0:00:00.000,0:00:03.000 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.170,0:00:13.830 - Now that we know how to find the profit[br]maximization point. We're going to show 0:00:14.010,0:00:18.807 the amount of profit on the diagram using[br]the average cost curve. 0:00:24.150,0:00:28.580 - So as I said in the last lecture average[br]cost is the cost per unit of output. That 0:00:28.760,0:00:35.160 is average cost is total cost divided by[br]Q. Now remember also that total cost can 0:00:35.340,0:00:40.358 be broken down into fixed costs plus[br]variable cost. So we can also write 0:00:40.358,0:00:42.546 average cost in a[br]slightly longer format. 0:00:42.546,0:00:46.400 Average cost is equal to[br]fixed cost divided by Q plus the 0:00:46.440,0:00:52.710 variable cost divided by Q the units of[br]output. That's a little bit useful because 0:00:52.890,0:00:57.660 we're able to see get some intuition for[br]the shape of a typical average cost curve. 0:00:57.840,0:01:05.280 Notice that the fixed costs don't change[br]with Q that's why they're fixed. So when Q 0:01:05.459,0:01:11.140 is small this number, suppose fixed cost[br]is a hundred and Q is small then this 0:01:11.320,0:01:18.080 number is going to be big like 100 divided[br]by 1. As Q gets larger however this number 0:01:18.260,0:01:23.220 fixed cost divided Q is going to get[br]smaller so when Q is 10 this number 100 0:01:23.400,0:01:29.170 divided by 10 becomes 10. So it goes from[br]100 and it goes down, down, down, down 0:01:29.350,0:01:32.340 get's lower, and lower and lower all the[br]time as you divide it a bigger 0:01:32.520,0:01:39.271 quantity. On the other hand, the variable[br]cost increase with quantity. Moreover, 0:01:39.271,0:01:44.259 what we saw with the marginal cost curve[br]is that at some point your variable costs 0:01:44.259,0:01:48.922 are going to increase faster than[br]quantity. So what's going to happen is 0:01:48.922,0:01:52.934 that this number at some point variable[br]cost divided by quantity is going to get 0:01:52.934,0:01:58.291 bigger, and bigger and bigger. So you have[br]two things one force is driving average 0:01:58.291,0:02:03.040 cost down. That's going to be[br]particularly strong at the beginning 0:02:03.220,0:02:09.699 eventually however the second force here[br]is going to drive average cost up. So 0:02:09.880,0:02:13.110 that's going to be our typical shape of an[br]average cost curve falling reaches a 0:02:13.290,0:02:17.640 minimum and then rising so let's draw it[br]like that. Okay here's our typical 0:02:17.820,0:02:22.830 marginal cost curve and here is our[br]marginal revenue curve equal the price. We 0:02:23.010,0:02:27.020 know that the profit maximizing point is[br]where marginal revenue is equal to 0:02:27.200,0:02:31.980 marginal cost. Here is our average cost[br]curve and notice it has the shape, which I 0:02:32.160,0:02:36.850 described, it starts off high, it falls[br]reaches a minimum and then goes right back 0:02:37.030,0:02:43.520 up again. Couple of other points to notice[br]is that the minimum point, the marginal 0:02:43.700,0:02:49.160 cost curve goes through the minimum point[br]of the average cost curve. Now that's just 0:02:49.340,0:02:53.730 a mathematical fact but let me give you[br]some intuition. Instead of cost I want to 0:02:53.910,0:02:59.930 talk about average grade and marginal[br]grade so suppose that your average grade 0:03:00.110,0:03:05.640 is 80%. You're doing really pretty good[br]but then on your next test you only get 0:03:05.820,0:03:11.602 60% lower. What is that going to do to[br]your average? Well, it's going to drive 0:03:11.602,0:03:18.640 your average down. Indeed whenever your[br]marginal is below your average the average 0:03:18.820,0:03:24.730 must be falling. On the other hand,[br]suppose that you're getting 80% and on 0:03:24.910,0:03:30.600 your next test you get 90% great but what[br]is that do to your average? It drives our 0:03:30.780,0:03:36.710 average up. Indeed whenever your marginal[br]is above the average the average must be 0:03:36.890,0:03:42.340 rising. Now suppose what happens when[br]you're getting let's say 80% and on your 0:03:42.520,0:03:49.630 next test you also get 80%. Well then your[br]marginal is equal to your average grade 0:03:49.810,0:03:55.700 and your average grade is flat it doesn't[br]change it's flat but what is true for 0:03:55.880,0:04:01.240 average and marginal grades is also true[br]for average cost and marginal cost. 0:04:01.420,0:04:09.180 Whenever the marginal cost is below the[br]average the average is falling. Whenever 0:04:09.360,0:04:15.090 the marginal cost is above the average the[br]average is rising and where marginal is 0:04:15.270,0:04:21.209 just equal to average the average is flat[br]in other words we are at the minimum point 0:04:21.390,0:04:26.600 of the average cost curve. Okay now I[br]said we could use the average cost curve 0:04:26.780,0:04:30.800 to figure out profit show profit on the[br]diagram. We can do that with just a little 0:04:30.980,0:04:36.400 bit of rearranging. Remember that profit[br]is equal to total revenue minus total cost 0:04:36.580,0:04:41.720 and total revenue is price times quantity[br]P times Q. We also know that average cost 0:04:41.900,0:04:46.830 is equal to total cost divided by[br]quantity. Let's just rearrange that to 0:04:47.010,0:04:51.890 tell us that total cost is equal to[br]average cost times quantity so just take 0:04:52.070,0:04:58.420 this one and multiply both sides by Q.[br]So let's now make these substitutions into 0:04:58.600,0:05:04.320 our profit equation if we do that then[br]profit is equal to total revenue price 0:05:04.500,0:05:10.550 times quantity minus total cost average[br]cost times quantity. Now let's take Q out 0:05:10.730,0:05:16.520 of both parts of this equation and we find[br]that profit can also be written as price 0:05:16.700,0:05:22.810 minus average cost all of that times[br]quantity. That's nice because we can find 0:05:22.990,0:05:30.570 all of these elements on our diagram.[br]Here's the price. Here's the average cost 0:05:30.750,0:05:36.420 at the profit maximizing quantity. Let's[br]just show that. There's the price. There's 0:05:36.600,0:05:42.190 the average cost at the profit maximizing[br]quantity. So profit at the profit 0:05:42.370,0:05:51.110 maximizing quantity is this green area[br]right here. Price minus average cost times 0:05:51.290,0:05:56.260 quantity. So now we have a nice way of[br]showing in a diagram exactly how much 0:05:56.440,0:06:02.090 profit is. Let's use this tool some more.[br]Here's another example of the average cost 0:06:02.270,0:06:06.710 curve in action. Remember I said that[br]profit maximization doesn't necessarily 0:06:06.890,0:06:11.450 mean the firm is making a positive profit.[br]Sometimes the best you can do is to 0:06:11.630,0:06:16.630 minimize your losses. You may have to take[br]a loss. For example, suppose that the 0:06:16.810,0:06:22.720 price is below $17. Here's the market[br]price which is equal to the firms marginal 0:06:22.900,0:06:27.750 revenue curve how does the firm profit[br]maximize? It chooses the quantity where 0:06:27.930,0:06:33.390 marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost[br]in that case this quantity is one. Now 0:06:33.570,0:06:40.000 what's the profit for the firm? Well, as[br]usual we measure profit as price minus 0:06:40.180,0:06:47.910 average cost times quantity but notice[br]that price is below the average cost at 0:06:48.090,0:06:54.980 the profit maximizing quantity of one.[br]Since price is below average cost, this is 0:06:55.160,0:07:03.920 a loss. It is a negative quantity. It is a[br]loss. In fact, notice that the breakeven 0:07:04.100,0:07:10.680 price is $17, which is the minimum of the[br]average cost curve. In order to make a 0:07:10.860,0:07:17.920 profit the firm at least has to meet the[br]minimum of it's average cost curve. So at 0:07:18.100,0:07:23.260 any price below $17 will be profit[br]maximizing at a point where price is equal 0:07:23.440,0:07:29.050 to marginal cost and notice that all of[br]these prices are below average cost. So 0:07:29.230,0:07:35.370 all of this area down here even the[br]profit maximizing quantity will mean a 0:07:35.550,0:07:41.940 loss. On the other hand, once we get above[br]$17, above the minimum of the average cost 0:07:42.120,0:07:47.600 curve then we can price equal to marginal[br]cost. We can chose the quantities such the 0:07:47.780,0:07:52.640 price is equal to marginal cost that price[br]will be above average cost so we'll be 0:07:52.820,0:08:00.360 taking a profit. Therefore $17 the minimum[br]of the average cost curve is the 0:08:00.540,0:08:04.190 breakeven point.[br]If the price is less than the minimum of 0:08:04.370,0:08:08.970 the average cost curve, we're going to be[br]taking a loss if the price is bigger than 0:08:09.150,0:08:13.490 the minimum of the average cost curve then[br]we can make a profit. So when should a 0:08:13.670,0:08:19.370 firm enter or exit an industry? In the[br]long run, the firms will enter when price 0:08:19.550,0:08:23.860 is above average cost. If price is[br]somewhere above the average cost curve 0:08:24.040,0:08:27.850 then the firm can make a profit by[br]entering and that's what firms want to do. 0:08:28.030,0:08:31.340 They want to find profit so they will[br]want to enter wherever a profit is 0:08:31.520,0:08:36.590 possible. Firms will exit the industry[br]when the price is below the average cost 0:08:36.770,0:08:41.460 curve then they're going to be taking a[br]loss and they're going to want to exit. So 0:08:41.640,0:08:45.720 finally when the price is equal to the[br]minimum of the average cost it's just 0:08:45.900,0:08:50.690 equal to the bottom of the average cost[br]curve, profits are zero and there's no 0:08:50.870,0:08:55.690 incentive to either exit or enter the[br]industry. Now you might ask why would 0:08:55.870,0:09:02.380 firms remain in an industry if profits are[br]zero? Zero profits, this is just a matter 0:09:02.560,0:09:07.370 of terminology means that at the market[br]price the firm is covering all of its 0:09:07.550,0:09:13.410 costs including enough to pay labor and[br]capital their ordinary opportunity cost. 0:09:13.590,0:09:18.220 So zero profits means everyone[br]is being payed enough to make 0:09:18.400,0:09:24.510 them satisfied. Zero profits in other[br]words is what normal people mean by normal 0:09:24.690,0:09:30.380 profits. So when an economist says zero[br]profits just substitute normal profits. 0:09:30.560,0:09:35.040 One more point about entry and exit. It[br]doesn't always make sense to exit an 0:09:35.220,0:09:40.890 industry immediately when price falls[br]below average cost or to enter immediately 0:09:41.070,0:09:48.320 when price is above average cost. Why not?[br]Well, there are also entry and exit costs. 0:09:48.500,0:09:53.400 For example, suppose that that the price[br]of oil is currently above the average cost 0:09:53.580,0:09:59.260 of pumping oil if you've already got a[br]well. Should you enter the industry? Well, 0:09:59.440,0:10:05.250 maybe not necessarily because entry[br]requires you to drill an oil well and 0:10:05.430,0:10:08.980 drilling an oil well is a sunk costs[br]literally in this case. 0:10:09.160,0:10:15.780 A sunk costs is a cost that once incurred[br]can never be recovered. So if you enter 0:10:15.960,0:10:20.690 the industry and drill the oil well you[br]don't get that money back when you later 0:10:20.870,0:10:28.160 exit the industry. What this means is you[br]don't want to enter unless you expect the 0:10:28.340,0:10:35.860 price of oil to stay above the minimum of[br]the average cost curve long enough so 0:10:36.040,0:10:41.680 that you can also recover your entry[br]costs. So just because the price goes 0:10:41.860,0:10:45.770 above the average cost a little bit you[br]don't immediately want to jump into that 0:10:45.950,0:10:52.120 industry you have to expect that that[br]price is going to stay above average cost 0:10:52.300,0:10:58.900 long enough for you to recover your entry[br]costs. For the same reasons if there are 0:10:59.080,0:11:03.480 exit cost. For example, if you have to[br]shutter up the well or fill the well with 0:11:03.660,0:11:07.850 cement when you exit the industry as you[br]do in the United States. Then when price 0:11:08.030,0:11:13.460 falls below average cost it may be best to[br]weather the storm at least for sometime 0:11:13.640,0:11:21.060 before you exit. Only if you expect the[br]price of oil to stay below your minimum of 0:11:21.240,0:11:26.550 average cost for an extended period of[br]time will you want to exit the industry. 0:11:26.730,0:11:31.670 After all, if the price of oil falls below[br]the average cost just for a little bit and 0:11:31.850,0:11:37.320 then it goes back up the lifetime[br]profits can still be possible. So entry 0:11:37.500,0:11:40.810 and exit could be quite complicated[br]because you've got to be thinking about 0:11:40.990,0:11:46.943 the lifetime profits not just your[br]immediate profits. However, the bottom 0:11:46.943,0:11:53.113 line is pretty simple. Firms seek profits[br]and they want to avoid losses. As a 0:11:53.113,0:11:57.637 result, firms will enter industries when[br]the price is above the average cost and 0:11:57.637,0:12:02.126 they can make a profit and they will exit[br]when the price is below the average cost. 0:12:02.126,0:12:03.891 Thanks. 0:12:04.420,0:12:09.410 - [narrator] If you want to test yourself,[br]click, "Practice Questions," or if you're 0:12:09.590,0:12:12.177 ready to move on,[br]just click, "Next Video." 0:12:12.177,0:12:15.170 ♪ [music] ♪