In previous videos, we've covered
the basics of the demand curve.
Now let's discuss what happens
when the demand curve shifts
due to increases or decreases
in market demand.
First, let's look at
an increase in demand.
An increase in demand
means that the demand curve
shifts up and to the right.
Take the market
for house plants, for instance.
On the old demand curve at $20,
the quantity demanded
was five plants,
but on the new demand curve
at, again, $20,
the quantity demanded
is eight plants.
At $16, we go from six plants
to nine plants.
At $12, we go from seven
to ten plants, and so on.
An increase in demand is a greater
quantity demanded at every price.
We can also read
an increase in demand
using what is called
the vertical method.
What that means
is that for every quantity,
there's a greater willingness
to pay for that quantity.
For instance, for the fifth unit,
people had been willing
to pay $20 for that unit.
Now with the new demand curve,
people are willing to pay
$32 for that unit.
In summary, an increase in demand
means an increase
in the quantity demanded
at every market price,
or equivalently,
it means an increase
in the maximum willingness
to pay for a given quantity.
A decrease in demand--
well, that's just the opposite
of an increase in demand.
It's a shift down and to the left.
There's a decrease in quantity
demanded at every price.
Now at $20, people only want
to buy two houseplants.
At $16, we go from six
to three house plants and so on.
Similarly, this means a decrease
in the willingness to pay
for the same quantity.
For the fifth unit,
people were willing to pay
$20 for that unit
but now they're only going
to fork over $8
for that house plan.
So what can cause
a shift in demand?
What would make consumers buy more
or less of a good at every price?
Take a moment
to jot down some guesses.
We'll go through these
with a few examples.
But the real goal
is not to memorize this list
but rather to understand
what an increase
or decrease in demand means
so that you can recreate
this list on your own.
Let's now go through five factors
that can increase
or decrease market demand,
namely income, population, tastes,
the price of related goods,
and finally, expectations.
Let's start with changes in income.
The effect of a change
in income on demand,
depends on the nature
of the good in question.
For most goods,
as your income goes up,
you demand more of the good.
Think, for instance, fine dining.
You need to be able
to afford it, right?
The demand curve then shifts up
and to the right.
These goods are called normal goods
because the demand for them
goes up when incomes go up,
and indeed most goods
are normal goods--
that's why we call them normal.
And these same goods--
the demand for them goes down
when incomes go down.
There are also goods, however,
for which,
when your income goes up,
your demand for them
actually goes down.
These are exceptions.
We call them inferior goods.
So, an example
of such an inferior good
might be instant ramen--
it's very cheap.
As you make more money,
you might buy, say,
more caviar, more steak,
and less instant ramen.
No, thanks!
Thus, the demand curve
for instant ramen
will shift down into the left
as your income increases.
Now let's move on
to changes in population.
If the population
of an economy changes,
the number of potential buyers
of a good changes also.
What would happen
to the demand for hearing aids
if the elderly population
in your country increased?
Well, very likely demand
for hearing aids would increase.
At any price
for those hearing aids,
there would be
a higher quantity demanded.
Can you think of a good
that would decrease in demand
if the birth rates
in your country decreased?
Now, we'll move on
to changes in tastes.
Tastes are subjective,
and they're changing all the time.
New information, fashions, and fads
all can impact tastes.
To give an example,
what happens to the demand
for hamburgers
if low-carb diets,
like the keto diet
or the caveman diet
become more popular?
Well, people would want to go out
and buy and eat more hamburgers,
and so the demand for
hamburgers would increase.
Alternatively,
what if a controversy surfaced
that questioned the ethics
of hamburger production?
People might then feel bad
about buying hamburgers,
and then they would buy
fewer hamburgers
or maybe stop buying them
altogether.
The demand for hamburgers
then would go down.
Next, let's consider how the price
of a related good
can affect demand
starting with substitute goods.
Now substitutes are two goods
that are roughly interchangeable.
They're not the same
but they can serve
broadly similar functions.
Take for instance,
hot dogs and hamburgers.
They're both something
you might have for dinner.
Now in the setting,
suppose the price
of hot dogs goes up.
What happens to the demand
for hamburgers?
A substitute for hot dogs.
People will opt to buy
the relatively less expensive
hamburgers,
instead of the now
more expensive hot dogs.
That means the demand
for hamburgers increases.
Or consider
the opposite occurrence.
What if the price
of hot dogs decreases
instead of going up?
What happens then
to the demand for hamburgers?
Well, that's just the opposite
of the first scenario.
Hot dogs are now cheaper,
and the demand
for hamburgers decreases
because it now costs less
to buy hot dogs instead.
Technically,
two goods are substitutes
if an increase
in the price of one good
leads to an increase in demand
for the other good and vice versa.
Another kind of related good
is what economists
call compliments.
Compliments are two goods
which are often used together
and make each other more valuable.
Suppose the price
of hamburgers increases.
What happens to the demand
for hamburger buns,
a complement to hamburgers proper?
Well, fewer people
will buy hamburgers
and so fewer people
will buy hamburger buns.
The demand
for hamburger buns decreases.
And to consider
the opposite situation,
if the price
of hamburger decreases,
demand for hamburger buns
will increase--
that is, more people
buying hamburger
means more people buying
hamburger buns as well
because again,
you're putting the hamburger
and the bun together.
Technically, two goods
are complements
if an increase
in the price of one good
leads to a decrease
in the demand for the other
and vice versa.
So in sum, hamburger producers
want the price
of hot dogs to go up,
the price of hamburger buns
to go down,
and low carb diets to go viral.
Finally, let's look
at expectations.
These can be expectations
of market prices
or of market events.
Consider video game consoles.
If it's November,
and people expect the price
of the gaming console to go down
in a December holiday sale,
they might wait a few weeks
before buying the console.
Demand for that console
decreases today
because it's going
to increase later on.
Or take batteries.
Suppose you hear there's going
to be a big hurricane in your area
if a hurricane hits,
you might expect the price
of batteries is going to go up,
or maybe it will be really hard
to get any batteries at all.
Oh no!
That means a higher
demand for batteries today,
and so the expectation
of this future event
of the hurricane
can change the demand
for batteries today.
If people expect
the price of a good
to be higher in the future,
that typically increases
demand today.
Consumers adjust
their current spending
anticipating the future prices
to obtain
the lowest price possible.
And that's it
for our list of shifters.
Now that you understand
what a shift in demand means,
practice recreating
this list of shifters on your own.
What would cause
a higher quantity demanded
at every price?
More people? Wealthier people?
It's the hotter in item and so on.
Conversely, what would cause
less of a good
to be demanded at every price?
Once you can do that,
you'll be able to identify
demand shifters
without the need
to memorize any list.
If you're a teacher,
you should check out
our supply and demand unit plan
that incorporates this video.
If you're a learner,
make sure this video sticks
by answering a few quick,
practice questions.
Or if you're ready
for more microeconomics,
click for the next video,