♪ [music] ♪
- [Alex] Now that we know
how to find the profit
maximization point,
we're going to show
the amount of profit on the diagram
using the average cost curve.
So as I said in the last lecture,
average cost is the cost
per unit of output.
That is, average cost is
total cost divided by Q.
Now remember also
that total cost can be broken down
into fixed costs plus
variable costs.
So we can also write average cost
in a slightly longer format.
Average cost is equal
to fixed cost divided by Q
plus the variable cost divided
by Q, the units of output.
That's a little bit useful
because we're able to see,
get some intuition, for the shape
of a typical average cost curve.
Notice that the fixed costs
don't change with Q.
That's why they're fixed.
So when Q is small, this number,
suppose fixed cost is a hundred
and Q is small,
then this number is going to be big
like 100 divided by 1.
fixed cost divided Q - is going to get
smaller, so when Q is 10 this number 100
divided by 10 becomes 10. So it goes from
100 and it goes down, down, down, down,
get's lower and lower and lower all the
time as you divide by a bigger
quantity. On the other hand, the variable
costs increase with quantity. Moreover,
what we saw with the marginal cost curve
is that at some point your variable costs
are going to increase faster than
quantity. So what's going to happen is
that this number at some point - variable
cost divided by quantity - is going to get
bigger and bigger and bigger. So you have
two things one force is driving average
cost down. That's going to be
particularly strong at the beginning.
Eventually however, the second force here
is going to drive average cost, uh, up. So
that's going to be our typical shape of an
average cost curve - falling reaches a
minimum and then rising. So let's draw it
like that. Okay here's our typical
marginal cost curve and here is our
marginal revenue curve equal to price. We
know that the profit maximizing point is
where marginal revenue is equal to
marginal cost. Here is our average cost
curve and notice it has the shape, which I
described, it starts off high, it falls,
reaches a minimum, and then goes right back
up again. Couple of other points to notice
is that the minimum point, the marginal
cost curve goes through the minimum point
of the average cost curve. Now that's just
a mathematical fact, but let me give you
some intuition. Instead of cost I want to
talk about average grade and marginal
grade. So suppose that your average grade
is 80%. You're doing really pretty good.
But then on your next test you only get
60% - lower. What is that going to do to
your average? Well, it's going to drive
your average down. Indeed whenever your
marginal is below your average, the average
must be falling. On the other hand,
suppose that you're getting, uh, 80% and on
your next test you get 90%. Great, but what
does that do to your average? It drives your
average up. Indeed whenever your marginal
is above the average, the average must be
rising. Now suppose what happens when
you're getting let's say 80%, and on your
next test you also get 80%. Well then your
marginal is equal to your average grade
and your average grade is flat - it doesn't
change, it's flat. But what is true for
average and marginal grades is also true
for average cost and marginal cost.
Whenever the marginal cost is below the
average, the average is falling. Whenever
the marginal cost is above the average, the
average is rising. And where marginal is
just equal to average, the average is flat.
In other words we are at the minimum point
of the average cost curve. Okay, now I
said we could use the average cost curve
to figure out profit - show profit on the
diagram. We can do that with just a little
bit of rearranging. Remember that profit
is equal to total revenue minus total cost
and total revenue is price times quantity -
P times Q. We also know that average cost
is equal to total cost divided by
quantity. Let's just rearrange that to
tell us that total cost is equal to
average cost times quantity. So just take
this one and multiply both sides by Q.
So, let's now make these substitutions into
our profit equation. If we do that, then
profit is equal to total revenue - price
times quantity - minus total cost - average
cost times quantity. Now let's take Q out
of both parts of this equation and we find
that profit can also be written as price
minus average cost, all of that times
quantity. That's nice because we can find
all of these elements on our diagram.
Here's the price. Here's the average cost
at the profit maximizing quantity. Let's
just show that. There's the price. There's
the average cost at the profit maximizing
quantity. So profit at the profit
maximizing quantity is this green area
right here. Price minus average cost times
quantity. So now we have a nice way of
showing in a diagram exactly how much
profit is. Let's use this tool some more.
Here's another example of the average cost
curve in action. Remember I said that
profit maximization doesn't necessarily
mean the firm is making a positive profit.
Sometimes the best you can do is to
minimize your losses. You may have to take
a loss. For example, suppose that the
price is below $17. That is, here's the market
price, which is equal to the firm's marginal
revenue curve. How does the firm profit
maximize? It chooses the quantity where
marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost.
In that case, this quantity is one. Now
what's the profit for the firm? Well, as
usual we measure profit as price minus
average cost times quantity. But notice
that price is below the average cost at
the profit maximizing quantity of one.
Since price is below average cost, this is
a loss. It's a negative quantity. It is a
loss. In fact, notice that the breakeven
price is $17, which is the minimum of the
average cost curve. In order to make a
profit, the firm at least has to meet the
minimum of it's average cost curve. So at
any price below $17 we'll be profit
maximizing at a point where price is equal
to marginal cost, and notice that all of
these prices are below average cost. So
all of this area down here, even the
profit maximizing quantity, will mean a
loss. On the other hand, once we get above
$17, above the minimum of the average cost
curve, then we can price equal to marginal
cost. We can chose the quantities such the
price is equal to marginal cost. That price
will be above average cost so we'll be
taking a profit. Therefore, $17, the minimum
of the average cost curve, is the
breakeven point.
If the price is less than the minimum of
the average cost curve, we're going to be
taking a loss. If the price is bigger than
the minimum of the average cost curve, then
we can make a profit. So when should a
firm enter or exit an industry? In the
long run, the firms will enter when price
is above average cost. If price is
somewhere above the average cost curve
then the firm can make a profit by
entering and that's what firms want to do.
They want to find profit, so they will
want to enter wherever a profit is
possible. Firms will exit the industry
when the price is below the average cost
curve. Then they're going to be taking a
loss and they're going to want to exit. So
finally, when the price is equal to the
minimum of the average cost - it's just
equal to the bottom of the average cost
curve, profits are zero and there's no
incentive to either exit or enter the
industry. Now you might ask, why would
firms remain in an industry if profits are
zero? Zero profits, this is just a matter
of terminology, means that at the market
price the firm is covering all of its
costs including enough to pay labor and
capital, their ordinary opportunity cost.
So zero profits means everyone
is being paid, enough to make
them satisfied. Zero profits, in other
words, is what normal people mean by normal
profits. So when an economist says zero
profits just substitute normal profits.
One more point about entry and exit. It
doesn't always make sense to exit an
industry immediately when price falls
below average cost. Or to enter immediately
when price is above average cost. Why not?
Well, there are also entry and exit costs.
For example, suppose that that the price
of oil is currently above the average cost
of pumping oil, if you've already got a
well. Should you enter the industry? Well,
maybe not necessarily. Because entry
requires you to drill an oil well, and
drilling an oil well is a sunk cost -
literally in this case.
A sunk cost is a cost that once incurred
can never be recovered. So if you enter
the industry and drill the oil well, you
don't get that money back when you later
exit the industry. What this means is you
don't want to enter unless you expect the
price of oil to stay above the minimum of
the average cost curve long enough so
that you can also recover your entry
costs. So just because the price goes
above the average cost a little bit, you
don't immediately want to jump into that
industry. You have to expect that that
price is going to stay above average cost
long enough for you to recover your entry
costs. For the same reasons, if there are
exit costs, for example, if you have to
shutter up the well or fill the well with
cement when you exit the industry as you
do in the United States, then when price
falls below average cost, it may be best to
weather the storm at least for sometime
before you exit. Only if you expect the
price of oil to stay below your minimum of
average cost for an extended period of
time will you want to exit the industry.
After all, if the price of oil falls below
the average cost just for a little bit, and
then it goes back up, the lifetime
profits can still be possible. So, entry
and exit could be quite complicated
because you've got to be thinking about
the lifetime profits, not just your
immediate profits. However, the bottom
line is pretty simple. Firms seek profits
and they want to avoid losses. As a
result, firms will enter industries when
the price is above the average cost and
they can make a profit, and they will exit
when the price is below the average cost.
Thanks.
- [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,
click, "Practice Questions," or if you're
ready to move on,
just click, "Next Video."
♪ [music] ♪