0:00:00.000,0:00:05.178 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.354,0:00:11.293 - [Alex] In our final talk[br]in monopoly, 0:00:11.293,0:00:13.509 we're going to discuss[br]the costs of monopoly, 0:00:13.509,0:00:16.458 but also the potential benefits. 0:00:21.451,0:00:24.713 The major costs of monopoly[br]is that compared to competition, 0:00:24.713,0:00:26.624 monopoly is inefficient. 0:00:26.624,0:00:30.367 It leads to a loss in the gains[br]from trade or a deadweight loss. 0:00:30.367,0:00:32.832 Let's remind ourselves[br]about the gains from trade 0:00:32.832,0:00:35.442 under competition[br]and then we can compare 0:00:35.442,0:00:36.825 with monopoly. 0:00:36.825,0:00:39.442 Here we'll simplify[br]with a flat supply curve, 0:00:39.442,0:00:41.409 a constant cost industry. 0:00:41.409,0:00:44.764 In this case the total gains[br]from trade go to consumers 0:00:44.764,0:00:46.923 in this blue area right here. 0:00:46.923,0:00:49.873 Now let's see what the total gains[br]from trade or total welfare 0:00:49.873,0:00:51.656 is under monopoly. 0:00:51.656,0:00:54.096 We choose exactly[br]the same demand curve 0:00:54.096,0:00:56.781 and the same constant cost curve. 0:00:56.781,0:01:00.891 We find the profit maximizing price[br]and quantity in the usual way. 0:01:01.714,0:01:05.819 Consumers, not surprisingly,[br]get less under monopoly 0:01:05.819,0:01:07.677 since the price is higher. 0:01:08.204,0:01:13.406 Now some of what the consumers lose[br]is transferred to the monopolist 0:01:13.406,0:01:17.027 in terms of profit, and as far[br]as an economist is concerned, 0:01:17.027,0:01:19.738 at least someone is getting[br]these gains from trade. 0:01:19.824,0:01:21.848 So the transfer is neutral. 0:01:22.930,0:01:26.681 What's bad however,[br]is that total welfare falls 0:01:26.681,0:01:30.462 under monopoly[br]because no one gets this area, 0:01:30.462,0:01:32.363 the deadweight loss. 0:01:32.363,0:01:36.562 These are trades that from a social[br]point of view are beneficial. 0:01:36.562,0:01:41.562 The demanders are willing to pay[br]more than what would be the cost 0:01:41.562,0:01:43.503 of producing these goods. 0:01:44.411,0:01:47.227 These trades, however,[br]don't happen. 0:01:48.110,0:01:50.952 Even though they're socially[br]beneficial they don't happen 0:01:50.952,0:01:55.193 because they aren't profitable,[br]they aren't privately beneficial. 0:01:55.670,0:01:57.718 Think of a movie theater[br]that is half empty. 0:01:58.247,0:02:00.647 Surely there are some people[br]out there who would value 0:02:00.647,0:02:04.816 watching the movie at more[br]than its marginal cost, about zero. 0:02:05.374,0:02:08.411 So why doesn't the movie theater[br]lower the price to these people? 0:02:09.241,0:02:13.556 Because to do so it would have[br]to lower the price to everyone 0:02:13.556,0:02:15.964 and that would reduce[br]total profits. 0:02:16.895,0:02:18.841 So the basic lesson is this. 0:02:20.577,0:02:23.510 Consumers buy a good[br]so long as the value to them 0:02:23.510,0:02:25.168 exceeds the price. 0:02:25.652,0:02:28.542 Under competition price[br]is equal to marginal cost, 0:02:29.055,0:02:33.076 so consumers will buy every unit[br]such that the value to them 0:02:33.076,0:02:35.741 is a greater[br]than the marginal cost. 0:02:36.388,0:02:38.014 That's efficient. 0:02:38.014,0:02:41.563 Under monopoly, consumers[br]also buy so long as the value 0:02:41.563,0:02:45.478 to them is greater than the price,[br]but since price is greater 0:02:45.478,0:02:49.964 than marginal cost,[br]we get too few units produced. 0:02:50.539,0:02:52.742 We get a loss[br]in the gains from trade. 0:02:53.917,0:02:55.658 Let's remind ourselves[br]what deadweight loss 0:02:55.658,0:02:57.436 looks like in practice. 0:02:57.436,0:03:00.828 GSK prices Combivir[br]at $12.50 per pill. 0:03:01.330,0:03:04.024 The marginal cost is 50 cents. 0:03:04.024,0:03:08.442 The deadweight loss is the value[br]of the trades that do not occur 0:03:08.442,0:03:11.226 because price is greater[br]than marginal cost. 0:03:11.226,0:03:15.000 Some people would be willing[br]and able to pay $10 per pill 0:03:15.000,0:03:19.086 or $4, or even $1 per pill[br]and those prices 0:03:19.086,0:03:23.104 would more than cover[br]the cost of producing those pills. 0:03:23.889,0:03:26.092 But those trades don't occur 0:03:26.092,0:03:29.108 because they aren't[br]profitable to GSK. 0:03:29.739,0:03:33.648 Many monopolies around the world[br]are born of government corruption. 0:03:33.648,0:03:37.074 In Indonesia, Tommy Suharto,[br]the president's son, 0:03:37.074,0:03:40.723 was given the highly profitable[br]clove monopoly. 0:03:40.723,0:03:42.443 He used the profits[br]from that monopoly 0:03:42.443,0:03:43.942 to buy Lamborghini. 0:03:43.942,0:03:47.460 Not a Lamborghini --[br]he bought the entire company. 0:03:48.071,0:03:50.925 These kinds of monopolies[br]are unredeemed. 0:03:50.925,0:03:53.674 They have costs[br]and no social benefits at all. 0:03:54.822,0:03:58.557 Some monopolies however,[br]do have countervailing benefits. 0:03:59.205,0:04:01.921 Consider what would happen[br]if the U.S. eliminated patents 0:04:01.921,0:04:03.708 for pharmaceuticals. 0:04:03.708,0:04:06.419 Competition, it's true,[br]would drive down the price 0:04:06.419,0:04:10.932 of existing drugs to marginal cost,[br]as happens today 0:04:10.932,0:04:14.811 as soon as patents expire,[br]usually within 10 to 15 years 0:04:14.811,0:04:17.142 after the drug first enters[br]the market. 0:04:17.849,0:04:20.911 But it costs about[br]a billion dollars 0:04:20.911,0:04:24.942 to bring the average new drug[br]to market in the United States, 0:04:24.942,0:04:29.269 and R&D costs are not included[br]in marginal cost. 0:04:30.042,0:04:33.477 As the saying goes,[br]it costs about a billion dollars 0:04:33.477,0:04:38.331 to create the first pill,[br]50 cents to create the second pill. 0:04:39.196,0:04:42.923 50 cents is the marginal cost,[br]the cost of an additional pill, 0:04:42.923,0:04:45.171 but to bring that first pill[br]to market costs 0:04:45.171,0:04:47.355 about a billion dollars. 0:04:47.941,0:04:52.096 If price were quickly pushed[br]down to marginal cost, 0:04:52.096,0:04:56.062 firms would not be able[br]to recover their R&D costs, 0:04:56.577,0:04:59.278 and the result would be[br]fewer new drugs. 0:05:00.579,0:05:03.731 Once the drug is created,[br]the patent, the monopoly, 0:05:03.731,0:05:06.896 creates inefficiency,[br]we get too few units produced. 0:05:07.473,0:05:10.816 But the patent increases[br]the incentive to produce 0:05:10.816,0:05:12.988 the new drugs in the first place. 0:05:13.644,0:05:14.937 So there's a trade-off. 0:05:15.333,0:05:17.996 More monopoly[br]reduces static efficiency, 0:05:17.996,0:05:20.515 the quantity produced,[br]but can increase 0:05:20.515,0:05:25.057 dynamic efficiency, the incentive[br]to do research and development. 0:05:26.968,0:05:29.327 This trade-off applies[br]to other goods 0:05:29.327,0:05:32.087 with high development cost,[br]not just pharmaceuticals. 0:05:32.604,0:05:35.465 Information goods,[br]goods like music, movies, 0:05:35.465,0:05:38.103 computer programs,[br]new chemicals, new materials, 0:05:38.103,0:05:39.530 new technologies. 0:05:39.530,0:05:42.324 These typically have high[br]development costs 0:05:42.324,0:05:44.772 and low marginal cost[br]of production. 0:05:44.835,0:05:48.179 And that suggests there may be[br]possible benefits to patent 0:05:48.179,0:05:50.260 or copyright production. 0:05:50.756,0:05:54.353 More generally for these types[br]of goods there's a policy trade-off 0:05:54.353,0:05:56.797 which we always want[br]to keep in mind. 0:05:56.797,0:06:01.657 That is lower prices today[br]may generate fewer new ideas 0:06:01.657,0:06:03.390 in the future. 0:06:05.356,0:06:08.381 Nobel prize winning[br]economic historian, Douglas North, 0:06:08.381,0:06:11.916 for example, has argued,[br]"The failure to develop 0:06:11.916,0:06:14.537 systematic property rights[br]in innovation 0:06:14.537,0:06:17.664 up until fairly modern times[br]was a major source 0:06:17.664,0:06:20.726 of the slow pace[br]of technological change." 0:06:21.956,0:06:24.889 Is there a better way[br]of navigating this trade-off? 0:06:25.095,0:06:26.622 Perhaps. 0:06:26.622,0:06:29.947 Suppose that the government[br]bought up a pharmaceutical patent 0:06:29.947,0:06:34.423 for its total monopoly profits[br]and then they ripped the patent up. 0:06:35.155,0:06:38.648 Competitors would enter[br]and drive the price of the drug 0:06:38.648,0:06:41.041 down to marginal cost,[br]thus we would have 0:06:41.041,0:06:42.676 static efficiency. 0:06:42.676,0:06:44.675 At the same time,[br]since the government 0:06:44.675,0:06:47.971 was paying firms[br]their monopoly profits, 0:06:47.971,0:06:50.728 we would still have lots[br]of incentive to do research 0:06:50.728,0:06:53.525 and development --[br]dynamic efficiency. 0:06:53.525,0:06:56.027 Thus we could have[br]the best of all worlds. 0:06:56.027,0:06:58.923 Of course, there may be[br]some downsides as well. 0:06:58.923,0:07:01.441 Higher taxes to pay[br]for the patent also have 0:07:01.441,0:07:03.980 their own deadweight loss,[br]and it might be difficult 0:07:03.980,0:07:06.840 to say exactly[br]how much a patent is worth. 0:07:07.323,0:07:09.346 And there could be[br]possible corruption. 0:07:09.346,0:07:11.964 Nevertheless, this is an idea[br]we're thinking about, 0:07:11.964,0:07:14.240 and perhaps worth[br]experimenting with. 0:07:15.437,0:07:18.172 Prizes are another way[br]of navigating the trade-off. 0:07:18.720,0:07:21.166 As with patent buyouts,[br]the idea is that a firm 0:07:21.166,0:07:24.227 is offered up front its R&D costs. 0:07:24.450,0:07:27.299 But the government[br]only pays the firm 0:07:27.299,0:07:29.360 if it achieves a certain goal. 0:07:29.360,0:07:31.954 And if that goal is achieved,[br]the technology goes 0:07:31.954,0:07:35.017 into the public domain[br]and could be used by anyone. 0:07:35.582,0:07:38.125 SpaceShipOne, for example,[br]won $10 million 0:07:38.125,0:07:41.831 for being the first privately[br]developed manned rocket 0:07:41.831,0:07:43.770 capable of reaching space[br]and returning 0:07:43.770,0:07:45.603 in a short period of time. 0:07:45.603,0:07:47.958 And prizes are being used[br]more often. 0:07:47.958,0:07:50.237 The government set up a prize[br]for better light bulbs, 0:07:50.237,0:07:53.014 for example,[br]and that worked quite well. 0:07:53.870,0:07:56.556 There's also a third way[br]of navigating the trade-off. 0:07:57.263,0:08:01.036 You may have noticed, for example,[br]that so far we've assumed 0:08:01.036,0:08:03.553 that the monopolist[br]must charge the same price 0:08:03.553,0:08:05.166 to everyone. 0:08:05.166,0:08:07.207 Is this necessarily true? 0:08:07.207,0:08:09.151 In some cases,[br]the monopolist can charge 0:08:09.151,0:08:11.381 different prices[br]to different people -- 0:08:11.381,0:08:13.378 price discrimination. 0:08:13.378,0:08:16.516 As we'll see in the next chapter[br]and set of lectures, 0:08:16.516,0:08:20.138 price discrimination explains a lot[br]about how products are priced 0:08:20.138,0:08:22.884 and it also has some costs[br]and some benefits 0:08:22.884,0:08:24.912 which we'll be discussing. 0:08:24.912,0:08:26.455 See you then, thanks. 0:08:27.587,0:08:29.252 - [Narrator] If you want[br]to test yourself, 0:08:29.252,0:08:31.389 click "Practice Questions." 0:08:31.389,0:08:34.794 Or if you're ready to move on,[br]just click "Next Video." 0:08:34.794,0:08:38.733 ♪ [music] ♪