1 00:00:01,854 --> 00:00:03,863 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:08,160 --> 00:00:13,130 - [Tyler] Today we begin the first of several talks on taxes and subsidies. 3 00:00:13,310 --> 00:00:17,070 We're not going to be talking about income taxes and income subsidies. Those are 4 00:00:17,250 --> 00:00:21,850 typically topics for macroeconomics. Instead, we'll be talking about taxes and 5 00:00:22,030 --> 00:00:27,430 subsidies on goods, like a sales tax or a subsidy for wheat. These are also called 6 00:00:27,610 --> 00:00:31,585 commodity taxes and subsidies. So let's get going. 7 00:00:35,513 --> 00:00:36,800 We're going to be emphasizing 8 00:00:36,840 --> 00:00:42,150 three important ideas about commodity taxation. First, who pays the tax does not 9 00:00:42,330 --> 00:00:46,810 depend on who writes the check to the government. For example, suppose the 10 00:00:46,990 --> 00:00:50,950 government is taxing apples. The government could make the buyer of apples 11 00:00:51,130 --> 00:00:55,390 pay for each apple that they buy. Or they could require the sellers of the apples 12 00:00:55,570 --> 00:01:00,080 pay for each apple that they sell. What we're going to show is that, from the 13 00:01:00,260 --> 00:01:04,319 point of view of the buyers or sellers, it actually doesn't matter how the tax is 14 00:01:04,500 --> 00:01:10,060 placed. The actual outcomes are going to be identical. Another way of putting this 15 00:01:10,240 --> 00:01:15,320 is that the economic incidence of the tax, who actually pays the tax, does not depend 16 00:01:15,500 --> 00:01:19,250 on the legal incidence, who is in law required to write the check to the 17 00:01:19,430 --> 00:01:23,680 government. This will become a little bit clearer as we go along. Don't worry about 18 00:01:23,860 --> 00:01:29,700 it if it's not clear yet. The second key point, who pays the tax does depend on the 19 00:01:29,880 --> 00:01:34,740 relative elasticities of demand and supply. In fact, we can summarize point 20 00:01:34,920 --> 00:01:40,500 one and point two by saying, who pays the tax depends not on the laws of congress 21 00:01:40,680 --> 00:01:45,810 but rather on the laws of supply and demand. The third point is that commodity 22 00:01:45,990 --> 00:01:51,160 taxation raises revenue, but it also takes away some gains from trade, that is, it 23 00:01:51,340 --> 00:01:55,560 creates deadweight loss. We're going to be looking at point one in this talk, and 24 00:01:55,740 --> 00:01:59,590 then we'll move on to point two, and point three in later talks. So, let's start with 25 00:01:59,770 --> 00:02:03,360 point one. Let's begin our analysis of commodity 26 00:02:03,540 --> 00:02:07,870 taxation by assuming the suppliers are the one who have to send the check to the 27 00:02:08,050 --> 00:02:13,320 government. That is the legal incidence of the tax falls on the suppliers. What does 28 00:02:13,500 --> 00:02:18,530 a tax on the suppliers do? We can think about a tax on suppliers as increasing 29 00:02:18,710 --> 00:02:23,880 their costs. This is going to shift the supply curve up by the amount of the tax, 30 00:02:24,060 --> 00:02:29,440 so the supply curve shifts up like this. Another way of thinking about this, is to 31 00:02:29,620 --> 00:02:34,550 remember that the supply curve tells us the minimum amount which suppliers require 32 00:02:34,730 --> 00:02:39,730 to offer a given quantity in the marketplace. The tax, that is going to 33 00:02:39,910 --> 00:02:44,620 increase the minimum amount that suppliers are requiring to offer that quantity in 34 00:02:44,800 --> 00:02:50,440 the marketplace. It shifts up that minimum amount required by just the amount of the 35 00:02:50,620 --> 00:02:56,330 tax. With the new supply curve we find the new equilibrium. The market equilibrium 36 00:02:56,510 --> 00:03:01,260 moves from point A to point B. What we see is that of course, the quantity which is 37 00:03:01,440 --> 00:03:07,070 exchanged goes down, in addition, the price paid by the buyers goes up. How much 38 00:03:07,250 --> 00:03:11,680 do the suppliers get? The suppliers collect this amount, the price paid by the 39 00:03:11,860 --> 00:03:15,460 buyers, but now they have to give a certain amount of that, the tax to the 40 00:03:15,640 --> 00:03:21,460 government. The suppliers end up receiving this amount after tax, right here. In 41 00:03:21,640 --> 00:03:26,160 other words, what the tax does, it means that the buyers pay more than before, and 42 00:03:26,340 --> 00:03:32,200 the sellers receive less than before. Without any tax, the price the buyers pay 43 00:03:32,380 --> 00:03:37,050 is the same as the price the supplier receives. With the tax the buyers pay a 44 00:03:37,230 --> 00:03:41,220 certain price, but the sellers get less than that. They get whatever the buyers 45 00:03:41,400 --> 00:03:46,570 pay minus of course, the tax. That's the situation when the suppliers pay the tax, 46 00:03:46,750 --> 00:03:50,700 or the suppliers have to send the check to the government. Let's now look at what 47 00:03:50,880 --> 00:03:55,870 happens when it's the buyers who must send the check to the government. Now, we look 48 00:03:56,050 --> 00:04:01,170 at the situation when the legal incidence is on the buyers. We begin just as before 49 00:04:01,350 --> 00:04:06,030 with the equilibrium with no taxes. No taxes on sellers or buyers. Again, that 50 00:04:06,210 --> 00:04:10,890 equilibrium is at point A. I've also included this supply curve here. This is 51 00:04:11,070 --> 00:04:15,150 the supply curve when the tax is on the suppliers. It's the supply curve from the 52 00:04:15,330 --> 00:04:20,070 previous problem. It's not relevant for this problem. I've included it rather to 53 00:04:20,250 --> 00:04:24,950 remind us of where the equilibrium on the previous problem was. You can think of 54 00:04:25,130 --> 00:04:30,120 this as a kind of ghost supply curve. It's a supply curve from the previous problem 55 00:04:30,300 --> 00:04:35,320 coming back to haunt us. So what's the effect of a tax on the demanders? Think 56 00:04:35,500 --> 00:04:39,560 about it this way. Suppose the most you were willing to pay for an apple is one 57 00:04:39,740 --> 00:04:44,260 dollar. Again, most you're willing to pay for that apple, a dollar, no more. Now, 58 00:04:44,440 --> 00:04:49,200 suppose you learned that the government has instituted a new tax. For every apple 59 00:04:49,380 --> 00:04:53,790 you buy, you must now pay 25 cents to the government. Now, how much are you willing 60 00:04:53,970 --> 00:04:59,060 to pay to suppliers for that apple? You're only willing to pay the maximum 61 00:04:59,240 --> 00:05:04,750 amount that you're going to be willing to pay suppliers is now 75 cents. The maximum 62 00:05:04,930 --> 00:05:08,680 amount that apple was worth to you is a dollar. If you know you're going to be 63 00:05:08,860 --> 00:05:13,100 taxed 25 cents if you buy that apple, then the most you're going to be willing to pay 64 00:05:13,280 --> 00:05:19,430 the supplier is 75 cents, because 75 cents plus the 25 cent tax to the government, 65 00:05:19,610 --> 00:05:23,580 that's one dollar. That's the most you're willing to pay to get the apple. In other 66 00:05:23,760 --> 00:05:28,540 words, what a tax on demanders does is it reduces their willingness to pay, and that 67 00:05:28,720 --> 00:05:33,520 means the demand curve shifts. Which way? The demand curve shifts down by the amount 68 00:05:33,700 --> 00:05:39,680 of the tax. So let's shift. The tax is exactly the same amount that was before. 69 00:05:39,860 --> 00:05:44,590 Let's shift the demand curve down by the amount of the tax. We find now that the 70 00:05:44,770 --> 00:05:49,010 new equilibrium is at point B. Notice first of all, that the quantity has 71 00:05:49,190 --> 00:05:54,000 declined. The quantity exchange has declined by exactly the same amount as 72 00:05:54,180 --> 00:05:59,800 before in the previous problem. What about the price received by the sellers? The 73 00:05:59,980 --> 00:06:04,550 sellers now receive this price. Low and behold, that's exactly the same 74 00:06:04,730 --> 00:06:10,250 price as it was before. How about the price paid by the buyers? The buyers now 75 00:06:10,430 --> 00:06:15,120 pay what they paid to the suppliers, plus they must pay the tax to the government. 76 00:06:15,300 --> 00:06:21,100 This distance is the tax. Low and behold, the price after tax paid by the buyers is 77 00:06:21,280 --> 00:06:26,760 once again exactly what it was when the tax was on the suppliers. When the tax is 78 00:06:26,940 --> 00:06:31,100 on the buyers, the buyers pay more than before. The sellers receive less than 79 00:06:31,280 --> 00:06:37,690 before by exactly the same amounts. The quantity declines by the same amount, too. 80 00:06:37,870 --> 00:06:42,950 The net price, or the total price paid by the buyers is the same. The total price 81 00:06:43,130 --> 00:06:47,530 received by the sellers is the same. Now that you know the idea, I'm going to show 82 00:06:47,710 --> 00:06:51,760 you a simpler way of demonstrating this. What we just showed is that it doesn't 83 00:06:51,940 --> 00:06:55,600 matter whether the suppliers must write the check to the government or the 84 00:06:55,780 --> 00:07:00,030 demanders must write the check to the government in order to pay the tax. In 85 00:07:00,210 --> 00:07:04,110 other words, we can analyze the tax by shifting the supply curve up, or by 86 00:07:04,290 --> 00:07:09,970 shifting the demand curve down. As long as we analyze the same size tax, we're going 87 00:07:10,150 --> 00:07:14,440 to get equivalent outcomes. It's going to come out the same whichever choice of tax 88 00:07:14,620 --> 00:07:19,560 we make. There's actually a simpler way of thinking about this. What we can think 89 00:07:19,740 --> 00:07:23,850 about such a tax is doing, is driving a wedge between what the buyer is paying and 90 00:07:24,030 --> 00:07:28,310 what the sellers receive. When there's no tax, what the buyers pay is what the 91 00:07:28,490 --> 00:07:32,730 sellers receive, but when there's a tax, the buyers pay more than what the sellers 92 00:07:32,910 --> 00:07:36,590 receive. The difference is what the government gets. The difference is the 93 00:07:36,770 --> 00:07:41,970 amount of the tax. So let's think about this as a tax wedge. Let's say this tax 94 00:07:42,150 --> 00:07:47,120 wedge, this side is, let's say a dollar. Another way of analyzing the tax is to 95 00:07:47,300 --> 00:07:51,430 drive this wedge into the diagram until the top of the wedge hits the demand 96 00:07:51,610 --> 00:07:55,940 curve, and the bottom of the wedge just touches the supply curve. Let's take a 97 00:07:56,120 --> 00:08:00,020 look. I'm going to drive the wedge in. What this tells us is that the price the 98 00:08:00,200 --> 00:08:04,990 buyer pays will be here, point B. The price the suppliers receive will be 99 00:08:05,170 --> 00:08:10,160 point D. The difference is the tax. For instance, if the buyers end up paying 100 00:08:10,340 --> 00:08:17,700 $2.65, then the sellers must receive $1.65 if the tax is a dollar. Similarly, if the 101 00:08:17,880 --> 00:08:24,190 suppliers receive a $1.65 and the tax is a dollar, the buyers must be paying $2.65. 102 00:08:24,370 --> 00:08:29,460 With this wedge, we could read off the diagram the price the buyer pays, the 103 00:08:29,640 --> 00:08:33,940 price the seller receives, and the quantity exchanged. We don't even have to 104 00:08:34,120 --> 00:08:38,850 shift any curves. We just drive the wedge into this diagram. Let's do an 105 00:08:39,030 --> 00:08:45,230 application. In the United States, under the Federal Insurance Contributions Act, 106 00:08:45,410 --> 00:08:50,190 FICA, 12.4% of earned income up to an annual limit must be paid into social 107 00:08:50,370 --> 00:08:57,510 security, and 2.9%, an additional 2.9% must be paid into Medicare. Half of this 108 00:08:57,690 --> 00:09:02,460 amount comes directly from the employee. You can see it on your own paychecks. This 109 00:09:02,640 --> 00:09:08,150 is the FICA tax, and half the amount comes from the employer. The question is, does 110 00:09:08,330 --> 00:09:13,330 the fact that it's a 50/50 split, does this make a difference? Does this mean for 111 00:09:13,510 --> 00:09:18,550 example, that since the employer is paying half that this is necessarily a good deal 112 00:09:18,730 --> 00:09:24,330 for the employee? No it doesn't mean that. What we now know is that we could have 113 00:09:24,510 --> 00:09:31,270 100% of this tax paid by the employee, or we could have 100% of this tax paid by the 114 00:09:31,450 --> 00:09:35,750 employer. This wouldn't make a difference, not to wages, not to prices, not to 115 00:09:35,930 --> 00:09:40,340 anything. It would change the legal incidence of the tax, but it would not 116 00:09:40,520 --> 00:09:45,880 change the final economic incidence. I haven't said here who actually pays the 117 00:09:46,060 --> 00:09:50,160 tax. That's what we're going to be talking about in the next lecture. What I've said 118 00:09:50,340 --> 00:09:55,260 here is that it doesn't matter who pays the tax from a legal point-of-view of who 119 00:09:55,440 --> 00:09:59,870 is obliged to deliver that money. So the legal incidence again, does not have a 120 00:10:00,050 --> 00:10:03,340 bearing on the economic incidence of the tax. 121 00:10:03,520 --> 00:10:07,230 What we're going to talk about in the next lecture is what does determine the 122 00:10:07,410 --> 00:10:12,810 economic incidence of a tax. It turns out to be elasticities of supply and demand, 123 00:10:12,990 --> 00:10:17,280 and that's what we'll take up in the next lecture. Thanks again for listening. 124 00:10:17,460 --> 00:10:23,280 - If you want to test yourself, click Practice Questions. Or if you're ready to 125 00:10:23,460 --> 00:10:26,097 move on, just click Next Video. 126 00:10:26,097 --> 00:10:28,097 ♪ [music] ♪