1 00:00:00,000 --> 00:00:02,900 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:08,900 --> 00:00:12,240 - Today we're going to look at the Coase Theorem and market solutions to 3 00:00:12,420 --> 00:00:18,200 externality problems. Basically what Coase pointed out in a remarkable paper was that 4 00:00:18,380 --> 00:00:22,560 the problem with external benefits and external cost is not that they're 5 00:00:22,740 --> 00:00:28,520 external but rather that property rights in these cases are vague and uncertain 6 00:00:28,700 --> 00:00:33,790 and that transactions costs are high. Let's get started with an example. 7 00:00:38,100 --> 00:00:40,820 - The Nobel prize winning economist James Meade 8 00:00:41,000 --> 00:00:46,620 argued that the market would under provide honey and pollination services. Bees Meade 9 00:00:46,800 --> 00:00:51,880 argued do two things first they create honey. That honey is bought and sold in 10 00:00:52,060 --> 00:00:57,640 markets and there's a price for the honey. Second however, bees will also fly out and 11 00:00:57,820 --> 00:01:03,030 they'll pollinate the crops of nearby farmers. That's a very useful service but 12 00:01:03,210 --> 00:01:08,050 Meade argued that the farmers wouldn't be paying for that service. The pollination 13 00:01:08,230 --> 00:01:13,590 services Meade argued were an external benefit because the beekeepers were not 14 00:01:13,770 --> 00:01:19,120 being paid for this useful pollination services there would be too few bees and 15 00:01:19,300 --> 00:01:22,748 as a result too little honey, and also too little crops and too 16 00:01:22,748 --> 00:01:24,508 little pollination services. 17 00:01:25,850 --> 00:01:30,940 However, another economist Steven Cheung proved that the Nobel prize winner was 18 00:01:31,120 --> 00:01:36,270 wrong and he did so by consulting the yellow pages. Cheung discovered that 19 00:01:36,450 --> 00:01:43,270 pollination in the United States in fact is a $15 billion industry. Beekeepers 20 00:01:43,450 --> 00:01:47,770 regularly truck their bee colonies around the country and they sell their 21 00:01:47,950 --> 00:01:54,170 pollination services to farmers because the farmers are paying the beekeepers for 22 00:01:54,350 --> 00:01:58,800 the services of the bees the benefits in fact are not external. They're not on 23 00:01:58,980 --> 00:02:06,090 bystanders and the market works. So why did Meade get it wrong? What about 24 00:02:06,270 --> 00:02:11,320 the bees and what about the farmers made it possible for this externality problem 25 00:02:11,500 --> 00:02:17,070 to be solved by markets when many other externality problems are not? 26 00:02:17,250 --> 00:02:21,660 The market for pollination works despite the fact that bees seem to create this 27 00:02:21,840 --> 00:02:27,677 external benefit because transactions costs are low that is all of the costs 28 00:02:27,677 --> 00:02:33,760 necessary for buyers and sellers to reach an agreement are low. In particular, bees 29 00:02:33,940 --> 00:02:40,540 simply don't fly very far. So an agreement between one beekeeper and one farmer can 30 00:02:40,720 --> 00:02:46,200 internalize all the externality that is if the beekeeper puts his bees in the middle 31 00:02:46,380 --> 00:02:51,660 of the farm basically the only crops which are going to be pollinated are the 32 00:02:51,840 --> 00:02:58,200 crops of that single farmer. So once an agreement is made between that beekeeper 33 00:02:58,380 --> 00:03:03,790 and that farmer all of the externalities have been internalized. There are no 34 00:03:03,970 --> 00:03:10,290 bystanders once the beekeeper and the farmer make an agreement. Moreover, the 35 00:03:10,470 --> 00:03:16,410 property rights here are very clear. The beekeeper has the rights to the honey. The 36 00:03:16,590 --> 00:03:20,910 farmer owns the crops that the bees pollinate. There isn't going to be a lot 37 00:03:21,090 --> 00:03:27,070 of bargaining and disagreement but who owns what? The property rights are clear. 38 00:03:27,250 --> 00:03:31,890 In other cases of externalities, some of the ones we've looked at previously 39 00:03:32,070 --> 00:03:37,570 neither of these things are true. Transactions cost are high and property 40 00:03:37,750 --> 00:03:43,300 rights are unclear. Let's compare with pollution and flu shots. In both cases 41 00:03:43,480 --> 00:03:48,260 here, the transactions costs are high and property rights are unclear and uncertain. 42 00:03:48,440 --> 00:03:53,180 Consider pollution there's an external cost the factory is putting lots of 43 00:03:53,360 --> 00:03:58,080 pollution up into the sky but on who? It's not necessarily on the people who 44 00:03:58,260 --> 00:04:03,150 live right next door to the factory. The pollution could be causing acid rain, 45 00:04:03,330 --> 00:04:07,070 which is ruining lakes hundreds of miles away or it could be causing global 46 00:04:07,250 --> 00:04:12,010 warming which is increasing sea levels and ruining people's lives thousands of miles 47 00:04:12,190 --> 00:04:17,402 away and exactly what are the costs? How much? How can we measure these costs? It's 48 00:04:17,402 --> 00:04:24,857 not obvious. Moreover, who has the rights here? Should the factory have to pay to 49 00:04:24,857 --> 00:04:30,521 pollute? Should it have to pay the people to whom it imposes an external cost or 50 00:04:30,521 --> 00:04:35,496 should the bystanders have to pay the factory not to pollute? Does the factory 51 00:04:35,496 --> 00:04:40,117 have the right not to pollute and do the bystanders have to pay the factory to 52 00:04:40,117 --> 00:04:42,791 stop? If you think that's obvious, 53 00:04:42,791 --> 00:04:47,070 let's consider a flu shot. There are external benefits if I get 54 00:04:47,250 --> 00:04:51,690 a flu shot for example I'm less likely to sneeze on people on the subway and give 55 00:04:51,870 --> 00:04:56,880 them the flu but that could be hundreds, dozens of people, hundreds of people. I 56 00:04:57,060 --> 00:05:01,740 don't know exactly which people get the external benefit and how much is this 57 00:05:01,920 --> 00:05:08,050 external benefit? It's hard to measure once again. Moreover, should people have 58 00:05:08,230 --> 00:05:15,930 to pay me to get a flu shot or should I have to pay others if I don't get a shot. 59 00:05:16,110 --> 00:05:19,800 Now by the way let's compare these two things, the pollution and the flu shot. If 60 00:05:19,980 --> 00:05:24,850 you thought it was obvious that the factory should have to pay to pollute and 61 00:05:25,030 --> 00:05:30,800 not that the bystanders should have to pay the factory. Well consider the flu shot, 62 00:05:30,980 --> 00:05:35,970 isn't sneezing, if you don't get a flu shot isn't sneezing, isn't that like 63 00:05:36,150 --> 00:05:41,970 pollution? Isn't that polluting? Shouldn't the polluter, the sneezer have to pay? So 64 00:05:42,150 --> 00:05:47,100 in that case you might want to argue that if you don't get a flu shot, you should 65 00:05:47,280 --> 00:05:52,900 have to pay others. You're polluting on them. Right? So the rights here are not as 66 00:05:53,080 --> 00:05:58,810 obvious as we might think at first glance. Moreover the main point is, is that the 67 00:05:58,990 --> 00:06:02,490 transactions costs of coming to an agreement between these hundreds or 68 00:06:02,670 --> 00:06:06,950 thousands or perhaps millions of people figuring out what the external costs are 69 00:06:07,130 --> 00:06:12,280 making that bargain. That's going to be very costly and we 70 00:06:12,460 --> 00:06:16,510 can't even agree on who has the rights here or it's very difficult to come to an 71 00:06:16,690 --> 00:06:21,710 agreement. Should the factory have to pay? Should the factory be the one to be paid? 72 00:06:21,890 --> 00:06:26,960 Should the person getting the flu shot be paid, or should the person not getting the 73 00:06:27,140 --> 00:06:32,990 flu shot have to pay? The rights here are uncertain, and unclear and again that's 74 00:06:33,170 --> 00:06:38,370 also going to make coming to a market agreement difficult to do and therefore 75 00:06:38,550 --> 00:06:43,347 the market isn't going to solve these types of externality problems very easily. 76 00:06:43,347 --> 00:06:48,750 So the conclusion here is that the market can be efficient even when there are 77 00:06:48,930 --> 00:06:53,540 externalities when transactions costs are low and when property rights are clearly 78 00:06:53,720 --> 00:06:59,000 defined and in fact that's the Coase Theorem. If transactions costs are low and 79 00:06:59,180 --> 00:07:03,580 property rights are clearly defined private bargains will insure that the 80 00:07:03,760 --> 00:07:08,990 market equilibrium is efficient even if there are externalities. 81 00:07:09,170 --> 00:07:12,920 The conditions for the Coase Theorem to be met low transactions costs and clear 82 00:07:13,100 --> 00:07:19,550 property rights are in practice often not met. Even so, however the theorem does 83 00:07:19,730 --> 00:07:24,010 suggest an alternative approach to externalities. We've already looked at the 84 00:07:24,400 --> 00:07:29,270 Pigovian taxes and subsidies, and command and control. The Coase Theorem suggests 85 00:07:29,450 --> 00:07:37,080 another solution namely the creation of new markets. If the government can define 86 00:07:37,260 --> 00:07:43,650 property rights and reduce transactions costs then markets can be used to control 87 00:07:43,830 --> 00:07:48,690 externality problems. So the Coase Theorem plus a little bit of command and control 88 00:07:48,870 --> 00:07:53,200 in terms of defining property rights and reducing transactions costs can create a 89 00:07:53,380 --> 00:07:59,630 new form of solution to externality problems and in fact tradable permits is 90 00:07:59,810 --> 00:08:02,445 what we're going to be looking at in the next talk. 91 00:08:02,445 --> 00:08:07,770 - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself, click "Practice Questions" or 92 00:08:07,950 --> 00:08:11,557 if you're ready to move on, just click "Next Video." 93 00:08:11,557 --> 00:08:14,500 ♪ [music] ♪