0:00:01.854,0:00:03.863 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:08.160,0:00:13.130 - [Tyler] Today we begin the first of[br]several talks on taxes and subsidies. 0:00:13.310,0:00:17.070 We're not going to be talking about income[br]taxes and income subsidies. Those are 0:00:17.250,0:00:21.850 typically topics for macroeconomics.[br]Instead, we'll be talking about taxes and 0:00:22.030,0:00:27.430 subsidies on goods, like a sales tax or a[br]subsidy for wheat. These are also called 0:00:27.610,0:00:31.585 commodity taxes and subsidies. So let's[br]get going. 0:00:35.513,0:00:36.800 We're going to be emphasizing 0:00:36.840,0:00:42.150 three important ideas about commodity[br]taxation. First, who pays the tax does not 0:00:42.330,0:00:46.810 depend on who writes the check to the[br]government. For example, suppose the 0:00:46.990,0:00:50.950 government is taxing apples. The[br]government could make the buyer of apples 0:00:51.130,0:00:55.390 pay for each apple that they buy. Or they[br]could require the sellers of the apples 0:00:55.570,0:01:00.080 pay for each apple that they sell. What[br]we're going to show is that, from the 0:01:00.260,0:01:04.319 point of view of the buyers or sellers, it[br]actually doesn't matter how the tax is 0:01:04.500,0:01:10.060 placed. The actual outcomes are going to[br]be identical. Another way of putting this 0:01:10.240,0:01:15.320 is that the economic incidence of the tax,[br]who actually pays the tax, does not depend 0:01:15.500,0:01:19.250 on the legal incidence, who is in law[br]required to write the check to the 0:01:19.430,0:01:23.680 government. This will become a little bit[br]clearer as we go along. Don't worry about 0:01:23.860,0:01:29.700 it if it's not clear yet. The second key[br]point, who pays the tax does depend on the 0:01:29.880,0:01:34.740 relative elasticities of demand and[br]supply. In fact, we can summarize point 0:01:34.920,0:01:40.500 one and point two by saying, who pays the[br]tax depends not on the laws of congress 0:01:40.680,0:01:45.810 but rather on the laws of supply and[br]demand. The third point is that commodity 0:01:45.990,0:01:51.160 taxation raises revenue, but it also takes[br]away some gains from trade, that is, it 0:01:51.340,0:01:55.560 creates deadweight loss. We're going to be[br]looking at point one in this talk, and 0:01:55.740,0:01:59.590 then we'll move on to point two, and point[br]three in later talks. So, let's start with 0:01:59.770,0:02:03.360 point one.[br]Let's begin our analysis of commodity 0:02:03.540,0:02:07.870 taxation by assuming the suppliers are the[br]one who have to send the check to the 0:02:08.050,0:02:13.320 government. That is the legal incidence of[br]the tax falls on the suppliers. What does 0:02:13.500,0:02:18.530 a tax on the suppliers do? We can think[br]about a tax on suppliers as increasing 0:02:18.710,0:02:23.880 their costs. This is going to shift the[br]supply curve up by the amount of the tax, 0:02:24.060,0:02:29.440 so the supply curve shifts up like this.[br]Another way of thinking about this, is to 0:02:29.620,0:02:34.550 remember that the supply curve tells us[br]the minimum amount which suppliers require 0:02:34.730,0:02:39.730 to offer a given quantity in the[br]marketplace. The tax, that is going to 0:02:39.910,0:02:44.620 increase the minimum amount that suppliers[br]are requiring to offer that quantity in 0:02:44.800,0:02:50.440 the marketplace. It shifts up that minimum[br]amount required by just the amount of the 0:02:50.620,0:02:56.330 tax. With the new supply curve we find the[br]new equilibrium. The market equilibrium 0:02:56.510,0:03:01.260 moves from point A to point B. What we see[br]is that of course, the quantity which is 0:03:01.440,0:03:07.070 exchanged goes down, in addition, the[br]price paid by the buyers goes up. How much 0:03:07.250,0:03:11.680 do the suppliers get? The suppliers[br]collect this amount, the price paid by the 0:03:11.860,0:03:15.460 buyers, but now they have to give a[br]certain amount of that, the tax to the 0:03:15.640,0:03:21.460 government. The suppliers end up receiving[br]this amount after tax, right here. In 0:03:21.640,0:03:26.160 other words, what the tax does, it means[br]that the buyers pay more than before, and 0:03:26.340,0:03:32.200 the sellers receive less than before.[br]Without any tax, the price the buyers pay 0:03:32.380,0:03:37.050 is the same as the price the supplier[br]receives. With the tax the buyers pay a 0:03:37.230,0:03:41.220 certain price, but the sellers get less[br]than that. They get whatever the buyers 0:03:41.400,0:03:46.570 pay minus of course, the tax. That's the[br]situation when the suppliers pay the tax, 0:03:46.750,0:03:50.700 or the suppliers have to send the check to[br]the government. Let's now look at what 0:03:50.880,0:03:55.870 happens when it's the buyers who must send[br]the check to the government. Now, we look 0:03:56.050,0:04:01.170 at the situation when the legal incidence[br]is on the buyers. We begin just as before 0:04:01.350,0:04:06.030 with the equilibrium with no taxes.[br]No taxes on sellers or buyers. Again, that 0:04:06.210,0:04:10.890 equilibrium is at point A. I've also[br]included this supply curve here. This is 0:04:11.070,0:04:15.150 the supply curve when the tax is on the[br]suppliers. It's the supply curve from the 0:04:15.330,0:04:20.070 previous problem. It's not relevant for[br]this problem. I've included it rather to 0:04:20.250,0:04:24.950 remind us of where the equilibrium on the[br]previous problem was. You can think of 0:04:25.130,0:04:30.120 this as a kind of ghost supply curve. It's[br]a supply curve from the previous problem 0:04:30.300,0:04:35.320 coming back to haunt us. So what's the[br]effect of a tax on the demanders? Think 0:04:35.500,0:04:39.560 about it this way. Suppose the most you[br]were willing to pay for an apple is one 0:04:39.740,0:04:44.260 dollar. Again, most you're willing to pay[br]for that apple, a dollar, no more. Now, 0:04:44.440,0:04:49.200 suppose you learned that the government[br]has instituted a new tax. For every apple 0:04:49.380,0:04:53.790 you buy, you must now pay 25 cents to the[br]government. Now, how much are you willing 0:04:53.970,0:04:59.060 to pay to suppliers for that apple?[br]You're only willing to pay the maximum 0:04:59.240,0:05:04.750 amount that you're going to be willing to[br]pay suppliers is now 75 cents. The maximum 0:05:04.930,0:05:08.680 amount that apple was worth to you is a[br]dollar. If you know you're going to be 0:05:08.860,0:05:13.100 taxed 25 cents if you buy that apple, then[br]the most you're going to be willing to pay 0:05:13.280,0:05:19.430 the supplier is 75 cents, because 75 cents[br]plus the 25 cent tax to the government, 0:05:19.610,0:05:23.580 that's one dollar. That's the most you're[br]willing to pay to get the apple. In other 0:05:23.760,0:05:28.540 words, what a tax on demanders does is it[br]reduces their willingness to pay, and that 0:05:28.720,0:05:33.520 means the demand curve shifts. Which way?[br]The demand curve shifts down by the amount 0:05:33.700,0:05:39.680 of the tax. So let's shift. The tax is[br]exactly the same amount that was before. 0:05:39.860,0:05:44.590 Let's shift the demand curve down by the[br]amount of the tax. We find now that the 0:05:44.770,0:05:49.010 new equilibrium is at point B. Notice[br]first of all, that the quantity has 0:05:49.190,0:05:54.000 declined. The quantity exchange has[br]declined by exactly the same amount as 0:05:54.180,0:05:59.800 before in the previous problem. What about[br]the price received by the sellers? The 0:05:59.980,0:06:04.550 sellers now receive this price.[br]Low and behold, that's exactly the same 0:06:04.730,0:06:10.250 price as it was before. How about the[br]price paid by the buyers? The buyers now 0:06:10.430,0:06:15.120 pay what they paid to the suppliers, plus[br]they must pay the tax to the government. 0:06:15.300,0:06:21.100 This distance is the tax. Low and behold,[br]the price after tax paid by the buyers is 0:06:21.280,0:06:26.760 once again exactly what it was when the[br]tax was on the suppliers. When the tax is 0:06:26.940,0:06:31.100 on the buyers, the buyers pay more than[br]before. The sellers receive less than 0:06:31.280,0:06:37.690 before by exactly the same amounts. The[br]quantity declines by the same amount, too. 0:06:37.870,0:06:42.950 The net price, or the total price paid by[br]the buyers is the same. The total price 0:06:43.130,0:06:47.530 received by the sellers is the same. Now[br]that you know the idea, I'm going to show 0:06:47.710,0:06:51.760 you a simpler way of demonstrating this.[br]What we just showed is that it doesn't 0:06:51.940,0:06:55.600 matter whether the suppliers must write[br]the check to the government or the 0:06:55.780,0:07:00.030 demanders must write the check to the[br]government in order to pay the tax. In 0:07:00.210,0:07:04.110 other words, we can analyze the tax by[br]shifting the supply curve up, or by 0:07:04.290,0:07:09.970 shifting the demand curve down. As long as[br]we analyze the same size tax, we're going 0:07:10.150,0:07:14.440 to get equivalent outcomes. It's going to[br]come out the same whichever choice of tax 0:07:14.620,0:07:19.560 we make. There's actually a simpler way of[br]thinking about this. What we can think 0:07:19.740,0:07:23.850 about such a tax is doing, is driving a[br]wedge between what the buyer is paying and 0:07:24.030,0:07:28.310 what the sellers receive. When there's no[br]tax, what the buyers pay is what the 0:07:28.490,0:07:32.730 sellers receive, but when there's a tax,[br]the buyers pay more than what the sellers 0:07:32.910,0:07:36.590 receive. The difference is what the[br]government gets. The difference is the 0:07:36.770,0:07:41.970 amount of the tax. So let's think about[br]this as a tax wedge. Let's say this tax 0:07:42.150,0:07:47.120 wedge, this side is, let's say a dollar.[br]Another way of analyzing the tax is to 0:07:47.300,0:07:51.430 drive this wedge into the diagram until[br]the top of the wedge hits the demand 0:07:51.610,0:07:55.940 curve, and the bottom of the wedge just[br]touches the supply curve. Let's take a 0:07:56.120,0:08:00.020 look. I'm going to drive the wedge in.[br]What this tells us is that the price the 0:08:00.200,0:08:04.990 buyer pays will be here, point B.[br]The price the suppliers receive will be 0:08:05.170,0:08:10.160 point D. The difference is the tax. For[br]instance, if the buyers end up paying 0:08:10.340,0:08:17.700 $2.65, then the sellers must receive $1.65[br]if the tax is a dollar. Similarly, if the 0:08:17.880,0:08:24.190 suppliers receive a $1.65 and the tax is a[br]dollar, the buyers must be paying $2.65. 0:08:24.370,0:08:29.460 With this wedge, we could read off the[br]diagram the price the buyer pays, the 0:08:29.640,0:08:33.940 price the seller receives, and the[br]quantity exchanged. We don't even have to 0:08:34.120,0:08:38.850 shift any curves. We just drive the wedge[br]into this diagram. Let's do an 0:08:39.030,0:08:45.230 application. In the United States, under[br]the Federal Insurance Contributions Act, 0:08:45.410,0:08:50.190 FICA, 12.4% of earned income up to an[br]annual limit must be paid into social 0:08:50.370,0:08:57.510 security, and 2.9%, an additional 2.9%[br]must be paid into Medicare. Half of this 0:08:57.690,0:09:02.460 amount comes directly from the employee.[br]You can see it on your own paychecks. This 0:09:02.640,0:09:08.150 is the FICA tax, and half the amount comes[br]from the employer. The question is, does 0:09:08.330,0:09:13.330 the fact that it's a 50/50 split, does[br]this make a difference? Does this mean for 0:09:13.510,0:09:18.550 example, that since the employer is paying[br]half that this is necessarily a good deal 0:09:18.730,0:09:24.330 for the employee? No it doesn't mean that.[br]What we now know is that we could have 0:09:24.510,0:09:31.270 100% of this tax paid by the employee, or[br]we could have 100% of this tax paid by the 0:09:31.450,0:09:35.750 employer. This wouldn't make a difference,[br]not to wages, not to prices, not to 0:09:35.930,0:09:40.340 anything. It would change the legal[br]incidence of the tax, but it would not 0:09:40.520,0:09:45.880 change the final economic incidence. I[br]haven't said here who actually pays the 0:09:46.060,0:09:50.160 tax. That's what we're going to be talking[br]about in the next lecture. What I've said 0:09:50.340,0:09:55.260 here is that it doesn't matter who pays[br]the tax from a legal point-of-view of who 0:09:55.440,0:09:59.870 is obliged to deliver that money. So the[br]legal incidence again, does not have a 0:10:00.050,0:10:03.340 bearing on the economic incidence of the[br]tax. 0:10:03.520,0:10:07.230 What we're going to talk about in the next[br]lecture is what does determine the 0:10:07.410,0:10:12.810 economic incidence of a tax. It turns out[br]to be elasticities of supply and demand, 0:10:12.990,0:10:17.280 and that's what we'll take up in the next[br]lecture. Thanks again for listening. 0:10:17.460,0:10:23.280 - If you want to test yourself, click[br]Practice Questions. Or if you're ready to 0:10:23.460,0:10:26.097 move on, just click Next Video. 0:10:26.097,0:10:28.097 ♪ [music] ♪