0:00:00.000,0:00:03.000 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.170,0:00:11.010 - [Alex] Now that we know [br]how to find the profit 0:00:11.010,0:00:14.010 maximization point, [br]we're going to show 0:00:14.010,0:00:18.807 the amount of profit on the diagram [br]using the average cost curve. 0:00:23.960,0:00:25.590 So as I said in the last lecture, 0:00:25.590,0:00:28.090 average cost is the cost [br]per unit of output. 0:00:28.090,0:00:32.780 That is, average cost is[br]total cost divided by Q. 0:00:32.780,0:00:36.110 Now remember also [br]that total cost can be broken down 0:00:36.110,0:00:39.018 into fixed costs plus [br]variable costs. 0:00:39.018,0:00:42.546 So we can also write average cost[br]in a slightly longer format. 0:00:42.546,0:00:45.770 Average cost is equal [br]to fixed cost divided by Q 0:00:45.770,0:00:50.230 plus the variable cost divided [br]by Q, the units of output. 0:00:50.230,0:00:53.790 That's a little bit useful [br]because we're able to see, 0:00:53.790,0:00:57.660 get some intuition, for the shape [br]of a typical average cost curve. 0:00:57.660,0:01:02.459 Notice that the fixed costs [br]don't change with Q. 0:01:02.459,0:01:04.079 That's why they're fixed. 0:01:04.079,0:01:07.330 So when Q is small -- this number, 0:01:07.330,0:01:09.260 suppose fixed cost is 100, 0:01:09.260,0:01:11.980 and Q is small -- then this number [br]is going to be big 0:01:11.980,0:01:14.700 like 100 divided by 1. 0:01:14.700,0:01:18.260 As Q gets larger, however,[br]this number -- 0:01:18.260,0:01:20.850 fixed cost divided by Q -- [br]is going to get smaller, 0:01:20.850,0:01:25.630 So when Q is 10, this number [br]100 divided by 10 becomes 10. 0:01:25.630,0:01:29.220 So it goes from 100,[br]and it goes down, down, down, down, 0:01:29.220,0:01:31.890 get's lower and lower and lower[br]all the time as you divide 0:01:31.890,0:01:33.371 by a bigger quantity. 0:01:33.371,0:01:38.411 On the other hand, the variable [br]costs increase with quantity. 0:01:38.411,0:01:41.761 Moreover, what we saw [br]with the marginal cost curve 0:01:41.761,0:01:44.869 is that at some point,[br]your variable costs are going 0:01:44.869,0:01:47.322 to increase faster than quantity. 0:01:47.322,0:01:50.494 So what's going to happen is [br]that this number at some point -- 0:01:50.494,0:01:52.954 variable cost divided by quantity --[br]is going to get bigger 0:01:52.954,0:01:54.341 and bigger and bigger. 0:01:54.341,0:01:59.521 So you have two things, one force [br]is driving average cost down. 0:01:59.521,0:02:03.140 That's going to be particularly [br]strong at the beginning. 0:02:03.140,0:02:06.770 Eventually, however, [br]the second force here is going 0:02:06.770,0:02:09.300 to drive average cost up. 0:02:09.300,0:02:12.340 So that's going to be our typical [br]shape of an average cost curve -- 0:02:12.340,0:02:14.750 falling, reaches a minimum,[br]and then rising. 0:02:14.750,0:02:16.560 So let's draw it like that. 0:02:16.560,0:02:19.030 Okay, here's our typical[br]marginal cost curve, 0:02:19.030,0:02:22.770 and here is our marginal [br]revenue curve, equal to price. 0:02:22.770,0:02:26.390 We know that the profit maximizing [br]point is where marginal revenue 0:02:26.390,0:02:28.190 is equal to marginal cost. 0:02:28.190,0:02:31.900 Here is our average cost curve [br]and notice it has the shape 0:02:31.900,0:02:35.010 which I described --[br]it starts off high, it falls, 0:02:35.010,0:02:37.890 reaches a minimum, [br]and then goes right back up again. 0:02:37.890,0:02:42.770 Couple of other points to notice[br]is that the minimum point, 0:02:42.770,0:02:46.340 the marginal cost curve goes [br]through the minimum point 0:02:46.340,0:02:48.400 of the average cost curve. 0:02:48.400,0:02:52.530 Now that's just a mathematical fact, [br]but let me give you some intuition. 0:02:52.530,0:02:57.110 Instead of cost I want [br]to talk about average grade 0:02:57.110,0:02:58.110 and marginal grade. 0:02:58.110,0:03:00.110 So suppose that your [br]average grade is 80%. 0:03:00.110,0:03:05.640 You're doing really pretty good,[br]but then on your next test 0:03:05.820,0:03:08.602 you only get 60% -- lower. 0:03:08.602,0:03:09.602 What is that going to do [br]to your average? 0:03:09.602,0:03:11.602 Well, it's going to drive [br]your average down. 0:03:11.602,0:03:18.640 Indeed whenever your marginal [br]is below your average, 0:03:18.820,0:03:21.910 the average must be falling. 0:03:21.910,0:03:24.910 On the other hand, suppose [br]that you're getting 80%, 0:03:24.910,0:03:25.910 and on your next test you get 90%. 0:03:25.910,0:03:28.780 Great, but what does [br]that do to your average? 0:03:28.780,0:03:30.780 It drives your average up. 0:03:30.780,0:03:36.710 Indeed whenever your marginal[br]is above the average, 0:03:36.890,0:03:39.520 the average must be rising. 0:03:39.520,0:03:40.520 Now suppose what happens [br]when you're getting let's say 80%, 0:03:40.520,0:03:42.520 and on your next test,[br]you also get 80%. 0:03:42.520,0:03:49.630 Well then your marginal is equal [br]to your average grade, 0:03:49.810,0:03:55.700 and your average grade is flat -- [br]it doesn't change, it's flat. 0:03:55.880,0:03:58.420 But what is true for average [br]and marginal grades is also true 0:03:58.420,0:04:01.420 for average cost and marginal cost. 0:04:01.420,0:04:06.360 Whenever the marginal cost is [br]below the average, 0:04:06.360,0:04:09.360 the average is falling. 0:04:09.360,0:04:10.360 Whenever the marginal cost is [br]above the average, 0:04:10.360,0:04:12.270 the average is rising. 0:04:12.270,0:04:15.270 And where marginal is [br]just equal to average, 0:04:15.270,0:04:18.390 the average is flat. 0:04:18.390,0:04:21.390 In other words, we are [br]at the minimum point 0:04:21.390,0:04:23.780 of the average cost curve. 0:04:23.780,0:04:26.780 Okay, now I said we could use [br]the average cost curve 0:04:26.780,0:04:27.980 to figure out profit -- [br]show profit on the diagram. 0:04:27.980,0:04:30.980 We can do that with just [br]a little bit of rearranging. 0:04:30.980,0:04:36.400 Remember that profit is equal [br]to total revenue minus total cost 0:04:36.580,0:04:41.720 and total revenue is [br]price times quantity -- P times Q. 0:04:41.900,0:04:44.010 We also know [br]that average cost is equal 0:04:44.010,0:04:47.010 to total cost divided by quantity. 0:04:47.010,0:04:49.070 Let's just rearrange that [br]to tell us that total cost is equal 0:04:49.070,0:04:52.070 to average cost times quantity. 0:04:52.070,0:04:55.600 So just take this one [br]and multiply both sides by Q. 0:04:55.600,0:04:58.600 Let's now make these substitutions [br]into our profit equation. 0:04:58.600,0:05:04.280 If we do that, then profit is equal [br]to total revenue -- 0:05:04.280,0:05:05.280 price times quantity --[br]minus total cost -- 0:05:05.280,0:05:07.730 average cost times quantity. 0:05:07.730,0:05:10.730 Now let's take Q out [br]of both parts of this equation, 0:05:10.730,0:05:16.520 and we find that profit [br]can also be written as price 0:05:16.700,0:05:19.990 minus average cost, [br]all of that times quantity. 0:05:19.990,0:05:22.990 That's nice because we can find 0:05:22.990,0:05:27.750 all of these elements [br]on our diagram. 0:05:27.750,0:05:30.750 Here's the price. 0:05:30.750,0:05:33.600 Here's the average cost[br]at the profit maximizing quantity. 0:05:33.600,0:05:36.600 Let's just show that. [br]There's the price. 0:05:36.600,0:05:42.190 There's the average cost [br]at the profit maximizing quantity. 0:05:42.370,0:05:45.290 So profit at the profit [br]maximizing quantity is 0:05:45.290,0:05:48.290 this green area right here -- 0:05:48.290,0:05:51.290 price minus average cost [br]times quantity. 0:05:51.290,0:05:56.260 So now we have a nice way [br]of showing in a diagram 0:05:56.440,0:05:59.270 exactly how much profit is. 0:05:59.270,0:06:00.270 Let's use this tool some more. 0:06:00.270,0:06:02.270 Here's another example [br]of the average cost curve in action. 0:06:02.270,0:06:06.710 Remember, I said that profit [br]maximization doesn't necessarily 0:06:06.890,0:06:08.630 mean the firm is making [br]a positive profit. 0:06:08.630,0:06:11.630 Sometimes the best you can do [br]is to minimize your losses. 0:06:11.630,0:06:16.630 You may have to take a loss. 0:06:16.810,0:06:19.900 For example, suppose [br]that the price is below $17. 0:06:19.900,0:06:22.900 That is, here's the market price, [br]which is equal to the firm's 0:06:22.900,0:06:24.930 marginal revenue curve. 0:06:24.930,0:06:25.930 How does the firm profit maximize? 0:06:25.930,0:06:27.930 It chooses the quantity [br]where marginal revenue is 0:06:27.930,0:06:30.570 equal to marginal cost. 0:06:30.570,0:06:33.570 In that case, this quantity is one. 0:06:33.570,0:06:37.180 Now what's the profit [br]for the firm? 0:06:37.180,0:06:40.180 Well, as usual we measure [br]profit as price minus 0:06:40.180,0:06:45.090 average cost times quantity. 0:06:45.090,0:06:48.090 But notice that price is [br]below the average cost 0:06:48.090,0:06:54.980 at the profit maximizing [br]quantity of one. 0:06:55.160,0:06:58.100 Since price is below average cost, [br]this is a loss. 0:06:58.100,0:07:01.100 It's a negative quantity. 0:07:01.100,0:07:04.100 It is a loss. In fact, notice [br]that the breakeven price is $17, 0:07:04.100,0:07:10.680 which is the minimum [br]of the average cost curve. 0:07:10.860,0:07:15.100 In order to make a profit, [br]the firm at least has to meet 0:07:15.100,0:07:18.100 the minimum of its [br]average cost curve. 0:07:18.100,0:07:20.440 So at any price below $17,[br]we'll be profit maximizing 0:07:20.440,0:07:23.440 at a point where price is equal[br]to marginal cost, 0:07:23.440,0:07:29.050 and notice that all of these [br]prices are below average cost. 0:07:29.230,0:07:32.550 So all of this area down here, 0:07:32.550,0:07:35.550 even the profit maximizing [br]quantity, will mean a loss. 0:07:35.550,0:07:39.120 On the other hand, once we get [br]above $17, above the minimum 0:07:39.120,0:07:42.120 of the average cost curve, then we [br]can price equal to marginal cost. 0:07:42.120,0:07:47.600 We can chose the quantities such [br]the price is equal to marginal cost. 0:07:47.780,0:07:52.640 That price will be above average [br]cost, so we'll be taking a profit. 0:07:52.820,0:08:00.360 Therefore, $17, the minimum[br]of the average cost curve, 0:08:00.540,0:08:01.540 is the breakeven point. 0:08:01.540,0:08:02.540 If the price is less [br]than the minimum 0:08:02.540,0:08:04.370 of the average cost curve, [br]we're going to be taking a loss. 0:08:04.370,0:08:08.970 If the price is bigger [br]than the minimum 0:08:09.150,0:08:13.490 of the average cost curve, [br]then we can make a profit. 0:08:13.670,0:08:16.550 So when should a firm enter [br]or exit an industry? 0:08:16.550,0:08:19.550 In the long run, the firms will [br]enter when price 0:08:19.550,0:08:21.040 is above average cost. 0:08:21.040,0:08:24.040 If price is somewhere [br]above the average cost curve 0:08:24.040,0:08:25.040 then the firm can make [br]a profit by entering 0:08:25.040,0:08:28.030 and that's what firms want to do. 0:08:28.030,0:08:29.030 They want to find profit, [br]so they will want to enter 0:08:29.030,0:08:31.520 wherever a profit is possible. 0:08:31.520,0:08:33.770 Firms will exit the industry [br]when the price is below 0:08:33.770,0:08:36.770 the average cost curve. 0:08:36.770,0:08:38.640 Then they're going [br]to be taking a loss, 0:08:38.640,0:08:41.640 and they're going to want to exit. 0:08:41.640,0:08:42.900 Finally, when the price is [br]equal to the minimum 0:08:42.900,0:08:45.900 of the average cost --[br]it's just equal to the bottom 0:08:45.900,0:08:50.690 of the average cost curve, [br]profits are zero, 0:08:50.870,0:08:52.870 and there's no incentive [br]to either exit or enter the industry. 0:08:52.870,0:08:55.870 Now you might ask, why would[br]firms remain in an industry 0:08:55.870,0:08:59.560 if profits are zero? 0:08:59.560,0:09:02.560 Zero profits, this is just [br]a matter of terminology, 0:09:02.560,0:09:07.370 means that at the market price [br]the firm is covering all of its costs 0:09:07.550,0:09:10.590 including enough [br]to pay labor and capital, 0:09:10.590,0:09:13.590 their ordinary opportunity cost. 0:09:13.590,0:09:18.220 So zero profits means everyone[br]is being paid enough 0:09:18.400,0:09:21.690 to make them satisfied. 0:09:21.690,0:09:24.690 Zero profits, in other words,[br]is what normal people mean 0:09:24.690,0:09:27.560 by normal profits. 0:09:27.560,0:09:28.560 So when an economist [br]says zero profits 0:09:28.560,0:09:30.560 just substitute normal profits. 0:09:30.560,0:09:32.220 One more point [br]about entry and exit. [br] 0:09:32.220,0:09:35.220 It doesn't always make sense [br]to exit an industry immediately 0:09:35.220,0:09:40.890 when price falls [br]below average cost. 0:09:41.070,0:09:45.500 Or to enter immediately [br]when price is above average cost. 0:09:45.500,0:09:48.500 Why not? Well, there are [br]also entry and exit costs. 0:09:48.500,0:09:53.400 For example, suppose that that the price[br]of oil is currently above the average cost 0:09:53.580,0:09:59.260 of pumping oil, if you've already got a[br]well. Should you enter the industry? Well, 0:09:59.440,0:10:05.250 maybe not necessarily. Because entry[br]requires you to drill an oil well, and 0:10:05.430,0:10:08.980 drilling an oil well is a sunk cost -[br]literally in this case. 0:10:09.160,0:10:15.780 A sunk cost is a cost that once incurred[br]can never be recovered. So if you enter 0:10:15.960,0:10:20.690 the industry and drill the oil well, you[br]don't get that money back when you later 0:10:20.870,0:10:28.160 exit the industry. What this means is you[br]don't want to enter unless you expect the 0:10:28.340,0:10:35.860 price of oil to stay above the minimum of[br]the average cost curve long enough so 0:10:36.040,0:10:41.680 that you can also recover your entry[br]costs. So just because the price goes 0:10:41.860,0:10:45.770 above the average cost a little bit, you[br]don't immediately want to jump into that 0:10:45.950,0:10:52.120 industry. You have to expect that that[br]price is going to stay above average cost 0:10:52.300,0:10:58.900 long enough for you to recover your entry[br]costs. For the same reasons, if there are 0:10:59.080,0:11:03.480 exit costs, for example, if you have to[br]shutter up the well or fill the well with 0:11:03.660,0:11:07.850 cement when you exit the industry as you[br]do in the United States, then when price 0:11:08.030,0:11:13.460 falls below average cost, it may be best to[br]weather the storm at least for sometime 0:11:13.640,0:11:21.060 before you exit. Only if you expect the[br]price of oil to stay below your minimum of 0:11:21.240,0:11:26.550 average cost for an extended period of[br]time will you want to exit the industry. 0:11:26.730,0:11:31.670 After all, if the price of oil falls below[br]the average cost just for a little bit, and 0:11:31.850,0:11:37.320 then it goes back up, the lifetime[br]profits can still be possible. So, entry 0:11:37.500,0:11:40.810 and exit could be quite complicated[br]because you've got to be thinking about 0:11:40.990,0:11:46.943 the lifetime profits, not just your[br]immediate profits. However, the bottom 0:11:46.943,0:11:53.113 line is pretty simple. Firms seek profits[br]and they want to avoid losses. As a 0:11:53.113,0:11:57.637 result, firms will enter industries when[br]the price is above the average cost and 0:11:57.637,0:12:02.126 they can make a profit, and they will exit[br]when the price is below the average cost. 0:12:02.126,0:12:03.891 Thanks. 0:12:04.420,0:12:09.410 - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,[br]click, "Practice Questions," or if you're 0:12:09.590,0:12:12.177 ready to move on,[br]just click, "Next Video." 0:12:12.177,0:12:15.170 ♪ [music] ♪