0:00:01.416,0:00:03.205 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.076,0:00:11.394 - [Alex] Now that we know [br]how to find the profit 0:00:11.394,0:00:13.805 maximization point, [br]we're going to show 0:00:13.805,0:00:18.706 the amount of profit on the diagram [br]using the average cost curve. 0:00:23.516,0:00:25.398 So as I said in the last lecture, 0:00:25.398,0:00:27.928 average cost is the cost [br]per unit of output. 0:00:28.295,0:00:32.792 That is, average cost is[br]total cost divided by Q. 0:00:33.140,0:00:36.041 Now remember also [br]that total cost can be broken down 0:00:36.041,0:00:38.842 into fixed costs plus [br]variable costs. 0:00:39.219,0:00:42.681 So we can also write average cost[br]in a slightly longer format. 0:00:42.681,0:00:45.507 Average cost is equal [br]to fixed cost divided by Q 0:00:45.507,0:00:49.588 plus the variable cost divided [br]by Q, the units of output. 0:00:50.194,0:00:53.702 That's a little bit useful [br]because we're able to see, 0:00:53.702,0:00:57.188 get some intuition, for the shape [br]of a typical average cost curve. 0:00:57.557,0:01:02.324 Notice that the fixed costs [br]don't change with Q. 0:01:02.456,0:01:04.261 That's why they're fixed. 0:01:04.261,0:01:07.312 So when Q is small -- this number, 0:01:07.312,0:01:09.143 suppose fixed cost is 100, 0:01:09.143,0:01:12.292 and Q is small -- then this number [br]is going to be big 0:01:12.292,0:01:14.431 like 100 divided by 1. 0:01:14.981,0:01:17.991 As Q gets larger, however,[br]this number -- 0:01:17.991,0:01:20.412 fixed cost divided by Q -- [br]is going to get smaller, 0:01:20.412,0:01:25.320 So when Q is 10, this number [br]100 divided by 10 becomes 10. 0:01:25.674,0:01:29.099 So it goes from 100,[br]and it goes down, down, down, down, 0:01:29.099,0:01:31.812 get's lower and lower and lower[br]all the time as you divide 0:01:31.812,0:01:33.489 by a bigger quantity. 0:01:33.626,0:01:38.154 On the other hand, the variable [br]costs increase with quantity. 0:01:38.154,0:01:41.774 Moreover, what we saw [br]with the marginal cost curve 0:01:41.774,0:01:44.925 is that at some point,[br]your variable costs are going 0:01:44.925,0:01:47.397 to increase faster than quantity. 0:01:47.397,0:01:50.676 So what's going to happen is [br]that this number at some point -- 0:01:50.676,0:01:52.857 variable cost divided by quantity --[br]is going to get bigger 0:01:52.857,0:01:54.196 and bigger and bigger. 0:01:54.241,0:01:58.824 So you have two things, one force [br]is driving average cost down. 0:01:59.412,0:02:02.365 That's going to be particularly [br]strong at the beginning. 0:02:03.123,0:02:06.784 Eventually, however, [br]the second force here is going 0:02:06.784,0:02:09.404 to drive average cost up. 0:02:09.562,0:02:12.191 So that's going to be our typical [br]shape of an average cost curve -- 0:02:12.191,0:02:14.554 falling, reaches a minimum,[br]and then rising. 0:02:14.666,0:02:16.241 So let's draw it like that. 0:02:16.452,0:02:18.790 Okay, here's our typical[br]marginal cost curve, 0:02:19.082,0:02:22.366 and here is our marginal [br]revenue curve, equal to price. 0:02:22.676,0:02:26.405 We know that the profit maximizing [br]point is where marginal revenue 0:02:26.405,0:02:28.006 is equal to marginal cost. 0:02:28.216,0:02:31.699 Here is our average cost curve,[br]and notice it has the shape 0:02:31.699,0:02:35.157 which I described --[br]it starts off high, it falls, 0:02:35.157,0:02:37.656 reaches a minimum, [br]and then goes right back up again. 0:02:37.815,0:02:42.644 Couple of other points to notice[br]is that the minimum point, 0:02:42.644,0:02:46.396 the marginal cost curve goes [br]through the minimum point 0:02:46.396,0:02:48.415 of the average cost curve. 0:02:48.415,0:02:52.046 Now that's just a mathematical fact, [br]but let me give you some intuition. 0:02:52.046,0:02:54.958 Instead of cost, I want [br]to talk about average grade 0:02:54.958,0:02:56.867 and marginal grade. 0:02:57.143,0:03:01.545 So suppose that your [br]average grade is 80%. 0:03:01.545,0:03:05.034 You're doing really pretty good,[br]but then on your next test 0:03:05.034,0:03:08.165 you only get 60% -- lower. 0:03:08.165,0:03:10.568 What is that going to do [br]to your average? 0:03:10.568,0:03:13.464 Well, it's going to drive [br]your average down. 0:03:13.464,0:03:18.045 Indeed whenever your marginal [br]is below your average, 0:03:18.045,0:03:20.395 the average must be falling. 0:03:20.395,0:03:24.326 On the other hand, suppose [br]that you're getting 80%, 0:03:24.326,0:03:26.944 and on your next test you get 90%. 0:03:26.944,0:03:29.534 Great, but what does [br]that do to your average? 0:03:29.534,0:03:31.948 It drives your average up. 0:03:31.948,0:03:35.846 Indeed whenever your marginal[br]is above the average, 0:03:35.846,0:03:37.776 the average must be rising. 0:03:37.776,0:03:41.486 Now suppose what happens [br]when you're getting let's say 80%, 0:03:41.486,0:03:45.347 and on your next test,[br]you also get 80%. 0:03:45.347,0:03:49.319 Well then your marginal is equal [br]to your average grade, 0:03:49.319,0:03:54.465 and your average grade is flat -- [br]it doesn't change, it's flat. 0:03:54.465,0:03:58.197 But what is true for average [br]and marginal grades is also true 0:03:58.197,0:04:00.666 for average cost and marginal cost. 0:04:00.791,0:04:06.868 Whenever the marginal cost is [br]below the average, 0:04:06.868,0:04:08.698 the average is falling. 0:04:08.698,0:04:11.867 Whenever the marginal cost is [br]above the average, 0:04:11.867,0:04:13.623 the average is rising. 0:04:13.623,0:04:16.857 And where marginal is [br]just equal to average, 0:04:16.857,0:04:18.386 the average is flat. 0:04:18.448,0:04:21.084 In other words, we are [br]at the minimum point 0:04:21.084,0:04:22.966 of the average cost curve. 0:04:23.818,0:04:26.738 Okay, now I said we could use [br]the average cost curve 0:04:26.747,0:04:29.378 to figure out profit -- [br]show profit on the diagram. 0:04:29.477,0:04:32.522 We can do that with just [br]a little bit of rearranging. 0:04:32.522,0:04:35.976 Remember that profit is equal [br]to total revenue minus total cost 0:04:35.976,0:04:39.574 and total revenue is [br]price times quantity -- P times Q. 0:04:39.574,0:04:42.114 We also know [br]that average cost is equal 0:04:42.114,0:04:44.804 to total cost divided by quantity. 0:04:44.804,0:04:48.834 Let's just rearrange that [br]to tell us that total cost is equal 0:04:48.834,0:04:51.293 to average cost times quantity. 0:04:51.293,0:04:54.404 So just take this one [br]and multiply both sides by Q. 0:04:54.783,0:04:59.744 Let's now make these substitutions [br]into our profit equation. 0:04:59.814,0:05:03.896 If we do that, then profit is equal [br]to total revenue -- 0:05:03.896,0:05:06.442 price times quantity --[br]minus total cost -- 0:05:06.442,0:05:08.215 average cost times quantity. 0:05:08.323,0:05:12.285 Now let's take Q out [br]of both parts of this equation, 0:05:12.285,0:05:16.604 and we find that profit [br]can also be written as price 0:05:16.604,0:05:19.982 minus average cost, [br]all of that times quantity. 0:05:20.593,0:05:22.604 That's nice because we can find 0:05:22.604,0:05:26.316 all of these elements [br]on our diagram. 0:05:26.783,0:05:28.336 Here's the price. 0:05:28.336,0:05:32.414 Here's the average cost[br]at the profit maximizing quantity. 0:05:32.874,0:05:35.125 Let's just show that. [br]There's the price. 0:05:35.544,0:05:40.094 There's the average cost [br]at the profit maximizing quantity. 0:05:40.094,0:05:44.144 So profit at the profit [br]maximizing quantity is 0:05:44.144,0:05:47.404 this green area right here -- 0:05:47.742,0:05:52.041 price minus average cost [br]times quantity. 0:05:52.041,0:05:54.696 So now we have a nice way [br]of showing in a diagram 0:05:54.696,0:05:57.237 exactly how much profit is. 0:05:57.746,0:05:59.662 Let's use this tool some more. 0:06:00.291,0:06:03.146 Here's another example [br]of the average cost curve in action. 0:06:03.169,0:06:06.669 Remember, I said that profit [br]maximization doesn't necessarily 0:06:06.669,0:06:09.241 mean the firm is making [br]a positive profit. 0:06:09.539,0:06:12.889 Sometimes the best you can do [br]is to minimize your losses. 0:06:12.889,0:06:14.768 You may have to take a loss. 0:06:14.768,0:06:18.919 For example, suppose [br]that the price is below $17. 0:06:18.919,0:06:22.169 That is, here's the market price, [br]which is equal to the firm's 0:06:22.169,0:06:23.789 marginal revenue curve. 0:06:24.099,0:06:26.133 How does the firm profit maximize? 0:06:26.133,0:06:28.848 It chooses the quantity [br]where marginal revenue is 0:06:28.848,0:06:30.640 equal to marginal cost. 0:06:30.640,0:06:33.172 In that case, this quantity is one. 0:06:33.172,0:06:35.056 Now what's the profit [br]for the firm? 0:06:35.056,0:06:39.971 Well, as usual we measure [br]profit as price minus 0:06:39.971,0:06:42.791 average cost times quantity. 0:06:42.791,0:06:46.820 But notice that price is [br]below the average cost 0:06:46.820,0:06:50.769 at the profit maximizing [br]quantity of one. 0:06:50.769,0:06:55.970 Since price is below average cost, [br]this is a loss. 0:06:55.970,0:06:57.700 It's a negative quantity. 0:06:57.700,0:07:05.877 It is a loss. In fact, notice [br]that the breakeven price is $17, 0:07:05.877,0:07:09.430 which is the minimum [br]of the average cost curve. 0:07:09.430,0:07:14.242 In order to make a profit, [br]the firm at least has to meet 0:07:14.242,0:07:17.430 the minimum of its [br]average cost curve. 0:07:17.430,0:07:21.332 So at any price below $17,[br]we'll be profit maximizing 0:07:21.332,0:07:24.101 at a point where price is equal[br]to marginal cost, 0:07:24.101,0:07:28.711 and notice that all of these [br]prices are below average cost. 0:07:28.711,0:07:30.853 So all of this area down here, 0:07:30.853,0:07:35.738 even the profit maximizing [br]quantity, will mean a loss. 0:07:36.281,0:07:40.929 On the other hand, once we get [br]above $17, above the minimum 0:07:40.929,0:07:45.561 of the average cost curve, then we [br]can price equal to marginal cost. 0:07:45.561,0:07:49.271 We can choose the quantities such [br]the price is equal to marginal cost. 0:07:49.334,0:07:54.055 That price will be above average [br]cost, so we'll be taking a profit. 0:07:54.525,0:07:59.224 Therefore, $17, the minimum[br]of the average cost curve, 0:07:59.224,0:08:01.216 is the breakeven point. 0:08:01.563,0:08:04.027 If the price is less [br]than the minimum 0:08:04.027,0:08:07.277 of the average cost curve, [br]we're going to be taking a loss. 0:08:07.372,0:08:09.344 If the price is bigger [br]than the minimum 0:08:09.344,0:08:12.244 of the average cost curve, [br]then we can make a profit. 0:08:12.982,0:08:15.784 So when should a firm enter [br]or exit an industry? 0:08:15.854,0:08:19.322 In the long run, the firms will [br]enter when price 0:08:19.322,0:08:21.189 is above average cost. 0:08:21.189,0:08:23.989 If price is somewhere [br]above the average cost curve 0:08:23.989,0:08:26.258 then the firm can make [br]a profit by entering, 0:08:26.258,0:08:27.928 and that's what firms want to do. 0:08:27.969,0:08:30.251 They want to find profit, [br]so they will want to enter 0:08:30.251,0:08:32.010 wherever a profit is possible. 0:08:32.010,0:08:35.640 Firms will exit the industry [br]when the price is below 0:08:35.640,0:08:37.229 the average cost curve. 0:08:37.229,0:08:38.550 Then they're going [br]to be taking a loss, 0:08:38.550,0:08:40.269 and they're going to want to exit. 0:08:40.364,0:08:44.171 Finally, when the price is [br]equal to the minimum 0:08:44.228,0:08:46.930 of the average cost --[br]it's just equal to the bottom 0:08:46.930,0:08:49.758 of the average cost curve, [br]profits are zero, 0:08:49.758,0:08:51.277 and there's no incentive 0:08:51.277,0:08:54.029 to either exit [br]or enter the industry. 0:08:54.163,0:08:56.519 Now you might ask, [br]why would firms remain 0:08:56.519,0:08:59.413 in an industry if profits are zero? 0:08:59.413,0:09:03.403 Zero profits, this is just [br]a matter of terminology, 0:09:03.403,0:09:07.013 means that at the market price [br]the firm is covering all 0:09:07.013,0:09:10.871 of its costs, including enough [br]to pay labor and capital, 0:09:10.871,0:09:13.134 their ordinary opportunity cost. 0:09:13.494,0:09:17.652 So zero profits means [br]everyone is being paid 0:09:17.652,0:09:19.573 enough to make them satisfied. 0:09:19.715,0:09:23.514 Zero profits, in other words,[br]is what normal people mean 0:09:23.514,0:09:25.496 by normal profits. 0:09:25.496,0:09:27.708 So when an economist [br]says zero profits 0:09:27.708,0:09:30.084 just substitute normal profits. 0:09:30.344,0:09:32.824 One more point [br]about entry and exit. 0:09:32.974,0:09:36.876 It doesn't always make sense [br]to exit an industry immediately 0:09:36.938,0:09:38.997 when price falls [br]below average cost, 0:09:39.208,0:09:43.127 or to enter immediately [br]when price is above average cost. 0:09:43.247,0:09:47.916 Why not? Well, there are [br]also entry and exit costs. 0:09:48.279,0:09:50.717 For example, suppose [br]that that the price of oil is 0:09:50.717,0:09:55.369 currently above the average [br]cost of pumping oil -- 0:09:55.369,0:09:59.011 if you've already got a well,[br]should you enter the industry? 0:09:59.269,0:10:01.248 Well, maybe not necessarily. 0:10:01.266,0:10:04.776 Because entry requires you [br]to drill an oil well, 0:10:04.776,0:10:09.037 and drilling an oil well is [br]a sunk cost -- literally in this case. 0:10:09.037,0:10:14.438 A sunk cost is a cost that once [br]incurred can never be recovered. 0:10:14.741,0:10:17.849 So if you enter the industry [br]and drill the oil well, 0:10:17.849,0:10:21.548 you don't get that money back [br]when you later exit the industry. 0:10:22.368,0:10:24.930 What this means is you[br]don't want to enter 0:10:24.930,0:10:30.286 unless you expect [br]the price of oil to stay 0:10:30.286,0:10:33.658 above the minimum [br]of the average cost curve 0:10:33.658,0:10:38.828 long enough so that you can [br]also recover your entry costs. 0:10:39.435,0:10:43.530 So just because the price goes[br]above the average cost a little bit, 0:10:43.530,0:10:46.498 you don't immediately [br]want to jump into that industry. 0:10:46.786,0:10:50.040 You have to expect that [br]that price is going to stay 0:10:50.040,0:10:53.958 above average cost [br]long enough for you 0:10:53.958,0:10:56.039 to recover your entry costs. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 For the same reasons, [br]if there are exit costs, 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 for example, if you have [br]to shutter up the well 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 or fill the well with cement [br]when you exit the industry 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 as you do in the United States, [br]then when price falls 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 below average cost, [br]it may be best to weather 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 the storm at least [br]for sometime before you exit. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 Only if you expect the price [br]of oil to stay below your minimum 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 of average cost [br]for an extended period of time 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 will you want to exit the industry. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 After all, if the price of oil falls [br]below the average cost 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 just for a little bit, [br]and then it goes back up, 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 the lifetime profits can [br]still be possible. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 So, entry and exit could be [br]quite complicated 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 because you've got [br]to be thinking 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 about the lifetime profits,[br]not just your immediate profits. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 However, the bottom line[br]is pretty simple. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 Firms seek profits[br]and they want to avoid losses. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 As a result, firms will enter [br]industries when the price is above 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 the average cost[br]and they can make a profit, 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 and they will exit when the price [br]is below the average cost. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 Thanks. 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 - [Narrator] If you want to test [br]yourself, click, "Practice Questions." 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 Or, if you're ready to move on,[br]just click, "Next Video." 9:59:59.000,9:59:59.000 ♪ [music] ♪