Return to Video

Weak and strong natural monopoly

  • 0:02 - 0:04
    Let's now consider the theory of natural monopoly
  • 0:04 - 0:09
    and the difference between what is often called weak and strong natural monopoly
  • 0:11 - 0:14
    Common examples of natural monopoly are,
  • 0:14 - 0:18
    electricity distribution systems, and water piping systems,
  • 0:18 - 0:23
    but often the concept of natural monopoly is used somewhat loosely or impressionistically.
  • 0:23 - 0:27
    Does it mean that in a market setting there would just be a single producer?
  • 0:28 - 0:31
    Or does it mean that there should just be a single producer.
  • 0:31 - 0:38
    Well, we're going to look at this a little more rigorously and break down the concept of natural monopoly into two different cases.
  • 0:39 - 0:45
    And as mentioned those cases will be strong natural monopoly and weak natural monopoly.
  • 0:45 - 0:57
    As we will see this difference will relate to whether average cost AC is decreasing as the strong natural monopoly or in weak natural monopoly AC is increasing.
  • 0:58 - 1:03
    We can define decreasing average costs by this equation here.
  • 1:03 - 1:07
    What this means is that as more units of the goods are produced,
  • 1:07 - 1:11
    the average cost of producing each unit falls
  • 1:11 - 1:13
    So you could also put this on a graph,
  • 1:13 - 1:19
    and here would be average cost, and as q is increasing, Ac is going down.
  • 1:19 - 1:25
    And of course this could be true across some range of the output, but not all ranges of the output
  • 1:25 - 1:30
    so this is defined across some particular range namely where the market will be.
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    Now let's consider the concept of subadditivity.
  • 1:34 - 1:40
    We can write subadditivity as follows, with a cost function here we have cost
  • 1:40 - 1:47
    and in parentheses we have a sum of q super script i, close parentheses,
  • 1:47 - 1:54
    being less than or equal to another sub here, c q super script i.
  • 1:55 - 2:01
    What the left hand side portrays here is simply the cost of producing all those units in a single firm.
  • 2:02 - 2:10
    What the right hand side portrays is the cost of taking those units and say producing them through using ten little different firms.
  • 2:11 - 2:16
    And of subadditivity holds, well it's cheaper to produce that given quantity of ouput,
  • 2:16 - 2:18
    in the single larger firm.
  • 2:18 - 2:21
    In this setting, subadditivity is simply an assumption.
  • 2:21 - 2:24
    With that which we don't have natural monopoly at all.
  • 2:24 - 2:29
    Decreasing average cost is something which as we will see, may or may not hold.
  • 2:30 - 2:34
    By definition we have strong natural monopoly
  • 2:34 - 2:39
    when both assumptions hold, and thus we are considering the case of decreasing average cost.
  • 2:39 - 2:41
    We can draw that case like this,
  • 2:41 - 2:46
    so here we have a demand curve, we have the marginal revenue curve,
  • 2:46 - 2:48
    we have an average cost curve
  • 2:48 - 2:50
    and we have a marginal cost curve,
  • 2:50 - 2:55
    and what's striking about this picture is that if we were too set price at marginal cost,
  • 2:56 - 3:00
    right here, well that would be normally the efficient price,
  • 3:00 - 3:04
    but at that price, you can see that average cost is above price
  • 3:05 - 3:08
    so if average cost is greater than price,
  • 3:08 - 3:12
    then the firm is earning profits which are less than zero,
  • 3:12 - 3:14
    or the firm is suffering loses.
  • 3:15 - 3:20
    In these cases, due to subadditvity in both strong and weak natural monopolies,
  • 3:20 - 3:24
    it is cheapest for a single firm to supply all output
  • 3:25 - 3:27
    but the general question, which arises,
  • 3:27 - 3:29
    is a single firm sustainable?
  • 3:31 - 3:34
    Well, in the case of strong natural monopoly,
  • 3:34 - 3:36
    if we set prices equal to marginal cost,
  • 3:36 - 3:41
    the tradition optimality condition, we can see that a subsidy is needed.
  • 3:42 - 3:46
    Again you can see in this picture that where demand meets marginal cost,
  • 3:46 - 3:48
    average cost is above that point,
  • 3:48 - 3:52
    and its the subsidy that would be needed to make up that difference.
  • 3:52 - 3:57
    And if you're wondering by the way, how is it that average costs are getting to be higher than marginal costs,
  • 3:57 - 4:03
    well basically, it has to do with the presence of fixed costs in the production function.
  • 4:03 - 4:05
    Namely costs that must be incurred no matter what,
  • 4:05 - 4:07
    just to get the firm up and running.
  • 4:08 - 4:11
    Those fixed costs will not contribute to marginal costs
  • 4:11 - 4:13
    but they will make average costs higher.
  • 4:15 - 4:20
    Sometimes, the regulators will allow a firm to set price equal to average costs,
  • 4:20 - 4:24
    and then that means there will not be any subsidy needed for the firm,
  • 4:24 - 4:26
    This is done for a few reasons ,
  • 4:26 - 4:30
    one is simply that subsidies to firms are not politically popular,
  • 4:30 - 4:35
    but another reason is that subsidies to firms are often distorting or cause corruption,
  • 4:35 - 4:38
    or there's a problem, how do you know how much subsidy to send to the firm?
  • 4:38 - 4:42
    What do you do, just call up the firm and ask, "Hey, what's your cost curve?"
  • 4:42 - 4:45
    Well, they're probably going to lie to you, to get a higher subsidy.
  • 4:45 - 4:51
    So in practice, with regulation, prices equals marginal costs under strong monopoly
  • 4:51 - 4:58
    is not always attainable and often the regulators settle for something more in the neighborhood of price equals average costs.
  • 4:59 - 5:02
    We'll now consider the case of weak natural monopoly
  • 5:02 - 5:04
    where subadditivity agains holds
  • 5:04 - 5:07
    but we do not have decreasing average cost.
  • 5:08 - 5:10
    Rather, we have increasing average cost.
  • 5:11 - 5:19
    The important mathematical point here is that for AC to be rising, marginal costs has to be greater than average cost
  • 5:19 - 5:25
    that is, you only get an average to be rising by tacking on some larger numbers to that average.
  • 5:25 - 5:28
    But if marginal costs is greater than average cost,
  • 5:28 - 5:31
    and we're going to be trying to set prices equal to marginal cost,
  • 5:31 - 5:35
    then indeed price itself will be greater than average cost
  • 5:35 - 5:38
    and the firm will earn profits rather than suffering loses.
  • 5:39 - 5:45
    We can see here in this diagram that, that price equal to marginal cost
  • 5:45 - 5:50
    that is indeed above average cost, and thus profits will be greater than zero.
  • 5:50 - 5:53
    The good news is, we don't need that subsidy anymore.
  • 5:53 - 5:58
    The bad news, that we have a new problem, and that is entry is possible
  • 5:58 - 6:02
    and that conceivably could raise total production costs.
  • 6:02 - 6:06
    So the new firms, they engage in what is sometimes called cream skimming
  • 6:06 - 6:10
    namely trying to serve the most profitable segments of the market,
  • 6:10 - 6:13
    and leaving the initial enterent to cover all the others
  • 6:13 - 6:17
    It's sometimes claimed for instance, if we opened the US Postal Service
  • 6:17 - 6:22
    to full private competition you might get say, three or four suppliers
  • 6:22 - 6:26
    mostly fighting over the lucrative urban segments of the market.
  • 6:26 - 6:31
    What you would have is three or four different firms, varying those fixed costs
  • 6:31 - 6:32
    we talked about.
  • 6:32 - 6:36
    because of subadditivity this may not be socially efficient
  • 6:36 - 6:42
    to be having three or four different firms paying the fixed costs of setting up a delivery network
  • 6:42 - 6:43
    yet because of the struggle,
  • 6:43 - 6:47
    over these profits based on monopoly or market power
  • 6:47 - 6:50
    maybe, that's what you would get, at least according to this theory.
  • 6:52 - 6:54
    So what does this look like?
  • 6:54 - 6:56
    Well here you would imagine a bunch of firms,
  • 6:56 - 6:59
    fighting over the top portion of this demand curve,
  • 6:59 - 7:02
    the consumer surplus, for people who demand service the most,
  • 7:02 - 7:06
    and the people who use this model to favor entry restrictions,
  • 7:06 - 7:08
    well they focus on the fixed cost.
  • 7:08 - 7:13
    They say you would have here, say three different firms varying those blocks of fixed costs
  • 7:13 - 7:15
    to set up a delivery network,
  • 7:15 - 7:19
    as opposed to the one, possibly state protected monopolist,
  • 7:19 - 7:23
    and that is an argument for creating a state protected monopolist.
  • 7:24 - 7:27
    Other economists will accept the logic of this view,
  • 7:27 - 7:37
    but they come to a different policy conclusion, they place a lot of stress on innovation, and also the dynamic benefits of competition.
  • 7:37 - 7:43
    So they understand that by having three competitors, as here you will pay more in terms of fixed costs,
  • 7:43 - 7:46
    but over the longer run you'll have more innovation,
  • 7:46 - 7:49
    saying how packages are delivered and tracked,
  • 7:49 - 7:55
    and the benefits of that dynamic competition will out weigh the initial payment of fire to fixed costs.
  • 7:55 - 8:00
    And these individuals would argue, then that we should allow a competitive market to operate,
  • 8:00 - 8:03
    and how you will make this judgment call depends on,
  • 8:03 - 8:06
    how important you think the fixed costs are,
  • 8:06 - 8:10
    compared to these factors of innovation and dynamic competition.
  • 8:10 - 8:15
    But in any case, sits the theory of weak natural monopoly, which helps you see this trade off.
  • 8:17 - 8:20
    There are plenty of places where you can pursue these topics,
  • 8:20 - 8:24
    one route to go is simply to study specific sectors and industries,
  • 8:24 - 8:28
    but more generally, you can google strong weak natural monopoly.
  • 8:28 - 8:31
    Also google natural monopoly regulation.
  • 8:31 - 8:34
    And here's a very useful source, it's not online, it's not free,
  • 8:35 - 8:37
    but it's a very good book, and it's called,
  • 8:37 - 8:39
    "Natural Monopoly Regulation".
Title:
Weak and strong natural monopoly
Description:

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Other videos
Duration:
08:53

English subtitles

Revisions