1 00:00:06,817 --> 00:00:09,617 Imagine we want to build a new space port 2 00:00:09,617 --> 00:00:13,200 at one of four recently settled Martian bases, 3 00:00:13,200 --> 00:00:16,650 and are holding a vote to determine its location. 4 00:00:16,650 --> 00:00:23,482 Of the hundred colonists on Mars, 42 live on West Base, 26 on North Base, 5 00:00:23,482 --> 00:00:28,252 15 on South Base, and 17 on East Base. 6 00:00:28,252 --> 00:00:32,342 For our purposes, let’s assume that everyone prefers the space port 7 00:00:32,342 --> 00:00:37,155 to be as close to their base as possible, and will vote accordingly. 8 00:00:37,155 --> 00:00:40,445 What is the fairest way to conduct that vote? 9 00:00:40,445 --> 00:00:44,400 The most straightforward solution would be to just let each individual 10 00:00:44,400 --> 00:00:48,750 cast a single ballot, and choose the location with the most votes. 11 00:00:48,750 --> 00:00:54,119 This is known as plurality voting, or "first past the post." 12 00:00:54,119 --> 00:00:57,179 In this case, West Base wins easily, 13 00:00:57,179 --> 00:00:59,791 since it has more residents than any other. 14 00:00:59,791 --> 00:01:04,031 And yet, most colonists would consider this the worst result, 15 00:01:04,031 --> 00:01:07,045 given how far it is from everyone else. 16 00:01:07,045 --> 00:01:12,099 So is plurality vote really the fairest method? 17 00:01:12,099 --> 00:01:15,939 What if we tried a system like instant runoff voting, 18 00:01:15,939 --> 00:01:19,265 which accounts for the full range of people’s preferences 19 00:01:19,265 --> 00:01:21,591 rather than just their top choices? 20 00:01:21,591 --> 00:01:23,131 Here’s how it would work. 21 00:01:23,131 --> 00:01:27,001 First, voters rank each of the options from 1 to 4, 22 00:01:27,001 --> 00:01:29,651 and we compare their top picks. 23 00:01:29,651 --> 00:01:34,348 South receives the fewest votes for first place, so it’s eliminated. 24 00:01:34,348 --> 00:01:39,716 Its 15 votes get allocated to those voters’ second choice— 25 00:01:39,716 --> 00:01:43,666 East Base— giving it a total of 32. 26 00:01:43,666 --> 00:01:49,177 We then compare top preferences and cut the last place option again. 27 00:01:49,177 --> 00:01:51,357 This time North Base is eliminated. 28 00:01:51,357 --> 00:01:54,926 Its residents’ second choice would’ve been South Base, 29 00:01:54,926 --> 00:01:59,190 but since that’s already gone, the votes go to their third choice. 30 00:01:59,190 --> 00:02:05,390 That gives East 58 votes over West’s 42, making it the winner. 31 00:02:05,390 --> 00:02:08,090 But this doesn’t seem fair either. 32 00:02:08,090 --> 00:02:11,806 Not only did East start out in second-to-last place, 33 00:02:11,806 --> 00:02:16,280 but a majority ranked it among their two least preferred options. 34 00:02:16,280 --> 00:02:20,867 Instead of using rankings, we could try voting in multiple rounds, 35 00:02:20,867 --> 00:02:25,057 with the top two winners proceeding to a separate runoff. 36 00:02:25,057 --> 00:02:29,120 Normally, this would mean West and North winning the first round, 37 00:02:29,120 --> 00:02:30,848 and North winning the second. 38 00:02:30,848 --> 00:02:33,509 But the residents of East Base realize 39 00:02:33,509 --> 00:02:36,029 that while they don’t have the votes to win, 40 00:02:36,029 --> 00:02:39,369 they can still skew the results in their favor. 41 00:02:39,369 --> 00:02:43,289 In the first round, they vote for South Base instead of their own, 42 00:02:43,289 --> 00:02:46,299 successfully keeping North from advancing. 43 00:02:46,299 --> 00:02:50,059 Thanks to this "tactical voting" by East Base residents, 44 00:02:50,059 --> 00:02:55,177 South wins the second round easily, despite being the least populated. 45 00:02:55,177 --> 00:02:59,762 Can a system be called fair and good if it incentivizes lying 46 00:02:59,762 --> 00:03:01,712 about your preferences? 47 00:03:01,712 --> 00:03:05,511 Maybe what we need to do is let voters express a preference 48 00:03:05,511 --> 00:03:08,676 in every possible head-to-head matchup. 49 00:03:08,676 --> 00:03:11,671 This is known as the Condorcet method. 50 00:03:11,671 --> 00:03:15,203 Consider one matchup: West versus North. 51 00:03:15,203 --> 00:03:18,713 All 100 colonists vote on their preference between the two. 52 00:03:18,713 --> 00:03:23,516 So that's West's 42 versus the 58 from North, South, and East, 53 00:03:23,516 --> 00:03:25,731 who would all prefer North. 54 00:03:25,731 --> 00:03:29,066 Now do the same for the other five matchups. 55 00:03:29,066 --> 00:03:32,661 The victor will be whichever base wins the most times. 56 00:03:32,661 --> 00:03:36,622 Here, North wins three and South wins two. 57 00:03:36,622 --> 00:03:40,082 These are indeed the two most central locations, 58 00:03:40,082 --> 00:03:45,659 and North has the advantage of not being anyone’s least preferred choice. 59 00:03:45,659 --> 00:03:50,846 So does that make the Condorcet method an ideal voting system in general? 60 00:03:50,846 --> 00:03:53,176 Not necessarily. 61 00:03:53,176 --> 00:03:55,877 Consider an election with three candidates. 62 00:03:55,877 --> 00:04:01,541 If voters prefer A over B, and B over C, but prefer C over A, 63 00:04:01,541 --> 00:04:04,151 this method fails to select a winner. 64 00:04:04,151 --> 00:04:08,027 Over the decades, researchers and statisticians have come up with 65 00:04:08,027 --> 00:04:12,057 dozens of intricate ways of conducting and counting votes, 66 00:04:12,057 --> 00:04:14,840 and some have even been put into practice. 67 00:04:14,840 --> 00:04:16,737 But whichever one you choose, 68 00:04:16,737 --> 00:04:21,508 it's possible to imagine it delivering an unfair result. 69 00:04:21,508 --> 00:04:25,128 It turns out that our intuitive concept of fairness 70 00:04:25,128 --> 00:04:29,590 actually contains a number of assumptions that may contradict each other. 71 00:04:29,590 --> 00:04:33,910 It doesn’t seem fair for some voters to have more influence than others. 72 00:04:33,910 --> 00:04:38,253 But nor does it seem fair to simply ignore minority preferences, 73 00:04:38,253 --> 00:04:41,419 or encourage people to game the system. 74 00:04:41,419 --> 00:04:45,453 In fact, mathematical proofs have shown that for any election 75 00:04:45,453 --> 00:04:47,243 with more than two options, 76 00:04:47,243 --> 00:04:51,023 it’s impossible to design a voting system that doesn’t violate 77 00:04:51,023 --> 00:04:55,513 at least some theoretically desirable criteria. 78 00:04:55,513 --> 00:05:00,030 So while we often think of democracy as a simple matter of counting votes, 79 00:05:00,030 --> 00:05:05,463 it’s also worth considering who benefits from the different ways of counting them.