0:00:00.000,0:00:05.517 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.273,0:00:12.398 - [Alex] In our first lecture[br]on the elasticity of demand, 0:00:12.398,0:00:15.295 we explain the intuitive meaning[br]of elasticity. 0:00:15.295,0:00:18.377 It measures the responsiveness[br]of the quantity demanded 0:00:18.377,0:00:20.000 to a change in price. 0:00:20.000,0:00:22.571 More responsive means more elastic. 0:00:22.571,0:00:24.620 In this lecture, we're going[br]to show how to create 0:00:24.620,0:00:27.048 a numeric measure of elasticity. 0:00:27.048,0:00:30.778 How to calculate with some data[br]on prices and quantities, 0:00:30.778,0:00:34.859 what the elasticity is over a range[br]of the demand curve. 0:00:39.567,0:00:42.994 So here's a more precise definition[br]of elasticity. 0:00:42.994,0:00:46.368 The elasticity of demand[br]is the percentage change 0:00:46.368,0:00:51.376 in quantity demanded divided[br]by the percentage change in price. 0:00:51.992,0:00:55.591 So let's write it like this.[br]We have some notation here. 0:00:55.591,0:01:00.721 The elasticity of demand is equal[br]to the percentage "change in". 0:01:00.721,0:01:05.310 Delta is the symbol for change in,[br]so this is the percentage change 0:01:05.310,0:01:10.102 in the quantity demanded[br]divided by the percentage change 0:01:10.102,0:01:12.647 in the price. 0:01:12.647,0:01:15.863 That's the elasticity of demand.[br]Let's give an example or two. 0:01:17.052,0:01:21.898 So, if the price of oil increases[br]by 10% and over a period 0:01:21.898,0:01:26.415 of several years the quantity[br]demanded falls by 5%, 0:01:26.415,0:01:31.603 then the long run elasticity[br]of demand for oil is what? 0:01:32.812,0:01:35.550 Well, elasticity[br]is the percentage change 0:01:35.550,0:01:37.746 and the quantity demanded. 0:01:37.746,0:01:41.380 That's -5% divided[br]by the percentage change 0:01:41.380,0:01:42.544 in the price. 0:01:42.544,0:01:43.915 That's 10%. 0:01:43.915,0:01:45.824 So the elasticity of demand 0:01:45.824,0:01:51.389 is -5% divided by 10%, or -0.5. 0:01:52.803,0:01:55.647 Elasticities of demand[br]are always negative 0:01:55.647,0:01:59.672 because when price goes up,[br]the quantity demanded goes down. 0:01:59.672,0:02:02.807 When price goes down,[br]the quantity demanded goes up. 0:02:02.807,0:02:06.649 So we often drop the negative sign[br]and write that the elasticity 0:02:06.649,0:02:10.089 of demand is 0.5. 0:02:12.201,0:02:14.412 Here's some more important notation. 0:02:15.187,0:02:18.495 If the absolute value[br]of the elasticity of demand 0:02:18.495,0:02:21.069 is less than one,[br]just like the example 0:02:21.069,0:02:26.292 we just gave for oil, we say[br]that the demand curve is inelastic. 0:02:26.806,0:02:30.837 Elasticity of demand less than one,[br]the demand curve is inelastic. 0:02:31.738,0:02:34.289 If the elasticity of demand[br]is greater than one, 0:02:34.289,0:02:36.984 we say the demand curve is elastic. 0:02:37.598,0:02:39.783 And if elasticity of demand[br]is equal to one, 0:02:39.783,0:02:42.700 that is the knife point case,[br]then the demand curve 0:02:42.700,0:02:45.163 is unit elastic. 0:02:45.676,0:02:49.466 These terms are going to come back,[br]so just keep them in mind. 0:02:49.518,0:02:53.694 Inelastic: less than one.[br]Elastic: greater than one. 0:02:55.380,0:02:57.639 So we know that elasticity[br]is the percentage change 0:02:57.639,0:03:00.491 in quantity divided[br]by the percentage change in price, 0:03:00.491,0:03:03.537 how do we calculate[br]the percentage change in something? 0:03:03.537,0:03:06.039 This is not so hard,[br]but it could be a little bit tricky 0:03:06.039,0:03:07.642 for the following reason. 0:03:07.642,0:03:10.574 Let's suppose you're driving down[br]the highway at 100 miles per hour. 0:03:10.574,0:03:12.355 I don't recommend this,[br]but let's just imagine 0:03:12.355,0:03:13.555 that you are. 0:03:13.555,0:03:17.537 You're going 100 miles per hour,[br]and now you increase speed by 50%. 0:03:18.182,0:03:21.987 How fast are you going?[br]150 miles per hour, right? 0:03:21.987,0:03:24.408 Okay, so now you're going[br]150 miles per hour. 0:03:24.408,0:03:29.531 Suppose you decrease speed by 50%.[br]Now, how fast are you going? 0:03:29.531,0:03:31.845 75 miles per hour, right? 0:03:31.845,0:03:34.841 So how is it that you can[br]increase speed by 50% 0:03:34.841,0:03:37.835 and then decrease by 50%[br]and not be back 0:03:37.835,0:03:39.920 to where you started? 0:03:39.920,0:03:42.424 Well the answer is,[br]is that intuitively, 0:03:42.424,0:03:45.368 we have changed the base[br]by which we are calculating 0:03:45.368,0:03:46.988 the percentage change. 0:03:46.988,0:03:51.129 And we don't want to have[br]this inconsistency 0:03:51.129,0:03:53.340 when we calculate elasticity. 0:03:53.340,0:03:56.146 We want people to get[br]the same elasticity 0:03:56.146,0:03:58.330 whether they're calculating[br]from the lower base 0:03:58.330,0:03:59.953 or from the higher base. 0:03:59.953,0:04:03.143 So, because of that, we're going[br]to use the Midpoint Formula. 0:04:03.583,0:04:06.868 So, the elasticity of demand,[br]percentage change in quantity 0:04:06.868,0:04:09.285 divided by the percentage[br]change in price, 0:04:09.285,0:04:14.618 that's the change in quantity[br]divided by the average quantity 0:04:14.618,0:04:16.234 times 100. 0:04:16.234,0:04:19.428 That will give us the percentage[br]change divided by 0:04:19.428,0:04:22.804 the change in price[br]divided by the average price. 0:04:22.804,0:04:24.331 Again, that times 100. 0:04:24.331,0:04:27.635 Notice, since we've actually got[br]100 on top and 100 on the bottom, 0:04:27.635,0:04:30.091 those 100s we can actually[br]cancel out. 0:04:30.987,0:04:33.719 Let's expand this[br]just a little bit more. 0:04:33.719,0:04:36.901 The change in quantity.[br]What is the change in quantity? 0:04:36.901,0:04:39.023 Well, let's suppose[br]we have two quantities. 0:04:39.023,0:04:41.040 Let's call them after and before. 0:04:41.040,0:04:44.151 It doesn't matter which one[br]we call after or which one before. 0:04:44.151,0:04:48.204 So, we're going to then expand this[br]to the change in quantity. 0:04:48.204,0:04:52.639 That's Q after minus Q before[br]divided by the average, 0:04:52.639,0:04:56.004 Q after plus Q before,[br]divided by two, 0:04:56.004,0:05:00.704 divided by the change in price,[br]P after minus P before, 0:05:00.704,0:05:04.396 divided by the average price,[br]b after plus b before, 0:05:04.396,0:05:05.682 divide by two. 0:05:05.682,0:05:09.920 So that's a little bit of a mouthful,[br]but everything, I think, 0:05:09.920,0:05:11.297 is fairly simple. 0:05:11.297,0:05:17.853 Just remember change in quantity[br]divided by the average quantity 0:05:17.853,0:05:20.205 and you should always be able[br]to calculate this. 0:05:20.612,0:05:22.258 Let's give an example. 0:05:23.286,0:05:25.235 Okay, here's an example[br]of a type of problem 0:05:25.235,0:05:28.658 you might see on a quiz[br]or a mid term. 0:05:28.658,0:05:32.747 At the initial price of $10,[br]the quantity demanded is 100. 0:05:32.747,0:05:36.577 When the price rises to $20,[br]the quantity demanded 0:05:36.577,0:05:38.287 falls to 90. 0:05:38.287,0:05:41.354 What is the elasticity is, [br]what is the elasticity over 0:05:41.354,0:05:43.611 this range of the demand curve? 0:05:43.930,0:05:46.055 Well, we always want[br]to begin by writing down 0:05:46.055,0:05:47.733 what we know -- our formula. 0:05:47.733,0:05:49.770 The elasticity of demand[br]is the percentage change 0:05:49.770,0:05:52.791 in quantity divided[br]by the percentage change in price. 0:05:52.791,0:05:55.220 Now, let's remember[br]to just expand that. 0:05:55.220,0:05:59.575 That's Delta Q over the average Q[br]all divided by Delta P 0:05:59.575,0:06:00.987 over the average P. 0:06:00.987,0:06:03.774 Now, we just start[br]to fill things in. 0:06:03.774,0:06:09.637 So our quantity after, okay,[br]after the change is 90. 0:06:09.637,0:06:13.785 Our quantity before that was 100. 0:06:14.440,0:06:16.275 So on the top,[br]the percentage change 0:06:16.275,0:06:21.069 in quantity is 90 minus 100[br]divided by 90 plus 100, over two. 0:06:21.069,0:06:23.317 That is the average quantity. 0:06:23.317,0:06:25.463 And then on the bottom,[br]and the only trick here 0:06:25.463,0:06:29.151 is always write it[br]in the same order, 0:06:29.151,0:06:33.303 so if you put the 90 here,[br]then make sure you put the 20, 0:06:33.303,0:06:35.350 the number the price[br]which is associated 0:06:35.350,0:06:38.332 with that quantity started off[br]the same way. 0:06:38.332,0:06:40.665 So, always just keep it[br]in the same order. 0:06:40.665,0:06:43.402 So on the bottom, then,[br]we have the quantity -- 0:06:43.402,0:06:46.355 the price after -- which is 20[br]minus the price before, 0:06:46.355,0:06:49.183 which is 10, divided[br]by the average price. 0:06:49.183,0:06:51.816 And now, just, it's numerics. 0:06:52.185,0:06:55.534 You plug in the numbers[br]and what you get is the elasticity 0:06:55.534,0:07:00.563 of demand is equal to -0.158,[br]approximately. 0:07:00.563,0:07:02.630 We can always drop[br]the negative sign 0:07:02.630,0:07:04.384 because these things,[br]elasticity of demands, 0:07:04.384,0:07:05.650 are always negative. 0:07:05.650,0:07:08.339 So it's equal to 0.158. 0:07:08.339,0:07:12.447 So does this make the elasticity[br]of demand over this range 0:07:12.447,0:07:15.871 elastic or inelastic? 0:07:17.437,0:07:19.001 Inelastic, right? 0:07:19.001,0:07:21.103 The elasticity of demand[br]we've just calculated 0:07:21.103,0:07:24.663 is less than one,[br]so that makes this one inelastic. 0:07:24.735,0:07:26.107 There you go. 0:07:26.861,0:07:28.916 We need to cover one more[br]important point 0:07:28.916,0:07:32.281 about the elasticity of demand,[br]and that is its relationship 0:07:32.281,0:07:34.302 to total revenue. 0:07:34.302,0:07:37.163 So a firm's revenues[br]are very simply equal 0:07:37.163,0:07:40.381 to price times quantity sold. 0:07:40.381,0:07:42.964 Revenue is equal[br]to price times quantity. 0:07:42.964,0:07:45.707 Now, elasticity, it's all about[br]the relationship 0:07:45.707,0:07:47.763 between price and quantity, 0:07:47.763,0:07:51.302 and so it's also going[br]to have implications for revenue. 0:07:52.292,0:07:54.435 Let's give some intuition[br]for the relationship 0:07:54.435,0:07:57.134 between the elasticity[br]and total revenue. 0:07:57.134,0:07:59.283 So revenue is price times quantity. 0:07:59.283,0:08:03.881 Now suppose the price goes up[br]by a lot and then quantity demanded 0:08:03.881,0:08:06.672 goes down, just by a little bit. 0:08:06.672,0:08:09.655 What then is going to be[br]the response of revenue? 0:08:09.655,0:08:12.541 Well, if price is going up[br]by a lot and quantity 0:08:12.541,0:08:15.219 is going down just by a little bit,[br]then revenue 0:08:15.219,0:08:17.825 is also going to be going up. 0:08:17.825,0:08:21.895 Now, what kind of demand curve[br]do we call that, when price goes up 0:08:21.895,0:08:25.696 by a lot and quantity falls [br]by just a little bit? 0:08:26.317,0:08:30.441 We call that[br]an inelastic demand curve. 0:08:30.441,0:08:33.273 So, what this little thought[br]experiment tells us 0:08:33.273,0:08:36.840 is that when you have[br]an inelastic demand curve, 0:08:37.320,0:08:42.357 when price goes up[br]revenue is also going to go up, 0:08:42.357,0:08:44.156 and of course, vice versa. 0:08:44.156,0:08:46.290 Let's take a look[br]at this with a graph. 0:08:46.290,0:08:50.749 So here's our initial demand curve,[br]a very inelastic demand curve, 0:08:50.749,0:08:54.783 at a price of $10, the quantity[br]demanded is 100 units, 0:08:54.783,0:08:56.695 so revenue is 1,000. 0:08:56.695,0:08:58.965 Notice that we can show revenue[br]in the graph 0:08:58.965,0:09:00.922 by price times quantity. 0:09:00.922,0:09:03.845 Now, just looking at the graph,[br]look at what happens 0:09:03.845,0:09:05.770 when the price goes up to 20. 0:09:05.770,0:09:08.775 Well, the quantity demanded[br]goes down by just a little bit, 0:09:08.775,0:09:13.114 in this case to 90,[br]but revenues go up to 1,800. 0:09:14.223,0:09:18.714 So you can just see,[br]by sketching the little graph, 0:09:19.104,0:09:22.533 what happens to revenues[br]when price goes up 0:09:22.533,0:09:25.124 when you have[br]an inelastic demand curve. 0:09:25.146,0:09:26.900 And again, vice versa. 0:09:27.225,0:09:29.096 Let's take a look[br]about what happens 0:09:29.096,0:09:31.034 when you have[br]an elastic demand curve. 0:09:31.782,0:09:34.324 So let's do the same kind[br]of little thought experiment, 0:09:34.324,0:09:36.443 revenue is price times quantity. 0:09:36.443,0:09:39.368 Suppose price goes up[br]by a modest amount 0:09:39.368,0:09:42.502 and quantity goes down[br]by a lot. 0:09:42.502,0:09:44.861 Well, if price is going up[br]by a little bit and quantity 0:09:44.861,0:09:48.737 is going down by a lot,[br]then revenue must also be falling. 0:09:48.737,0:09:52.906 And what type of demand curve[br]is it when price goes up 0:09:52.906,0:09:55.212 by a little bit,[br]quantity falls by a lot? 0:09:55.212,0:09:56.825 What type of demand curve is that? 0:09:56.825,0:09:59.772 That's an elastic demand curve. 0:09:59.772,0:10:05.002 So, revenues fall as price rises[br]with an elastic demand curve. 0:10:05.414,0:10:06.921 And again, let's show that. 0:10:06.921,0:10:09.721 If you're ever confused[br]and you can't quite remember, 0:10:09.721,0:10:11.067 just draw the graph. 0:10:11.067,0:10:13.414 I can never remember, myself,[br]but I always draw 0:10:13.414,0:10:14.763 these little graphs. 0:10:14.763,0:10:19.121 So, draw a really flatter,[br]elastic demand curve. 0:10:19.121,0:10:25.033 In this case, at a price of $10,[br]the quantity demanded is 250 units. 0:10:25.033,0:10:27.573 So revenues is 2,500. 0:10:27.573,0:10:30.664 And see what happens,[br]when price goes up, 0:10:30.664,0:10:35.986 price goes up to $20,[br]quantity demanded falls to 50, 0:10:35.986,0:10:38.033 so revenue falls to 1,000. 0:10:38.033,0:10:40.003 And again, you can just compare 0:10:40.003,0:10:43.264 the sizes of these[br]revenue rectangles 0:10:43.264,0:10:46.555 to see which way[br]the relationship goes. 0:10:46.555,0:10:51.396 And of course, this also implies,[br]going from $20, the price of $20 0:10:51.396,0:10:54.969 to a price of $10,[br]revenues increase. 0:10:54.969,0:10:58.444 So with an elastic demand curve,[br]when price goes down, 0:10:58.444,0:11:00.546 revenues go up. 0:11:01.364,0:11:04.034 So here's a summary[br]of these relationships. 0:11:04.034,0:11:06.212 When the elasticity of demand[br]is less than one, 0:11:06.212,0:11:09.372 that's an inelastic demand curve[br]and price and revenue 0:11:09.372,0:11:10.519 move together. 0:11:10.519,0:11:11.945 When one goes up,[br]the other goes up. 0:11:11.945,0:11:13.901 When one goes down,[br]the other goes down. 0:11:13.901,0:11:16.706 If the elasticity of demand [br]is greater than one, 0:11:16.706,0:11:20.018 that's an elastic demand curve[br]and price and revenue move 0:11:20.018,0:11:22.124 in opposite directions. 0:11:22.645,0:11:24.993 And could you guess what happens[br]if the elasticity of demand 0:11:24.993,0:11:28.357 is equal to one --[br]if you have a unit elastic curve? 0:11:28.357,0:11:32.603 Well then, when the price changes,[br]revenue stays the same. 0:11:32.682,0:11:36.043 Now, if you have to, again,[br]memorize these, 0:11:36.043,0:11:40.095 but it's really much better[br]to just sketch some graphs. 0:11:40.095,0:11:42.147 I never remember them,[br]as I've said myself, 0:11:42.147,0:11:43.944 I never remember[br]these relationships, 0:11:43.944,0:11:46.444 but I can always sketch[br]an inelastic graph 0:11:46.444,0:11:49.543 and then with a few changes[br]in price, I can see 0:11:49.543,0:11:52.527 whether the revenue rectangles[br]are getting bigger or smaller 0:11:52.527,0:11:55.528 and so I'll be able to recompute 0:11:55.528,0:11:58.323 all of these relationships[br]pretty easily. 0:11:59.432,0:12:01.270 Here's a quick practice question. 0:12:01.270,0:12:05.274 The elasticity of demand for eggs[br]has been estimated to be 0.1. 0:12:05.784,0:12:09.822 If egg producers raise their prices[br]by 10%, what will happen 0:12:09.822,0:12:15.082 to their total revenues? Increase?[br]Decrease? Or it won't change? 0:12:16.274,0:12:18.174 Okay, how should we[br]approach this problem? 0:12:19.325,0:12:23.372 If the elasticity of demand is 0.1,[br]what type of demand curve? 0:12:24.974,0:12:26.676 Inelastic demand. 0:12:27.125,0:12:31.551 Now, what's the relationship[br]between an inelastic demand curve? 0:12:31.821,0:12:34.439 When price goes up,[br]what happens to revenue? 0:12:34.439,0:12:36.161 If you're not sure, [br]if you don't remember, 0:12:36.161,0:12:37.472 draw some graphs. 0:12:37.472,0:12:40.093 Draw an inelastic,[br]draw an elastic, figure it out. 0:12:40.672,0:12:45.062 Okay, let's see. What happens?[br]Revenue increases, right? 0:12:45.111,0:12:48.086 If you have an inelastic[br]demand curve and price goes up, 0:12:48.086,0:12:49.961 revenue goes up as well. 0:12:50.891,0:12:52.390 Here's an application. 0:12:52.428,0:12:55.566 Why is the war on drugs[br]so hard to win? 0:12:56.193,0:12:58.461 Well, drugs are typically[br]going to have 0:12:58.461,0:13:01.142 a fairly inelastic demand curve. 0:13:01.994,0:13:05.928 What that means[br]is that when enforcement actions 0:13:05.928,0:13:09.783 raise the price of drugs,[br]make it more costly to get drugs, 0:13:09.783,0:13:12.427 raising the price,[br]that means the total revenue 0:13:12.427,0:13:14.831 for the drug dealers goes up. 0:13:15.195,0:13:17.043 So check out this graph. 0:13:17.043,0:13:19.129 Here is the price[br]with no prohibition, 0:13:19.129,0:13:22.294 here's our demand curve,[br]our inelastic demand curve. 0:13:22.294,0:13:24.859 What prohibition does,[br]is it raises the cost 0:13:24.859,0:13:26.306 of supplying the good. 0:13:26.306,0:13:30.963 But that raises the price,[br]which is what it's supposed to do, 0:13:30.963,0:13:34.458 and that does reduce[br]the quantity demanded of the drug. 0:13:34.458,0:13:38.711 But it also has the effect[br]of increasing seller revenues. 0:13:38.984,0:13:42.307 And seller revenues may be[br]where many of the problems 0:13:42.307,0:13:44.473 of drug prohibition come from. 0:13:44.473,0:13:47.642 It's the seller revenues[br]which drive the violence, 0:13:47.642,0:13:52.012 which drive the guns,[br]which make it look good 0:13:52.012,0:13:54.672 to be a drug dealer,[br]which encourage people 0:13:54.672,0:13:57.374 to become drug dealers,[br]and so forth. 0:13:57.799,0:14:01.099 So there's a real difficulty[br]with prohibition, 0:14:01.099,0:14:03.527 with prohibiting a good,[br]especially when it has 0:14:03.527,0:14:05.616 an inelastic demand. 0:14:06.181,0:14:08.858 Here's another application[br]of elasticity of demand 0:14:08.858,0:14:11.436 and how it can be used[br]to understand our world. 0:14:11.858,0:14:16.738 This is a quotation from 2012[br]from NPRs food blog "The Salt." 0:14:17.206,0:14:18.318 "You've all heard a lot 0:14:18.318,0:14:21.502 about this year's devastating[br]drought in the Midwest, right? 0:14:21.856,0:14:24.686 US Department of Agriculture[br]announced last Friday 0:14:24.733,0:14:29.192 that the average US cornfield[br]this year will yield less per acre 0:14:29.192,0:14:31.869 than it has since 1995. 0:14:32.430,0:14:34.191 Soybean yields are down, too. 0:14:34.712,0:14:37.103 So you think that farmers[br]who grow these crops 0:14:37.103,0:14:38.986 must be really hurting. 0:14:38.986,0:14:42.876 And that's certainly the impression[br]you get from media reports. 0:14:44.104,0:14:46.349 But how's this,[br]for a surprising fact? 0:14:46.349,0:14:49.613 On average, corn growers[br]actually will rake in 0:14:49.613,0:14:53.883 a record amount of cash[br]from their harvest this year." 0:14:55.095,0:14:58.776 So can you explain this secret side[br]of the drought? 0:14:59.301,0:15:01.016 I'm not going to answer[br]this question. 0:15:01.016,0:15:03.536 This is exactly the type[br]of question you might receive 0:15:03.536,0:15:05.087 on an exam. 0:15:05.087,0:15:07.602 But you should be able[br]to answer it by now, 0:15:07.602,0:15:09.883 with a few sketches[br]on a piece of paper. 0:15:09.949,0:15:12.370 And in particular, what I want you[br]to answer is, 0:15:12.370,0:15:17.010 what type of demand curve,[br]for corn, would make exactly 0:15:17.010,0:15:20.408 this type of outcome[br]perfectly understandable? 0:15:20.408,0:15:24.462 Not a secret or surprise,[br]but perfectly understandable. 0:15:25.082,0:15:28.086 Okay, that's the elasticity[br]of demand. 0:15:28.086,0:15:31.220 Next time we'll be taking up[br]the elasticity of supply, 0:15:31.220,0:15:33.700 and we'll be able to move[br]through that material much quicker 0:15:33.700,0:15:36.843 because it covers[br]many similar concepts. 0:15:36.843,0:15:38.455 Thanks. 0:15:39.469,0:15:41.296 - [Narrator] If you want[br]to test yourself, 0:15:41.296,0:15:45.287 click Practice Questions,[br]or if you're ready to move on, 0:15:45.287,0:15:47.058 just click Next Video. 0:15:47.088,0:15:50.882 ♪ [music] ♪