Return to Video

An Introduction to Externalities

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:11
    - [Prof. Alex Tabarrok]
    In previous videos,
  • 0:11 - 0:14
    we've emphasized
    that a price is a signal
  • 0:14 - 0:16
    wrapped up in an incentive,
  • 0:16 - 0:18
    and that prices
    coming out of free markets
  • 0:18 - 0:20
    coordinate individual actions
  • 0:20 - 0:23
    in just such a way
    that the outcome
  • 0:23 - 0:27
    looks as if it were created
    by a benevolent invisible hand.
  • 0:28 - 0:31
    We've shown how price controls
    can impede this process.
  • 0:31 - 0:33
    And what we want to show now
  • 0:33 - 0:35
    is that even with the free market,
  • 0:35 - 0:38
    sometimes the price isn't right.
  • 0:38 - 0:41
    In particular,
    when we have externalities --
  • 0:41 - 0:43
    external costs,
    and external benefits,
  • 0:43 - 0:45
    which I'll define more
    in just a few minutes --
  • 0:45 - 0:48
    then the price isn't right.
  • 0:48 - 0:50
    So what we want to do in this video
  • 0:50 - 0:53
    is show both the causes
    and the consequences
  • 0:53 - 0:56
    of external costs
    and external benefits.
  • 0:56 - 0:57
    Let's get going.
  • 1:01 - 1:04
    Let's begin with the rise
    of the super bugs.
  • 1:04 - 1:08
    These are bacteria which are now
    resistant to our antibiotics.
  • 1:08 - 1:11
    Before the age of the antibiotic,
  • 1:11 - 1:15
    even a simple skin cut
    or a bruise or scrape
  • 1:15 - 1:17
    could kill people
    due to the infection.
  • 1:17 - 1:19
    And people
    who were more seriously injured,
  • 1:19 - 1:21
    for example in battle,
  • 1:21 - 1:23
    most of them died
  • 1:23 - 1:24
    not because of their battle wounds,
  • 1:24 - 1:28
    but because of infection
    which took place after the wound,
  • 1:28 - 1:30
    because of the wound.
  • 1:30 - 1:32
    In the 20th century,
  • 1:32 - 1:36
    the miracle of antibiotics
    meant that far, far fewer people
  • 1:36 - 1:38
    died from these infections.
  • 1:38 - 1:41
    But that miracle
    is now coming to an end,
  • 1:41 - 1:43
    as our antibiotics
  • 1:43 - 1:46
    are no longer as effective
    as they once were.
  • 1:46 - 1:48
    Why is this happening?
  • 1:48 - 1:50
    Well, part of the problem
  • 1:50 - 1:54
    is that no antibiotic
    is always 100% effective.
  • 1:54 - 1:57
    And bacteria,
    like people, are diverse.
  • 1:57 - 2:00
    They have different strengths
    and different weaknesses.
  • 2:01 - 2:04
    The bacteria which are
    not killed by an antibiotic --
  • 2:04 - 2:06
    which happen to have
    certain characteristics
  • 2:06 - 2:10
    which make them strong
    against that antibiotic --
  • 2:10 - 2:12
    those bacteria
    propagate and survive
  • 2:12 - 2:14
    and become more dominant.
  • 2:14 - 2:19
    So, the evolutionary process
    has led to resistance.
  • 2:20 - 2:23
    We, however, are not
    entirely innocent in this process.
  • 2:23 - 2:29
    Resistance has been helped
    by the overuse of antibiotics.
  • 2:29 - 2:32
    So why are antibiotics overused?
  • 2:32 - 2:34
    The fundamental reason
  • 2:34 - 2:36
    is that users get all the benefits
  • 2:36 - 2:40
    but do not bear all of the costs
    of antibiotic use.
  • 2:40 - 2:42
    Each use of an antibiotic
  • 2:42 - 2:45
    creates a small increase
    in bacterial resistance,
  • 2:45 - 2:47
    at least in a probabilistic sense.
  • 2:47 - 2:51
    But bacteria don't stay
    in one place or one body.
  • 2:51 - 2:53
    They spread
    throughout the environment
  • 2:53 - 2:54
    and indeed throughout that world.
  • 2:54 - 2:59
    So an increase, that cost,
    that increase in bacterial resistance
  • 2:59 - 3:01
    is a cost borne by everyone,
  • 3:01 - 3:04
    not just the user
    of the antibiotic.
  • 3:05 - 3:07
    We can think of using an antibiotic
  • 3:07 - 3:09
    as creating a little bit of pollution,
  • 3:09 - 3:11
    of polluting the environment
  • 3:11 - 3:14
    with more resistant
    and stronger bacteria.
  • 3:14 - 3:17
    This is true when somebody,
    for example,
  • 3:17 - 3:19
    uses an antibiotic
    when they have a virus
  • 3:19 - 3:21
    which the antibiotic
    doesn't help with,
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    rather than
    when they have bacteria.
  • 3:24 - 3:25
    That's a cost.
  • 3:25 - 3:28
    It's a cost because
    that use of the antibiotic
  • 3:28 - 3:30
    then generates more resistance,
  • 3:30 - 3:33
    and that resistance
    spreads around the world.
  • 3:33 - 3:36
    Farmers who use antibiotics,
  • 3:36 - 3:38
    not to combat disease
    in their livestock,
  • 3:38 - 3:41
    but to help
    the livestock grow faster,
  • 3:41 - 3:45
    also create more
    bacterial resistance.
  • 3:45 - 3:49
    But that resistance
    is something they don't include
  • 3:49 - 3:51
    in their calculus of costs.
  • 3:51 - 3:52
    They don't pay attention
  • 3:52 - 3:55
    to those costs
    which are borne by other people.
  • 3:56 - 3:57
    When antibiotic users
  • 3:57 - 4:02
    ignore the external costs
    of their choices,
  • 4:02 - 4:04
    we get overuse.
  • 4:04 - 4:07
    Since some costs are ignored
    by the decision makers,
  • 4:07 - 4:10
    we get overuse of antibiotics.
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    Okay, well,
    with that as an introduction,
  • 4:12 - 4:14
    let's define some terms.
  • 4:14 - 4:15
    Private cost --
  • 4:15 - 4:19
    this is the cost paid
    by the consumer or the producer.
  • 4:19 - 4:21
    External cost --
  • 4:21 - 4:24
    this is a cost paid by bystanders,
  • 4:24 - 4:27
    by people other than
    the consumer or the producer.
  • 4:27 - 4:30
    It's a cost paid by people
    other than those
  • 4:30 - 4:32
    who are buying or selling
  • 4:32 - 4:34
    in this particular market.
  • 4:34 - 4:37
    The social cost
    is the cost to everyone --
  • 4:37 - 4:39
    the cost when we take into account
  • 4:39 - 4:42
    consumers, producers
    and bystanders.
  • 4:42 - 4:44
    In other words,
  • 4:44 - 4:47
    it's the private cost
    plus the external cost.
  • 4:48 - 4:49
    Externalities --
  • 4:49 - 4:52
    this is simply another word
    for external costs
  • 4:52 - 4:54
    or external benefits.
  • 4:54 - 4:57
    We'll talk more about
    external benefits in a future talk.
  • 4:57 - 5:00
    In other words, externalities
    is just another word
  • 5:00 - 5:04
    for costs or benefits
    that fall on bystanders.
  • 5:05 - 5:07
    When there are
    significant external costs
  • 5:07 - 5:09
    or external benefits,
  • 5:09 - 5:12
    a market will not
    maximize social surplus.
  • 5:12 - 5:14
    Now, remember we showed earlier
  • 5:14 - 5:17
    that a market maximizes
    consumer surplus
  • 5:17 - 5:19
    plus producer surplus.
  • 5:19 - 5:21
    That's always true
    for a free market.
  • 5:21 - 5:23
    However, what we've just learned
  • 5:23 - 5:28
    is that an external cost
    is a cost that falls on bystanders,
  • 5:28 - 5:30
    not on consumers or producers.
  • 5:30 - 5:34
    So social surplus,
    which is consumer surplus
  • 5:34 - 5:37
    plus producer surplus
    plus bystander surplus --
  • 5:37 - 5:40
    that's ultimately
    really what we care about.
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    We care about not just
    about consumers and producers,
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    we care about everyone
    including bystanders.
  • 5:46 - 5:49
    So we want
    to maximize social surplus.
  • 5:49 - 5:50
    However,
  • 5:50 - 5:53
    when there are significant
    external costs or benefits,
  • 5:53 - 5:56
    the market is not going to
    maximize social surplus.
  • 5:56 - 5:58
    It's going to maximize
    consumer surplus
  • 5:58 - 6:00
    plus producer surplus.
  • 6:00 - 6:02
    But that's not everything.
  • 6:02 - 6:05
    When the costs
    and the benefits to bystanders
  • 6:05 - 6:07
    are not counted,
  • 6:07 - 6:10
    then we're not going to
    maximize social surplus.
  • 6:10 - 6:13
    In fact, we can say things
    a little bit more precisely,
  • 6:13 - 6:17
    and we'll do that next
    with a supply and demand diagram.
  • 6:17 - 6:19
    Okay, here's our standard diagram
  • 6:19 - 6:21
    with the quantity of antibiotics
    on the horizontal axis
  • 6:21 - 6:24
    and prices and costs
    on the vertical axis.
  • 6:24 - 6:26
    As usual, the equilibrium is found
  • 6:26 - 6:28
    where demand intersects supply,
  • 6:28 - 6:31
    or where quantity demanded
    is equal to quantity supplied.
  • 6:31 - 6:33
    Now the key point here
  • 6:33 - 6:37
    is that the supply curve
    is based on private cost --
  • 6:37 - 6:40
    basically the cost
    of producing the antibiotic.
  • 6:40 - 6:42
    But there's another cost.
  • 6:42 - 6:46
    Every time an antibiotic
    is produced and consumed
  • 6:46 - 6:49
    there's a cost
    of bacterial resistance,
  • 6:49 - 6:53
    a cost borne by all of us,
    by bystanders.
  • 6:53 - 6:55
    There's an external cost
  • 6:55 - 6:59
    and that is not taken
    into account by the suppliers.
  • 6:59 - 7:03
    So this external cost
    doesn't go into the price.
  • 7:03 - 7:06
    Nevertheless,
    what we really care about
  • 7:06 - 7:09
    is the social cost
    of antibiotic use,
  • 7:09 - 7:12
    not just the cost
    of producing the antibiotic,
  • 7:12 - 7:14
    but also the cost
    of actually using it,
  • 7:14 - 7:16
    including the external cost.
  • 7:16 - 7:20
    So, the market equilibrium,
    the market quantity,
  • 7:20 - 7:23
    is found where the market
    demand and supply curves intersect.
  • 7:23 - 7:26
    But the true efficient equilibrium,
  • 7:26 - 7:29
    the equilibrium
    we would like to be at,
  • 7:29 - 7:34
    is where the demand curve
    intersects the social cost curve.
  • 7:34 - 7:36
    So, the efficient quantity
  • 7:36 - 7:41
    is less than the market quantity,
    thus we have overuse.
  • 7:41 - 7:44
    The market doesn't
    take into account
  • 7:44 - 7:48
    all of the costs of antibiotic use
  • 7:48 - 7:50
    so we get overuse
  • 7:50 - 7:52
    relative to
    the efficient equilibrium.
  • 7:52 - 7:55
    Now we can actually show this
    in another way.
  • 7:55 - 8:00
    Let's look at the value
    of the marginal unit,
  • 8:00 - 8:02
    the value of the unit,
    the market unit,
  • 8:02 - 8:05
    the last unit the market produces.
  • 8:05 - 8:08
    What's the private value,
    what's the value of this unit?
  • 8:08 - 8:11
    Well, it's given by the height
    of the demand curve.
  • 8:11 - 8:14
    Now, what is the cost
    of that marginal unit,
  • 8:14 - 8:17
    of that last unit consumed?
  • 8:17 - 8:20
    Well, the private cost is given
    by the private supply curve,
  • 8:20 - 8:27
    but the social cost is given
    by the much higher social cost curve.
  • 8:27 - 8:29
    So notice on that last unit,
  • 8:29 - 8:35
    the cost of that last unit
    is much larger than the value.
  • 8:35 - 8:38
    That's the sense
    in which we have overuse.
  • 8:38 - 8:44
    We don't really want
    to produce this last unit
  • 8:44 - 8:46
    because the cost
    is greater than the value.
  • 8:46 - 8:49
    Indeed, if we don't
    want to produce this unit,
  • 8:49 - 8:53
    we don't to produce any unit
  • 8:53 - 8:56
    where the social cost
    is greater than the value.
  • 8:56 - 8:59
    So in other words,
  • 8:59 - 9:02
    this area right here
    is a deadweight loss.
  • 9:02 - 9:04
    These are the units
  • 9:04 - 9:05
    for which the social cost
    is greater than the private value.
  • 9:05 - 9:07
    Therefore, these are the units
    we don't want to produce --
  • 9:07 - 9:12
    this is the deadweight loss
  • 9:12 - 9:15
    and this is the overuse
    of the antibiotic.
  • 9:15 - 9:19
    What conclusions can we make? When there
    are external costs, output should be
  • 9:19 - 9:24
    reduced to maximize social surplus.
    Another way of thinking about this is for
  • 9:24 - 9:29
    determining the efficient level of output,
    who bears the cost is irrelevant. The fact
  • 9:29 - 9:34
    that these costs are borne by bystanders
    is irrelevant - we want to take into
  • 9:34 - 9:40
    account all costs, not just the cost to the
    suppliers. The problem is, is that when
  • 9:40 - 9:45
    other people bear some of the cost of
    production, the price is too low.
  • 9:45 - 9:52
    Not all of the costs are reflected in the
    price. As a result, the price is sending
  • 9:52 - 9:57
    the wrong signal. It's incentivizing too
    much production. Because the price is too
  • 9:58 - 10:04
    low, antibiotic users purchase too
    many antibiotics and we get overuse.
  • 10:04 - 10:09
    The solution to this, or one solution to
    this, is in what's called a Pigouvian tax -
  • 10:10 - 10:16
    a tax on a good with external costs. Let's
    take a look at how that works. The idea of
  • 10:16 - 10:20
    a Pigouvian tax after the economist
    Arthur Pigou first talked about these
  • 10:20 - 10:25
    ideas, is pretty simple. The market
    equilibrium is down here. The efficient
  • 10:25 - 10:32
    equilibrium is here. The problem is that
    the suppliers aren't taking into account
  • 10:32 - 10:36
    all the costs of their production. They're
    not taking into account these external
  • 10:36 - 10:42
    costs. So how could we get these suppliers
    to take into account all of the costs of
  • 10:42 - 10:49
    their production? Well, one way of doing
    it is to tax them. A Pigouvian tax equal
  • 10:50 - 10:56
    to the external cost makes the private
    cost plus the tax, the total private cost,
  • 10:56 - 10:58
    equal to the social cost.
  • 10:58 - 11:03
    Let's remember how we can analyze a tax.
    Remember that one of the ways to analyze a
  • 11:03 - 11:09
    tax is to shift the supply curve up by the
    amount of the tax. So, if we impose a tax
  • 11:10 - 11:16
    on the suppliers equal to the external
    cost the supply curve will shift up until
  • 11:16 - 11:24
    the private cost plus the tax is equal to
    the social cost. In this case, we will now
  • 11:24 - 11:29
    have the efficient equilibrium will be the
    same as the market equilibrium. The market
  • 11:29 - 11:36
    will internalize the externality. All of
    the costs, private cost plus the tax equal
  • 11:36 - 11:41
    to the external cost, will come to be
    reflected in the price. And because all of
  • 11:41 - 11:46
    the costs are reflected in the price,
    consumers will buy the efficient quantity
  • 11:46 - 11:48
    of the good.
  • 11:48 - 11:54
    So, that's one way to handle an external
    cost problem. In the next couple of
  • 11:54 - 11:58
    lectures we'll be talking about external
    benefits, and we'll also illustrate some
  • 11:58 - 12:01
    other ways in which externalities
    can be handled.
  • 12:01 - 12:07
    - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself
    click “Practice Questions.” Or, if you're
  • 12:07 - 12:10
    ready to move on just click “Next Video.”
  • 12:10 - 12:12
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
An Introduction to Externalities
Description:

What are externalities and what are the different kinds of costs? And what does this have to do with the rise of “superbugs"? This video is an introduction to externalities, including the concepts of private cost, external cost, and social cost. Using the example of antibiotics and viruses, we take a look at how costs are passed along to different members of society beyond the producer and consumer. We’ll use a chart to illustrate how to calculate the effects of a Pigouvian tax, and we provide definitions for the other key terms that will be used throughout this video series.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/externalities-definition-pigovian-tax#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/flu-shot-positive-externalities-pigovian-subsidy

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
12:15

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions