0:00:00.000,0:00:05.362 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.472,0:00:11.543 - [Tyler] Today we begin[br]the first of several talks 0:00:11.543,0:00:13.408 on taxes and subsidies. 0:00:13.408,0:00:15.572 We're not going to be talking[br]about income taxes 0:00:15.572,0:00:17.077 and income subsidies. 0:00:17.077,0:00:19.942 Those are typically topics[br]for macroeconomics. 0:00:19.942,0:00:23.626 Instead, we'll be talking[br]about taxes and subsidies on goods, 0:00:23.626,0:00:26.469 like a sales tax[br]or a subsidy for wheat. 0:00:26.469,0:00:30.187 These are also called[br]commodity taxes and subsidies. 0:00:30.187,0:00:31.651 So let's get going. 0:00:35.748,0:00:38.072 We're going to be emphasizing[br]three important ideas 0:00:38.072,0:00:39.989 about commodity taxation. 0:00:39.989,0:00:42.650 First, who pays the tax[br]does not depend 0:00:42.650,0:00:45.439 on who writes the check[br]to the government. 0:00:45.439,0:00:48.635 For example, suppose the government[br]is taxing apples. 0:00:48.680,0:00:50.965 The government could make[br]the buyer of apples 0:00:50.965,0:00:53.139 pay for each apple that they buy. 0:00:53.139,0:00:56.601 Or they could require the sellers[br]of the apples pay for each apple 0:00:56.601,0:00:58.200 that they sell. 0:00:58.207,0:01:00.773 What we're going to show is that,[br]from the point of view 0:01:00.773,0:01:03.774 of the buyers or sellers,[br]it actually doesn't matter 0:01:03.774,0:01:05.474 how the tax is placed. 0:01:05.474,0:01:08.380 The actual outcomes[br]are going to be identical. 0:01:08.445,0:01:11.686 Another way of putting this[br]is that the economic incidence 0:01:11.686,0:01:15.356 of the tax, who actually pays[br]the tax, does not depend 0:01:15.356,0:01:18.831 on the legal incidence,[br]who is in law required to write 0:01:18.831,0:01:20.435 the check to the government. 0:01:20.435,0:01:23.164 This will become a little bit[br]clearer as we go along. 0:01:23.164,0:01:25.692 Don't worry about it[br]if it's not clear yet. 0:01:25.884,0:01:28.625 The second key point,[br]who pays the tax 0:01:28.625,0:01:32.731 does depend on the relative[br]elasticities of demand and supply. 0:01:33.323,0:01:36.780 In fact, we can summarize[br]point one and point two by saying, 0:01:36.780,0:01:40.715 who pays the tax depends not[br]on the laws of congress 0:01:40.715,0:01:43.561 but rather on the laws[br]of supply and demand. 0:01:44.442,0:01:46.708 The third point[br]is that commodity taxation 0:01:46.708,0:01:49.341 raises revenue,[br]but it also takes away 0:01:49.341,0:01:53.144 some gains from trade, that is,[br]it creates deadweight loss. 0:01:53.379,0:01:55.808 We're going to be looking[br]at point one in this talk, 0:01:55.808,0:01:58.016 and then we'll move on[br]to point two, and point three 0:01:58.016,0:01:59.213 in later talks. 0:01:59.213,0:02:00.964 So, let's start with point one. 0:02:01.260,0:02:04.481 Let's begin our analysis[br]of commodity taxation 0:02:04.481,0:02:07.458 by assuming the suppliers[br]are the one who have to send 0:02:07.458,0:02:08.876 the check to the government. 0:02:08.876,0:02:12.478 That is, the legal incidence[br]of the tax falls on the suppliers. 0:02:13.267,0:02:15.704 What does a tax[br]on the suppliers do? 0:02:15.704,0:02:17.901 We can think about a tax[br]on suppliers 0:02:17.901,0:02:19.960 as increasing their costs. 0:02:19.960,0:02:22.562 This is going to shift[br]the supply curve up 0:02:22.562,0:02:25.305 by the amount of the tax,[br]so the supply curve 0:02:25.305,0:02:26.864 shifts up like this. 0:02:27.629,0:02:30.114 Another way of thinking[br]about this, is to remember 0:02:30.114,0:02:33.243 that the supply curve tells us[br]the minimum amount 0:02:33.243,0:02:36.464 which suppliers require to offer[br]a given quantity 0:02:36.464,0:02:38.078 in the marketplace. 0:02:38.078,0:02:42.373 The tax, that is going to increase[br]the minimum amount that suppliers 0:02:42.373,0:02:45.742 are requiring to offer[br]that quantity in the marketplace. 0:02:46.494,0:02:50.181 It shifts up that minimum amount[br]required by just the amount 0:02:50.181,0:02:51.445 of the tax. 0:02:52.025,0:02:55.015 With the new supply curve[br]we find the new equilibrium. 0:02:55.181,0:02:58.311 The market equilibrium[br]moves from point A to point B. 0:02:58.864,0:03:02.220 What we see is that of course,[br]the quantity which is exchanged 0:03:02.220,0:03:04.695 goes down, in addition,[br]the price paid 0:03:04.695,0:03:06.743 by the buyers goes up. 0:03:06.777,0:03:08.839 How much do the suppliers get? 0:03:08.839,0:03:12.658 The suppliers collect this amount,[br]the price paid by the buyers, 0:03:12.658,0:03:14.971 but now they have to give[br]a certain amount of that, 0:03:14.971,0:03:16.942 the tax to the government. 0:03:16.942,0:03:21.069 The suppliers end up receiving[br]this amount after tax, right here. 0:03:21.605,0:03:24.861 In other words, what the tax does,[br]it means that the buyers 0:03:24.861,0:03:27.487 pay more than before,[br]and the sellers receive 0:03:27.487,0:03:29.221 less than before. 0:03:29.221,0:03:32.191 Without any tax,[br]the price the buyers pay 0:03:32.191,0:03:35.109 is the same as the price[br]the supplier receives. 0:03:35.221,0:03:38.082 With the tax,[br]the buyers pay a certain price, 0:03:38.082,0:03:40.137 but the sellers get less than that. 0:03:40.137,0:03:43.563 They get whatever the buyers pay[br]minus of course, the tax. 0:03:44.065,0:03:46.866 That's the situation[br]when the suppliers pay the tax, 0:03:46.866,0:03:50.028 or the suppliers have to send[br]the check to the government. 0:03:50.028,0:03:52.632 Let's now look at what happens[br]when it's the buyers 0:03:52.632,0:03:54.602 who must send the check[br]to the government. 0:03:55.577,0:03:58.141 Now, we look at the situation[br]when the legal incidence 0:03:58.141,0:03:59.712 is on the buyers. 0:03:59.712,0:04:03.616 We begin just as before[br]with the equilibrium with no taxes. 0:04:03.616,0:04:05.777 No taxes on sellers or buyers. 0:04:05.777,0:04:08.323 Again, that equilibrium[br]is at point A. 0:04:08.323,0:04:10.767 I've also included[br]this supply curve here. 0:04:10.767,0:04:14.074 This is the supply curve[br]when the tax is on the suppliers. 0:04:14.074,0:04:16.719 It's the supply curve[br]from the previous problem. 0:04:16.719,0:04:18.809 It's not relevant for this problem. 0:04:18.809,0:04:21.502 I've included it rather[br]to remind us of where 0:04:21.502,0:04:24.259 the equilibrium[br]on the previous problem was. 0:04:24.259,0:04:27.598 You can think of this[br]as a kind of ghost supply curve. 0:04:27.598,0:04:30.310 It's a supply curve[br]from the previous problem 0:04:30.310,0:04:32.245 coming back to haunt us. 0:04:32.245,0:04:35.211 So what's the effect[br]of a tax on the demanders? 0:04:35.211,0:04:37.016 Think about it this way. 0:04:37.016,0:04:40.645 Suppose the most you were willing[br]to pay for an apple is $1. 0:04:40.645,0:04:44.066 Again, most you're willing to pay[br]for that apple, a dollar, no more. 0:04:44.066,0:04:46.743 Now, suppose you learned[br]that the government has instituted 0:04:46.743,0:04:48.197 a new tax. 0:04:48.197,0:04:51.596 For every apple you buy,[br]you must now pay 25 cents 0:04:51.596,0:04:52.763 to the government. 0:04:52.763,0:04:54.380 Now, how much[br]are you willing to pay 0:04:54.380,0:04:56.821 to suppliers for that apple? 0:04:56.821,0:04:59.680 You're only willing to pay[br]the maximum amount 0:04:59.680,0:05:01.798 that you're going to be willing[br]to pay suppliers 0:05:01.798,0:05:04.137 is now 75 cents. 0:05:04.226,0:05:06.942 The maximum amount[br]that apple was worth to you 0:05:06.942,0:05:07.902 is a dollar. 0:05:07.902,0:05:10.320 If you know you're going[br]to be taxed 25 cents 0:05:10.320,0:05:11.702 if you buy that apple, 0:05:11.702,0:05:13.870 then the most you're going[br]to be willing to pay the supplier 0:05:13.870,0:05:18.617 is 75 cents, because 75 cents[br]plus the 25 cent tax 0:05:18.617,0:05:21.144 to the government, that's $1. 0:05:21.144,0:05:23.556 That's the most you're willing[br]to pay to get the apple. 0:05:23.556,0:05:26.063 In other words, what a tax[br]on demanders does 0:05:26.063,0:05:28.160 is it reduces[br]their willingness to pay, 0:05:28.160,0:05:30.734 and that means[br]the demand curve shifts. 0:05:30.734,0:05:34.344 Which way? The demand curve shifts[br]down by the amount of the tax. 0:05:35.108,0:05:36.522 So let's shift. 0:05:36.522,0:05:39.830 The tax is exactly[br]the same amount that it was before. 0:05:39.830,0:05:43.280 Let's shift the demand curve[br]down by the amount of the tax. 0:05:43.924,0:05:45.681 We find now[br]that the new equilibrium 0:05:45.681,0:05:47.187 is at point B. 0:05:47.187,0:05:50.165 Notice first of all,[br]that the quantity has declined. 0:05:50.165,0:05:54.066 The quantity exchange has declined[br]by exactly the same amount 0:05:54.066,0:05:56.398 as before in the previous problem. 0:05:57.305,0:05:59.812 What about the price[br]received by the sellers? 0:05:59.812,0:06:02.076 The sellers now receive this price. 0:06:02.076,0:06:05.275 Lo and behold,[br]that's exactly the same price 0:06:05.275,0:06:06.587 as it was before. 0:06:07.364,0:06:09.576 How about the price[br]paid by the buyers? 0:06:09.576,0:06:12.530 The buyers now pay[br]what they paid to the suppliers, 0:06:12.530,0:06:15.314 plus they must pay the tax[br]to the government. 0:06:15.314,0:06:17.415 This distance is the tax. 0:06:17.415,0:06:20.940 Lo and behold, the price after tax[br]paid by the buyers 0:06:20.940,0:06:23.633 is once again exactly[br]what it was when the tax 0:06:23.633,0:06:25.567 was on the suppliers. 0:06:26.279,0:06:29.833 When the tax is on the buyers,[br]the buyers pay more than before. 0:06:29.833,0:06:32.165 The sellers receive less[br]than before 0:06:32.165,0:06:34.123 by exactly the same amounts. 0:06:34.123,0:06:36.878 The quantity declines[br]by the same amount, too. 0:06:37.929,0:06:40.066 The net price,[br]or the total price paid 0:06:40.066,0:06:42.216 by the buyers is the same. 0:06:42.216,0:06:45.451 The total price received[br]by the sellers is the same. 0:06:45.930,0:06:48.553 Now that you know the idea,[br]I'm going to show you a simpler way 0:06:48.553,0:06:50.176 of demonstrating this. 0:06:50.208,0:06:52.619 What we just showed[br]is that it doesn't matter 0:06:52.619,0:06:54.558 whether the suppliers[br]must write the check 0:06:54.558,0:06:57.148 to the government, or the demanders[br]must write the check 0:06:57.148,0:06:59.813 to the government[br]in order to pay the tax. 0:06:59.850,0:07:02.114 In other words,[br]we can analyze the tax 0:07:02.114,0:07:04.557 by shifting the supply curve up,[br]or by shifting 0:07:04.557,0:07:06.389 the demand curve down. 0:07:06.971,0:07:09.547 As long as we analyze[br]the same size tax, 0:07:09.547,0:07:11.963 we're going to get[br]equivalent outcomes. 0:07:11.963,0:07:15.446 It's going to come out the same[br]whichever choice of tax we make. 0:07:16.061,0:07:18.284 There's actually a simpler way[br]of thinking about this. 0:07:19.112,0:07:21.271 What we can think[br]about such a tax is doing, 0:07:21.271,0:07:23.931 is driving a wedge[br]between what the buyer is paying 0:07:23.931,0:07:25.761 and what the sellers receive. 0:07:25.761,0:07:27.771 When there's no tax,[br]what the buyers pay 0:07:27.771,0:07:31.073 is what the sellers receive,[br]but when there's a tax, 0:07:31.073,0:07:33.921 the buyers pay more[br]than what the sellers receive. 0:07:33.921,0:07:35.920 The difference[br]is what the government gets. 0:07:35.920,0:07:38.238 The difference[br]is the amount of the tax. 0:07:38.339,0:07:40.756 So let's think about this[br]as a tax wedge. 0:07:41.225,0:07:44.979 Let's say this tax wedge,[br]this side is, let's say a dollar. 0:07:45.120,0:07:48.143 Another way of analyzing[br]the tax is to drive this wedge 0:07:48.143,0:07:50.887 into the diagram[br]until the top of the wedge 0:07:50.887,0:07:53.363 hits the demand curve,[br]and the bottom of the wedge 0:07:53.363,0:07:55.373 just touches the supply curve. 0:07:55.421,0:07:56.774 Let's take a look. 0:07:56.795,0:07:58.575 I'm going to drive the wedge in. 0:07:58.575,0:08:00.887 What this tells us[br]is that the price the buyer pays 0:08:00.887,0:08:03.008 will be here, point B. 0:08:03.008,0:08:06.337 The price the suppliers receive[br]will be point D. 0:08:06.337,0:08:08.294 The difference is the tax. 0:08:08.294,0:08:11.946 For instance, if the buyers[br]end up paying $2.65, 0:08:11.946,0:08:16.138 then the sellers must receive $1.65[br]if the tax is a dollar. 0:08:16.844,0:08:21.977 Similarly, if the suppliers receive[br]a $1.65 and the tax is a dollar, 0:08:21.977,0:08:24.998 the buyers must be paying $2.65. 0:08:24.998,0:08:27.905 With this wedge, we could read[br]off the diagram 0:08:27.905,0:08:31.388 the price the buyer pays,[br]the price the seller receives, 0:08:31.388,0:08:33.154 and the quantity exchanged. 0:08:33.193,0:08:35.382 We don't even have[br]to shift any curves. 0:08:35.382,0:08:37.971 We just drive the wedge[br]into this diagram. 0:08:38.582,0:08:40.297 Let's do an application. 0:08:40.340,0:08:41.828 In the United States, 0:08:41.828,0:08:45.109 under the Federal Insurance[br]Contributions Act -- FICA -- 0:08:45.109,0:08:49.163 12.4% of earned income[br]up to an annual limit 0:08:49.163,0:08:54.640 must be paid into social security,[br]and 2.9%, an additional 2.9% 0:08:54.640,0:08:57.073 must be paid into Medicare. 0:08:57.073,0:09:00.059 Half of this amount comes directly[br]from the employee. 0:09:00.059,0:09:02.484 You can see it[br]on your own paychecks. 0:09:02.484,0:09:05.340 This is the FICA tax,[br]and half the amount comes 0:09:05.340,0:09:06.870 from the employer. 0:09:06.870,0:09:10.393 The question is, does the fact[br]that it's a 50/50 split, 0:09:10.393,0:09:12.574 does this make a difference? 0:09:12.602,0:09:15.388 Does this mean for example,[br]that since the employer 0:09:15.388,0:09:20.044 is paying half that this is necessarily[br]a good deal for the employee? 0:09:20.082,0:09:22.059 No, it doesn't mean that. 0:09:22.059,0:09:25.816 What we now know[br]is that we could have 100% 0:09:25.816,0:09:29.954 of this tax paid by the employee,[br]or we could have 100% 0:09:29.954,0:09:32.397 of this tax paid by the employer. 0:09:32.397,0:09:35.566 This wouldn't make a difference,[br]not to wages, not to prices, 0:09:35.566,0:09:37.198 not to anything. 0:09:37.198,0:09:39.922 It would change[br]the legal incidence of the tax, 0:09:39.922,0:09:43.265 but it would not change[br]the final economic incidence. 0:09:44.021,0:09:46.946 I haven't said here[br]who actually pays the tax. 0:09:46.946,0:09:48.594 That's what we're going[br]to be talking about 0:09:48.594,0:09:49.929 in the next lecture. 0:09:49.929,0:09:52.336 What I've said here[br]is that it doesn't matter 0:09:52.336,0:09:55.190 who pays the tax[br]from a legal point-of-view 0:09:55.190,0:09:57.460 of who is obliged[br]to deliver that money. 0:09:57.460,0:10:00.380 So the legal incidence again,[br]does not have a bearing 0:10:00.380,0:10:02.684 on the economic incidence[br]of the tax. 0:10:03.507,0:10:05.517 What we're going to talk[br]about in the next lecture 0:10:05.517,0:10:09.060 is what does determine[br]the economic incidence of a tax. 0:10:09.528,0:10:12.934 It turns out to be elasticities[br]of supply and demand, 0:10:12.934,0:10:15.600 and that's what we'll take up[br]in the next lecture. 0:10:15.730,0:10:17.454 Thanks again for listening. 0:10:18.517,0:10:20.184 - [Narrator] If you want[br]to test yourself, 0:10:20.184,0:10:22.389 click "Practice Questions." 0:10:22.389,0:10:25.720 Or if you're ready to move on,[br]just click "Next Video." 0:10:25.720,0:10:30.798 ♪ [music] ♪