What I wanna do in this video is think about a concept that we've already thought about multiple times in the context of many many videos and this is the idea of utility which is really just a way of saying how much benefit, or satisfaction, or value do you get out getting a good or service but the angle that we're gonna take in this video is gonna be slightly different in the past when we were measuring benefit or value we either measured in term of dollars or we said hey the benefit of getting an incremental Honda Civic was 5,000 dollars and when we're talking about incremental we're talking about the marginal benefit or early on, when we talked about the production possibilities frontier and when we talked about the marginal benefit of getting another squirel we were talking about it in terms of berries we were talking in terms of another good or service but what we're gonna do in this video is just think about it in absolute terms we're just gonna think of some arbitrary way of measuring utility and then just assign values to what's the value of getting one chocolate bar and then what's the value that we give to the next chocolate bar and chocolate bar after that we're gonna do the same things about fruit and from that we're gonna see if we can kind of built up some the things that we already know about demand curves and how things relate to price and the price of other goods and things like that and in particular we're gonna focus on marginal utility so obviously you could have total utility if I have four chocolate bars you could say that the total utility I am getting from all four of them or you can think of the marginal utility the utility I am getting from the next incremental chocolate bar or the next incremental pound of food and before I move on there's one thing this was a point of confusion for me when I first learned this ok I am using the word marginal utility now -in the past I've used the word marginal benefit- they sound very similar in fact I even used the word benefit when I defined marginal utility How are these things different? And the simple answer is conceptually they aren't conceptually they are the exact same thing though the difference is how the words tend to be used in the context of traditional microeconomics class so when people talk about utility they tend to measure in terms of some type of absolute measure that they just came up with some type of you could view it as utility units some type of satisfaction units while when they talk about marginal benefit they tend to measure it either in dollars or in terms of some other goods but I've seen either term used either way so they really do mean the exact same thing but in this video we're gonna use the term utility and we're gonna come up with measuring scale and it's somewhat arbitrary one and we're gonna use that to come up with some conclusions about the basket of goods someone might purchase depending on different prices so as you can imagine, I prewrote these two things we're gonna talk about chocolate bars and we're gonna talk about fruit so right here in these little tables here I've shown the marginal utility of each incremental bar and in case of fruit of each incremental pound of fruit so this is saying that first chocolate bar obviously if I have no chocolate bars I am getting no utility from chocolate bars and this is saying that the first chocolate bar has a marginal utility so the utility of that next icnremental one is a hundred I'm not saying a hundred dollars I'm not saying it's equivalent to a hundred pounds of fruit I'm not saying it's equivalent to a hundred berries I'm just saying arbitrarily saying it is a hundred and what matters is not that this is a hundred or thousand or million what matters is how this compares to others things so for example if I would say that this is a hundred and if I know that I like fruit a pound of fruit 20 percent more than that first or if I like an incremental -my first pound of fruit- 20 percent more then I would have to say that the marginal utility of my first pound of fruit is 120 and this is what we said right over here and if another way to think about it is if the marginal utility of the second chocolate bar I get because I've already enjoyed a little bit of chocolate bar and I am a little "chocolated" out is 20 percent less than that then if this is a hundred that this would have to be 80 I could have said this to be 1000 and this to be 800 and this to be 1200 I could have said this to be 10 and this to be 8 and this to be 12 what matters is that they really just have the same ratios between them that really do reflect much actual preferences so let's just think about this a little bit my first chocolate bar I am pretty excited I just call it a hundred the next chocolate bar I am a little bit less excited about it I've already had some chocolate my craving has been satiated to some degree but I still like chocolate so I'll call that an 80 we can call it 80 satisfaction units whatever you wanna call it then the next chocolate bar after this now I am starting to get pretty stuffed and I am really "chocolated" out and so I am not getting as much benefit from it and then finally if you give me another chocolate bar it's even less and if we were to list fifth chocolate bar I might not want it at all my marginal utility might go to zero for that fifth chocolate bar maybe for that sixth chocolate bar I have to somehow get rid of it I am so tired of chocolate bars maybe I have a negative marginal utility and we can think about the same thing with fruit the first pound of fruit I am pretty excited about fruit I have a fruit craving I like that first pound of fruit even more than that first chocolate bar I like it 20 percent more so I get 120, you could call it utility points or whatever arbitrary you want to call it then my next pound of fruit once again, I am having diminishing utility diminishing benefit as I get more and more incremental pound of fruit now, it's very important to realize this is marginal utility not total utility this is the utility I am getting from each incremental pound it's positive so I am still enjoying that next incremental pound I am just enjoying it little bit less than the pound before and to realize what total utility is if I were to have to pounds of fruit I would get 120 of utility from that first pound and I would get a 100 from that second pound and so you would say I had a total utility of 220 utility units from both pounds now with just the information that I've given here there are few things you could say you could say well look my first pound of fruit I enjoy more 20 percent more than my first chocolate bar you could also say my second pound of fruit I derive about the same amount of value as my first chocolate bar you could say that my second chocolate bar I enjoy less than my first chocolate bar you could even say 20 percent less if these numbers are good but it still doesn't give you a lot of information about how you would actually spend your money you might say obviously wouldn't you just want to buy fruit over chocolate bars or at least that first pound of fruit over that first chocolate bar? well you might but it depends on how much fruit actually cost just looking at this alone we can just make relative judgements about how much we prefer each incremental bar or each incremental pound or them relative to each other but it really doesn't tell us how we would spend our actual money so let's think about things let's put some prices on some of these goods and think about we would actually allocate our dollars given these marginal utility numbers right over here so let's say that the chocolate bars are 1 dollar per bar and let's say that the fruit is 2 dollars per pound 2 dollars per pound so this is going to be per pound and this is going to be per bar and what we're gonna think about is we're gonna think about marginal utility for that incremental chocolate bar per price of that incremental chocolate bar here the price is gonna be at a dollar per pound so here for that first bar I am going to be spending a dollar and I am getting a hundred marginal utility points whatever you want to call it so I am getting a 100 marginal utility points for that dollar so I'm getting a hundred a hundred marginal utility points per dollar Here, same logic I am getting 80 marginal utility points per dollar this is pretty simple math here I am getting 60 marginal utility points for the dollar her I am getting 40 so that doesn't seem too interesting it might be a little bit more interesting here what is the marginal utility per incremental fruit that I am getting per dollar per price or I should say per price of the incremental fruit here well here, the first pound of fruit I am getting 120 marginal utility points but I paid 2 dollars for it so 120, let me write it over here so for that first incremental fruit the marginal utility for that first fruit is 120 and the price for that first pound of fruit is equal to 2 so I am getting 60 marginal utility points per dollar I'm getting 60 here 100 marginal utility points but I am spending 2 dollars so it's 50 points per dollar this is 25 points per dollar this is 10 points per dollar now this makes things a little bit more interesting if I had 5 dollars to spend how would I want to spend my 5 dollars well where am I getting the most you really want to just think about where you're getting the most satisfaction for each dollar where you're getting the most bang for your buck so where am I going to spend my first dollar so dollar one: let's think about it a little bit my first dollar so dollar one: my first dollar where am I going to get the most satisfaction per dollar well I get the most satisfaction per dollar right over here I get a 100 satisfaction units per dollar even though I like a pound of fruit more I am getting less satisfaction per dollar so I am getting less bang for my buck so my first dollar is going to go right over there I am going to buy one candy bar then where am I going to spend my second dollar dollar two: so once again, I just wan to look at all my options and we're gonna assume that I am going to spend my dollar on either of these two just to limit our universe once again I am gonna maximize my bang for buck I get 80 satisfaction points or marginal utility points over here per dollar and I only get 60 over here so I am gonna buy a second chocolate bar let's keep going where am I gonna spend my third dollar now it gets a little bit interesting I could spend my third dollar right over here and get 60 points per dollar or I could spend it over here and get 60 points per dollar I would actually get the same amount these are both 60 points per dollar so I am kind of neutral I am getting the same bang for my buck whether I get another chocolate bar or whether I get another fruit so just for simplicity let's say I get another chocolate bar I could have got the fruit too so it's really a toss-up I could flip a coin and I choose to get another chocolate bar so I spent my first three dollar on three chocolate bars now, where am I going to spend my fourth dollar well my fourth dollar now my best bang for my buck isn't to get another chocolate bar I am only going to get 40 points per buck there now it is to spend it on fruit so now the next dollar I could spend on half a pound of fruit and I would get this so my fourth dollar, I could spend on this for half a pound of fruit because it's two dollars per pound and then I could spend my fifth dollar there too so this is my fourth and my fifth dollar because it's two dollars you could think of it we're spending 2 dollars for one pound of fruit and we're getting 60 utility points per dollar so we're getting the best bang for our buck right over there but what was useful about this is that it allowed us without thinking money just say how much do we like these things irrespective of their actual price and then given a certain price it allowed us to think rationally about how would we actually spend our money in this case when chocolate bars are a dollar and fruit is two dollars per pound we decided to buy three chocolate bars and only one pound of fruit