1 00:00:01,725 --> 00:00:04,642 Hi. I'm here to talk about congestion, 2 00:00:04,642 --> 00:00:05,996 namely road congestion. 3 00:00:05,996 --> 00:00:08,257 Road congestion is a pervasive phenomenon. 4 00:00:08,257 --> 00:00:11,117 It exists in basically all of the cities all around the world, 5 00:00:11,117 --> 00:00:13,065 which is a little bit surprising when you think about it. 6 00:00:13,065 --> 00:00:16,028 I mean, think about how different cities are, actually. 7 00:00:16,028 --> 00:00:17,790 I mean, you have the typical European cities, 8 00:00:17,790 --> 00:00:20,782 with a dense urban core, good public transportation 9 00:00:20,782 --> 00:00:23,237 mostly, not a lot of road capacity. 10 00:00:23,237 --> 00:00:25,686 But then, on the other hand, you have the American cities. 11 00:00:25,686 --> 00:00:28,477 It's moving by itself, okay. 12 00:00:28,477 --> 00:00:31,483 Anyway, the American cities: 13 00:00:31,483 --> 00:00:34,411 lots of roads dispersed over large areas, 14 00:00:34,411 --> 00:00:35,870 almost no public transportation. 15 00:00:35,870 --> 00:00:38,080 And then you have the emerging world cities, 16 00:00:38,080 --> 00:00:39,606 with a mixed variety of vehicles, 17 00:00:39,606 --> 00:00:42,148 mixed land-use patterns, also rather dispersed 18 00:00:42,148 --> 00:00:44,747 but often with a very dense urban core. 19 00:00:44,747 --> 00:00:47,149 And traffic planners all around the world have tried 20 00:00:47,149 --> 00:00:50,803 lots of different measures: dense cities or dispersed cities, 21 00:00:50,803 --> 00:00:53,354 lots of roads or lots of public transport 22 00:00:53,354 --> 00:00:56,140 or lots of bike lanes or more information, 23 00:00:56,140 --> 00:00:59,934 or lots of different things, but nothing seems to work. 24 00:00:59,934 --> 00:01:02,937 But all of these attempts have one thing in common. 25 00:01:02,937 --> 00:01:05,288 They're basically attempts at figuring out 26 00:01:05,288 --> 00:01:08,615 what people should do instead of rush hour car driving. 27 00:01:08,615 --> 00:01:11,727 They're essentially, to a point, attempts at planning 28 00:01:11,727 --> 00:01:14,929 what other people should do, planning their life for them. 29 00:01:14,929 --> 00:01:17,381 Now, planning a complex social system 30 00:01:17,381 --> 00:01:20,456 is a very hard thing to do, and let me tell you a story. 31 00:01:20,456 --> 00:01:23,183 Back in 1989, when the Berlin Wall fell, 32 00:01:23,183 --> 00:01:25,805 an urban planner in London got a phone call 33 00:01:25,805 --> 00:01:28,355 from a colleague in Moscow saying, basically, 34 00:01:28,355 --> 00:01:30,873 "Hi, this is Vladimir. I'd like to know, 35 00:01:30,873 --> 00:01:33,895 who's in charge of London's bread supply?" 36 00:01:33,895 --> 00:01:35,548 And the urban planner in London goes, 37 00:01:35,548 --> 00:01:37,518 "What do you mean, who's in charge of London's — 38 00:01:37,518 --> 00:01:38,789 I mean, no one is in charge." 39 00:01:38,789 --> 00:01:40,671 "Oh, but surely someone must be in charge. 40 00:01:40,671 --> 00:01:44,327 I mean, it's a very complicated system. Someone must control all of this." 41 00:01:44,327 --> 00:01:47,433 "No. No. No one is in charge. 42 00:01:47,433 --> 00:01:50,034 I mean, it basically -- I haven't really thought of it. 43 00:01:50,034 --> 00:01:52,623 It basically organizes itself." 44 00:01:52,623 --> 00:01:55,200 It organizes itself. 45 00:01:55,200 --> 00:01:58,043 That's an example of a complex social system 46 00:01:58,043 --> 00:02:00,771 which has the ability of self-organizing, 47 00:02:00,771 --> 00:02:03,359 and this is a very deep insight. 48 00:02:03,359 --> 00:02:06,672 When you try to solve really complex social problems, 49 00:02:06,672 --> 00:02:08,388 the right thing to do is most of the time 50 00:02:08,388 --> 00:02:09,979 to create the incentives. 51 00:02:09,979 --> 00:02:11,923 You don't plan the details, 52 00:02:11,923 --> 00:02:14,543 and people will figure out what to do, 53 00:02:14,543 --> 00:02:16,403 how to adapt to this new framework. 54 00:02:16,403 --> 00:02:19,894 And let's now look at how we can use this insight 55 00:02:19,894 --> 00:02:21,530 to combat road congestion. 56 00:02:21,530 --> 00:02:23,762 This is a map of Stockholm, my hometown. 57 00:02:23,762 --> 00:02:27,403 Now, Stockholm is a medium-sized city, roughly two million people, 58 00:02:27,403 --> 00:02:30,192 but Stockholm also has lots of water and lots of water 59 00:02:30,192 --> 00:02:33,469 means lots of bridges -- narrow bridges, old bridges -- 60 00:02:33,469 --> 00:02:36,504 which means lots of road congestion. 61 00:02:36,504 --> 00:02:40,144 And these red dots show the most congested parts, 62 00:02:40,144 --> 00:02:42,721 which are the bridges that lead into the inner city. 63 00:02:42,721 --> 00:02:45,247 And then someone came up with the idea that, 64 00:02:45,247 --> 00:02:47,084 apart from good public transport, 65 00:02:47,084 --> 00:02:49,685 apart from spending money on roads, 66 00:02:49,685 --> 00:02:53,900 let's try to charge drivers one or two euros at these bottlenecks. 67 00:02:53,900 --> 00:02:56,824 Now, one or two euros, that isn't really a lot of money, 68 00:02:56,824 --> 00:02:59,481 I mean compared to parking charges and running costs, etc., 69 00:02:59,481 --> 00:03:02,199 so you would probably expect that car drivers 70 00:03:02,199 --> 00:03:04,637 wouldn't really react to this fairly small charge. 71 00:03:04,637 --> 00:03:05,937 You would be wrong. 72 00:03:05,937 --> 00:03:09,965 One or two euros was enough to make 20 percent of cars 73 00:03:09,965 --> 00:03:12,349 disappear from rush hours. 74 00:03:12,349 --> 00:03:15,900 Now, 20 percent, well, that's a fairly huge figure, you might think, 75 00:03:15,900 --> 00:03:18,107 but you've still got 80 percent left of the problem, right? 76 00:03:18,107 --> 00:03:19,976 Because you still have 80 percent of the traffic. 77 00:03:19,976 --> 00:03:23,243 Now, that's also wrong, because traffic happens to be 78 00:03:23,243 --> 00:03:25,935 a nonlinear phenomenon, meaning that 79 00:03:25,935 --> 00:03:29,076 once you reach above a certain capacity threshold 80 00:03:29,076 --> 00:03:32,244 then congestion starts to increase really, really rapidly. 81 00:03:32,244 --> 00:03:34,704 But fortunately, it also works the other way around. 82 00:03:34,704 --> 00:03:38,035 If you can reduce traffic even somewhat, then congestion 83 00:03:38,035 --> 00:03:41,664 will go down much faster than you might think. 84 00:03:41,664 --> 00:03:44,555 Now, congestion charges were introduced in Stockholm 85 00:03:44,555 --> 00:03:49,159 on January 3, 2006, and the first picture here is a picture 86 00:03:49,159 --> 00:03:53,142 of Stockholm, one of the typical streets, January 2. 87 00:03:53,142 --> 00:03:56,955 The first day with the congestion charges looked like this. 88 00:03:56,955 --> 00:03:59,875 This is what happens when you take away 89 00:03:59,875 --> 00:04:01,940 20 percent of the cars from the streets. 90 00:04:01,940 --> 00:04:04,650 You really reduce congestion quite substantially. 91 00:04:04,650 --> 00:04:08,308 But, well, as I said, I mean, car drivers adapt, right? 92 00:04:08,308 --> 00:04:10,810 So after a while they would all come back because they 93 00:04:10,810 --> 00:04:12,758 have sort of gotten used to charges. 94 00:04:12,758 --> 00:04:16,434 Wrong again. It's now six and a half years ago 95 00:04:16,434 --> 00:04:18,417 since the congestion charges were introduced in Stockholm, 96 00:04:18,417 --> 00:04:22,406 and we basically have the same low traffic levels still. 97 00:04:22,406 --> 00:04:24,677 But you see, there's an interesting gap here in the time series 98 00:04:24,677 --> 00:04:26,140 in 2007. 99 00:04:26,140 --> 00:04:28,529 Well, the thing is that, the congestion charges, 100 00:04:28,529 --> 00:04:31,625 they were introduced first as a trial, so they were introduced 101 00:04:31,625 --> 00:04:35,594 in January and then abolished again at the end of July, 102 00:04:35,594 --> 00:04:38,188 followed by a referendum, and then they were reintroduced 103 00:04:38,188 --> 00:04:42,388 again in 2007, which of course was a wonderful scientific opportunity. 104 00:04:42,388 --> 00:04:46,525 I mean, this was a really fun experiment to start with, 105 00:04:46,525 --> 00:04:48,306 and we actually got to do it twice. 106 00:04:48,306 --> 00:04:50,415 And personally, I would like to do this every once a year or so, 107 00:04:50,415 --> 00:04:51,903 but they won't let me do that. 108 00:04:51,903 --> 00:04:54,088 But it was fun anyway. 109 00:04:54,088 --> 00:04:57,473 So, we followed up. What happened? 110 00:04:57,473 --> 00:05:01,339 This is the last day with the congestion charges, July 31, 111 00:05:01,339 --> 00:05:03,117 and you see the same street but now it's summer, 112 00:05:03,117 --> 00:05:04,861 and summer in Stockholm is a very nice 113 00:05:04,861 --> 00:05:07,111 and light time of the year, 114 00:05:07,111 --> 00:05:09,954 and the first day without the congestion charges 115 00:05:09,954 --> 00:05:11,321 looked like this. 116 00:05:11,321 --> 00:05:13,984 All the cars were back again, and you even have to admire 117 00:05:13,984 --> 00:05:16,894 the car drivers. They adapt so extremely quickly. 118 00:05:16,894 --> 00:05:19,141 The first day they all came back. 119 00:05:19,141 --> 00:05:24,491 And this effect hanged on. So 2007 figures looked like this. 120 00:05:24,491 --> 00:05:26,822 Now these traffic figures are really exciting 121 00:05:26,822 --> 00:05:29,473 and a little bit surprising and very useful to know, 122 00:05:29,473 --> 00:05:32,232 but I would say that the most surprising slide here 123 00:05:32,232 --> 00:05:36,262 I'm going to show you today is not this one. It's this one. 124 00:05:36,262 --> 00:05:39,593 This shows public support for congestion pricing of Stockholm, 125 00:05:39,593 --> 00:05:42,262 and you see that when congestion pricing were introduced 126 00:05:42,262 --> 00:05:46,579 in the beginning of Spring 2006, people were fiercely against it. 127 00:05:46,579 --> 00:05:49,607 Seventy percent of the population didn't want this. 128 00:05:49,607 --> 00:05:51,255 But what happened when the congestion charges 129 00:05:51,255 --> 00:05:54,716 were there is not what you would expect, that people hated it more and more. 130 00:05:54,716 --> 00:05:57,869 No, on the contrary, they changed, up to a point 131 00:05:57,869 --> 00:06:01,570 where we now have 70 percent support for keeping the charges, 132 00:06:01,570 --> 00:06:03,411 meaning that -- I mean, let me repeat that: 133 00:06:03,411 --> 00:06:06,218 70 percent of the population in Stockholm 134 00:06:06,218 --> 00:06:10,211 want to keep a price for something that used to be free. 135 00:06:10,211 --> 00:06:13,837 Okay. So why can that be? Why is that? 136 00:06:13,837 --> 00:06:16,837 Well, think about it this way. Who changed? 137 00:06:16,837 --> 00:06:19,463 I mean, the 20 percent of the car drivers that disappeared, 138 00:06:19,463 --> 00:06:21,408 surely they must be discontent in a way. 139 00:06:21,408 --> 00:06:23,742 And where did they go? If we can understand this, 140 00:06:23,742 --> 00:06:27,872 then maybe we can figure out how people can be so happy with this. 141 00:06:27,872 --> 00:06:30,274 Well, so we did this huge interview survey 142 00:06:30,274 --> 00:06:32,109 with lots of travel services, and tried to figure out 143 00:06:32,109 --> 00:06:33,864 who changed, and where did they go? 144 00:06:33,864 --> 00:06:38,278 And it turned out that they don't know themselves. (Laughter) 145 00:06:38,278 --> 00:06:43,126 For some reason, the car drivers are -- 146 00:06:43,126 --> 00:06:46,622 they are confident they actually drive the same way that they used to do. 147 00:06:46,622 --> 00:06:48,878 And why is that? It's because that travel patterns 148 00:06:48,878 --> 00:06:51,277 are much less stable than you might think. 149 00:06:51,277 --> 00:06:54,108 Each day, people make new decisions, and people change 150 00:06:54,108 --> 00:06:56,533 and the world changes around them, and each day 151 00:06:56,533 --> 00:06:59,786 all of these decisions are sort of nudged ever so slightly 152 00:06:59,786 --> 00:07:01,753 away from rush hour car driving 153 00:07:01,753 --> 00:07:04,337 in a way that people don't even notice. 154 00:07:04,337 --> 00:07:06,382 They're not even aware of this themselves. 155 00:07:06,382 --> 00:07:09,183 And the other question, who changed their mind? 156 00:07:09,183 --> 00:07:11,149 Who changed their opinion, and why? 157 00:07:11,149 --> 00:07:13,675 So we did another interview survey, tried to figure out 158 00:07:13,675 --> 00:07:18,051 why people changed their mind, and what type of group changed their minds? 159 00:07:18,051 --> 00:07:20,944 And after analyzing the answers, it turned out that 160 00:07:20,944 --> 00:07:24,829 more than half of them believe that they haven't changed their minds. 161 00:07:24,829 --> 00:07:27,116 They're actually confident that they have 162 00:07:27,116 --> 00:07:29,805 liked congestion pricing all along. 163 00:07:29,805 --> 00:07:31,524 Which means that we are now in a position 164 00:07:31,524 --> 00:07:34,517 where we have reduced traffic across this toll cordon 165 00:07:34,517 --> 00:07:37,728 with 20 percent, and reduced congestion by enormous numbers, 166 00:07:37,728 --> 00:07:41,275 and people aren't even aware that they have changed, 167 00:07:41,275 --> 00:07:45,186 and they honestly believe that they have liked this all along. 168 00:07:45,186 --> 00:07:48,660 This is the power of nudges when trying to solve 169 00:07:48,660 --> 00:07:51,292 complex social problems, and when you do that, 170 00:07:51,292 --> 00:07:54,922 you shouldn't try to tell people how to adapt. 171 00:07:54,922 --> 00:07:57,109 You should just nudge them in the right direction. 172 00:07:57,109 --> 00:07:58,831 And if you do it right, 173 00:07:58,831 --> 00:08:00,883 people will actually embrace the change, 174 00:08:00,883 --> 00:08:03,945 and if you do it right, people will actually even like it. 175 00:08:03,945 --> 00:08:07,270 Thank you. (Applause)