283 but they can serve broadly similar functions. 00:05:49.283 --> 00:05:51.500 Take for instance, hot dogs and hamburgers. 00:05:51.800 --> 00:05:54.000 They're both something you might have for dinner. 00:05:54.500 --> 00:05:55.614 Now in the setting, 00:05:55.614 --> 00:05:58.000 suppose the price of hot dogs goes up. 00:05:58.500 --> 00:06:00.609 What happens to the demand for hamburgers? 00:06:00.609 --> 00:06:02.400 A substitute for hot dogs. 00:06:03.100 --> 00:06:04.552 People will opt to buy 00:06:04.552 --> 00:06:07.687 the relatively less expensive hamburgers, 00:06:07.687 --> 00:06:10.786 instead of the now more expensive hot dogs. 00:06:13.100 --> 00:06:15.900 That means the demand for hamburgers increases. 00:06:17.000 --> 00:06:19.200 Or consider the opposite occurrence. 00:06:19.700 --> 00:06:22.490 What if the price of hot dogs decreases 00:06:22.490 --> 00:06:23.661 instead of going up? 00:06:23.661 --> 00:06:26.684 What happens then to the demand for hamburgers? 00:06:26.684 --> 00:06:29.300 Well, that's just the opposite of the first scenario. 00:06:29.500 --> 00:06:31.004 Hot dogs are now cheaper, 00:06:31.004 --> 00:06:33.988 and the demand for hamburgers decreases 00:06:33.988 --> 00:06:37.100 because it now costs less to buy hot dogs instead. 00:06:38.000 --> 00:06:40.500 Technically, two goods are substitutes 00:06:40.600 --> 00:06:42.861 if an increase in the price of one good 00:06:42.861 --> 00:06:47.000 leads to an increase in demand for the other good and vice versa. 00:06:48.300 --> 00:06:49.899 Another kind of related good 00:06:49.899 --> 00:06:52.200 is what economists call compliments. 00:06:52.700 --> 00:06:55.826 Compliments are two goods which are often used together 00:06:55.826 --> 00:06:57.826 and make each other more valuable. 00:06:58.300 --> 00:07:01.000 Suppose the price of hamburgers increases. 00:07:01.600 --> 00:07:04.600 What happens to the demand for hamburger buns, 00:07:04.800 --> 00:07:07.100 a complement to hamburgers proper? 00:07:07.900 --> 00:07:10.600 Well, fewer people will buy hamburgers 00:07:11.000 --> 00:07:14.000 and so fewer people will buy hamburger buns. 00:07:14.300 --> 00:07:17.700 The demand for hamburger buns decreases. 00:07:18.600 --> 00:07:21.200 And to consider the opposite situation, 00:07:21.500 --> 00:07:23.952 if the price of hamburger decreases, 00:07:23.952 --> 00:07:26.600 demand for hamburger buns will increase-- 00:07:27.000 --> 00:07:29.570 that is, more people buying hamburger 00:07:29.570 --> 00:07:32.421 means more people buying hamburger buns as well 00:07:32.421 --> 00:07:33.890 because again, you're putting the hamburger 00:07:33.890 --> 00:07:35.200 and the bun together. 00:07:35.800 --> 00:07:38.100 Technically, two goods are complements 00:07:38.300 --> 00:07:40.500 if an increase in the price of one good 00:07:40.600 --> 00:07:43.299 leads to a decrease in the demand for the other 00:07:43.299 --> 00:07:44.600 and vice versa. 00:07:45.400 --> 00:07:47.485 So in sum, hamburger producers 00:07:47.485 --> 00:07:49.570 want the price of hot dogs to go up, 00:07:49.900 --> 00:07:52.250 the price of hamburger buns to go down, 00:07:52.250 --> 00:07:54.600 and low carb diets to go viral. 00:07:54.900 --> 00:07:57.400 Finally, let's look at expectations. 00:07:57.800 --> 00:08:00.554 These can be expectations of market prices 00:08:00.554 --> 00:08:01.800 or of market events. 00:08:02.000 --> 00:08:04.000 Consider video game consoles. 00:08:04.500 --> 00:08:05.707 If it's November, 00:08:05.707 --> 00:08:09.171 and people expect the price of the gaming console to go down 00:08:09.171 --> 00:08:11.000 in a December holiday sale, 00:08:11.400 --> 00:08:14.300 they might wait a few weeks before buying the console. 00:08:15.000 --> 00:08:18.136 Demand for that console decreases today 00:08:18.136 --> 00:08:20.368 because it's going to increase later on. 00:08:21.200 --> 00:08:22.600 Or take batteries. 00:08:22.900 --> 00:08:26.100 Suppose you hear there's going to be a big hurricane in your area 00:08:26.800 --> 00:08:28.000 if a hurricane hits, 00:08:28.200 --> 00:08:31.400 you might expect the price of batteries is going to go up, 00:08:31.600 --> 00:08:34.779 or maybe it will be really hard to get any batteries at all. 00:08:34.779 --> 00:08:35.644 Oh no! 00:08:35.644 --> 00:08:38.656 That means a higher demand for batteries today, 00:08:38.656 --> 00:08:40.278 and so the expectation 00:08:40.278 --> 00:08:41.900 of this future event of the hurricane 00:08:42.000 --> 00:08:44.700 can change the demand for batteries today. 00:08:45.600 --> 00:08:47.350 If people expect the price of a good 00:08:47.350 --> 00:08:49.100 to be higher in the future, 00:08:49.600 --> 00:08:52.300 that typically increases demand today. 00:08:52.700 --> 00:08:54.800 Consumers adjust their current spending 00:08:54.800 --> 00:08:56.900 anticipating the future prices 00:08:57.100 --> 00:08:59.758 to obtain the lowest price possible. 00:08:59.758 --> 00:09:01.900 And that's it for our list of shifters. 00:09:02.700 --> 00:09:05.600 Now that you understand what a shift in demand means, 00:09:05.800 --> 00:09:09.100 practice recreating this list of shifters on your own. 00:09:09.900 --> 00:09:12.278 What would cause a higher quantity demanded 00:09:12.278 --> 00:09:13.300 at every price? 00:09:13.600 --> 00:09:15.200 More people? Wealthier people? 00:09:15.400 --> 00:09:17.800 It's the hotter in item and so on. 00:09:18.400 --> 00:09:20.950 Conversely, what would cause less of a good 00:09:20.950 --> 00:09:23.500 to be demanded at every price? 00:09:24.100 --> 00:09:25.411 Once you can do that, 00:09:25.411 --> 00:09:28.000 you'll be able to identify demand shifters 00:09:28.200 --> 00:09:31.000 without the need to memorize any list. 00:09:33.400 --> 00:09:34.360 If you're a teacher, 00:09:34.360 --> 00:09:36.722 you should check out our supply and demand unit plan 00:09:36.722 --> 00:09:38.100 that incorporates this video. 00:09:38.400 --> 00:09:39.400 If you're a learner, 00:09:39.400 --> 00:09:41.086 make sure this video sticks 00:09:41.086 --> 00:09:43.200 by answering a few quick, practice questions. 00:09:43.600 --> 00:09:45.870 Or if you're ready for more microeconomics, 00:09:45.870 --> 00:09:47.303 click for the next video,