Return to Video

An Introduction to Externalities

  • 0:02 - 0:05
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:10 - 0:14
    - [Alex] In previous videos, we've
    emphasized that a price is a signal
  • 0:14 - 0:19
    wrapped up in an incentive and that prices
    coming out of free markets coordinate
  • 0:19 - 0:26
    individual actions in just such a way that
    the outcome looks as if it were created by
  • 0:26 - 0:32
    a benevolent invisible hand. We've shown
    how price controls can impede the price
  • 0:32 - 0:37
    and what we want to show now is that even
    with the free market sometimes the price
  • 0:37 - 0:43
    isn't right. In particular, when we have
    externalities, external cost, and external
  • 0:43 - 0:48
    benefits, which I'll define more in just a
    few minutes, then the price isn't right.
  • 0:49 - 0:53
    So what we want to do in this video is
    show both the causes and the consequences
  • 0:53 - 0:58
    of external costs and external benefits.
    Let's get going.
  • 1:01 - 1:06
    Let's begin with the rise of the super
    bugs. These are bacteria which are now
  • 1:06 - 1:12
    resistant to our antibiotics. Before the
    age of the antibiotic, even a simple skin
  • 1:13 - 1:18
    cut or a bruise or scrape could kill
    people due to the infection. And people
  • 1:18 - 1:23
    who are more seriously injured, for
    example, in battle most of them died not
  • 1:23 - 1:27
    because of their battle wounds, but
    because of infection which took place
  • 1:28 - 1:30
    after the wound, because of the wound.
  • 1:30 - 1:36
    In the 20th century, the miracle of
    antibiotics meant that far, far fewer
  • 1:36 - 1:42
    people died from these infections. But
    that miracle is now coming to an end, as
  • 1:42 - 1:49
    our antibiotics are no longer as effective
    as they once were. Why is this happening?
  • 1:49 - 1:55
    Part of the problem is that no antibiotic
    is always 100% effective. And
  • 1:55 - 1:59
    bacteria, like people, are diverse. They
    have different strengths and different
  • 1:59 - 2:01
    weaknesses.
  • 2:01 - 2:05
    The bacteria which are not killed by an
    antibiotic which happen to have certain
  • 2:06 - 2:11
    characteristics which make them strong
    against that antibiotic. Those bacteria
  • 2:11 - 2:17
    propagate and survive and become more
    dominant. So, the evolutionary process has
  • 2:17 - 2:20
    led to resistance.
  • 2:20 - 2:26
    We however, are not entirely innocent in
    this process. Resistance has been helped
  • 2:26 - 2:33
    by the overuse of antibiotics. So why are
    antibiotics overused? The fundamental
  • 2:33 - 2:37
    reason is that users get all the benefits
    but do not bear all of the
  • 2:38 - 2:44
    costs of antibiotic use. Each use of an
    antibiotic creates a small increase in
  • 2:44 - 2:48
    bacterial resistance, at least in a
    probabilistic sense. But bacteria don't
  • 2:49 - 2:53
    stay in one place or one body, they spread
    throughout the environment and indeed
  • 2:53 - 2:58
    throughout that world. So an increase that
    cost, that increase in bacterial
  • 2:58 - 3:05
    resistance is a cost borne by everyone,
    not just the user of the antibiotic.
  • 3:05 - 3:10
    We can think of using an antibiotic as
    creating a little bit of pollution, of
  • 3:10 - 3:15
    polluting the environment with more
    resistant and stronger bacteria. This is
  • 3:15 - 3:20
    true when somebody, for example, uses an
    antibiotic when they have a virus which
  • 3:20 - 3:24
    the antibiotic doesn't help with rather
    than when they have bacteria. That's a
  • 3:24 - 3:31
    cost. It's a cost because that use of the
    antibiotic then generates more resistance
  • 3:31 - 3:36
    and that resistance spreads around the
    world. Farmers who use antibiotics not to
  • 3:36 - 3:42
    combat disease in their livestock but to
    help the livestock grow faster, also
  • 3:42 - 3:49
    create more bacterial resistance. But that
    resistance is something they don't include
  • 3:49 - 3:54
    in their calculus of cost. They don't pay
    attention to those costs which are borne
  • 3:54 - 3:56
    by other people.
  • 3:56 - 4:01
    When antibiotic users ignore the external
    cost
  • 4:01 - 4:06
    of their choices we get overuse. Since
    some costs are ignored by the decision
  • 4:07 - 4:12
    makers we get overuse of antibiotics.
    Okay, well, with that as an introduction,
  • 4:13 - 4:15
    let's define some terms. Private cost:
  • 4:15 - 4:21
    this is the cost paid by the consumer or
    the producer. External cost:
  • 4:21 - 4:26
    this is a cost paid by bystanders, by
    people other than the consumer or the
  • 4:26 - 4:32
    producer. It's a cost paid by people other
    than those who are buying or selling in
  • 4:32 - 4:35
    this particular market. The social cost
  • 4:35 - 4:41
    is the cost to everyone. The cost when
    we take into account consumers, producers
  • 4:41 - 4:48
    and bystanders. In other words, it's the
    private cost plus the external cost.
  • 4:48 - 4:49
    Externalities:
  • 4:49 - 4:54
    this is simply another word for external
    cost or external benefits. We'll talk
  • 4:55 - 4:59
    more about external benefits in a future
    talk. In other words, externalities is
  • 4:59 - 5:05
    just another word for cost or benefits
    that fall on bystanders.
  • 5:05 - 5:10
    When there are significant external costs
    or external benefits a market will not
  • 5:10 - 5:15
    maximize social surplus. Now, remember we
    showed earlier that a market maximizes
  • 5:15 - 5:21
    consumer surplus plus producer surplus.
    That's always true for a free market.
  • 5:21 - 5:27
    However, what we've just learned is that
    an external cost is a cost that falls on
  • 5:27 - 5:33
    bystanders, not on consumers or producers.
    So, social surplus which is consumer
  • 5:33 - 5:38
    surplus plus producer surplus plus
    bystander surplus. That's ultimately
  • 5:39 - 5:42
    really what we care about. We care about
    not just about consumers and producers, we
  • 5:43 - 5:49
    care about everyone including bystanders.
    So we want to maximize social surplus.
  • 5:50 - 5:54
    However, when there are significant
    external costs or benefits, the market is
  • 5:54 - 5:58
    not going to maximize social surplus. It's
    going to maximize consumer surplus plus
  • 5:59 - 6:02
    producer surplus. But that's not
    everything. When the
  • 6:02 - 6:08
    costs and the benefits to bystanders
    are not counted, then we're not going to
  • 6:08 - 6:13
    maximize social surplus. In fact, we can
    say things a little bit more precisely,
  • 6:14 - 6:18
    and we'll do that next with a supply and
    demand diagram. Okay, here's our standard
  • 6:19 - 6:22
    diagram with the quantity of antibiotics
    on the horizontal axis and prices and
  • 6:22 - 6:27
    costs on the vertical axis. As usual, the
    equilibrium is found where demand
  • 6:27 - 6:32
    intersects supply, where quantity demanded
    is equal to quantity supplied. Now the key
  • 6:32 - 6:38
    point here is that the supply curve is
    based on private cost, basically the
  • 6:38 - 6:42
    cost of producing the antibiotic. But
    there's another cost.
  • 6:42 - 6:49
    Every time an antibiotic is produced and
    consumed there's a cost of bacterial
  • 6:49 - 6:55
    resistance. A cost borne by all of us, by
    bystanders. There's an external cost and
  • 6:55 - 7:02
    that is not taken into account by the
    suppliers. So this external cost doesn't
  • 7:02 - 7:08
    go into the price. Nevertheless, what we
    really care about is the social cost of
  • 7:08 - 7:13
    antibiotic use, not just the cost of
    producing the antibiotic but also the cost
  • 7:13 - 7:19
    of actually using it, including the
    external cost. So, the market equilibrium,
  • 7:19 - 7:24
    the market quantity, is found where the
    market demand and supply curves intersect.
  • 7:24 - 7:30
    But the true efficient equilibrium, the
    equilibrium we would like to be at, is
  • 7:30 - 7:35
    where the demand curve intersects the
    social cost curve. So, the efficient
  • 7:35 - 7:42
    quantity is less than the market quantity,
    thus we have overuse.
  • 7:42 - 7:49
    The market doesn't take into account all
    of the costs of antibiotic use so we get
  • 7:49 - 7:55
    overuse relative to the efficient
    equilibrium. Now we can actually show this
  • 7:55 - 8:00
    in another way. Let's look at the value of
    the marginal unit,
  • 8:00 - 8:05
    the value of the unit, the market unit,
    the last unit the market produces. What's
  • 8:05 - 8:10
    the private value, what's the value of
    this unit? Well, it's given by the height
  • 8:10 - 8:16
    of the demand curve. Now, what is the cost
    of that marginal unit, of that last unit
  • 8:16 - 8:21
    consumed? Well, the private cost is given
    by the private supply curve, but the
  • 8:21 - 8:29
    social cost is given by the much higher
    social cost curve. So notice on that last
  • 8:29 - 8:36
    unit, the cost of that last unit is much
    larger than the value. That's the sense in
  • 8:36 - 8:38
    which we have overuse.
  • 8:38 - 8:44
    We don't really want to produce this last
    unit because the cost is greater than the
  • 8:44 - 8:49
    value. Indeed, if we don't want to produce
    this unit, we don't to produce any unit
  • 8:49 - 8:55
    where the social cost is greater than the
    value. So in other words, this area right
  • 8:56 - 9:02
    here is a deadweight loss. These are the
    units for which the social cost is greater
  • 9:02 - 9:06
    than the private value, therefore, these
    are the units we don't want to produce.
  • 9:07 - 9:14
    This is the deadweight loss and this is
    the overuse of the antibiotic.
  • 9:15 - 9:19
    What conclusions can we make? When there
    are external costs, output should be
  • 9:19 - 9:24
    reduced to maximize social surplus.
    Another way of thinking about this is, for
  • 9:24 - 9:29
    determining the efficient level of output.
    Who bears the cost is irrelevant. The fact
  • 9:29 - 9:34
    that these costs are borne by bystanders
    is irrelevant, we want to take into
  • 9:34 - 9:40
    account all costs not just the cost of the
    suppliers. The problem is, is that when
  • 9:40 - 9:45
    other people bear some of the cost of
    production, the price is too low.
  • 9:45 - 9:52
    Not all of the costs are reflected in the
    price. As a result, the price is sending
  • 9:52 - 9:57
    the wrong signal. It's incentivizing too
    much production. Because the price is too
  • 9:58 - 10:04
    low, antibiotic users purchase too many
    antibiotics and we get overuse.
  • 10:04 - 10:09
    The solution to this or one solution to
    this is in what's called a Pigouvian tax.
  • 10:10 - 10:16
    A tax on a good with external costs. Let's
    take a look at how that works. The idea of
  • 10:16 - 10:20
    a Pigouvian tax after the economist
    Arthur Pigou, first talked about these
  • 10:20 - 10:25
    ideas is pretty simple. The market
    equilibrium is down here. The efficient
  • 10:25 - 10:32
    equilibrium is here. The problem is that
    the suppliers aren't taking into account
  • 10:32 - 10:36
    all the costs of their production. They're
    not taking into account these external
  • 10:36 - 10:42
    costs. So how could we get these suppliers
    to take into account all of the costs of
  • 10:42 - 10:49
    their production? Well, one way of doing
    it is to tax them, a Pigouvian tax equal
  • 10:50 - 10:56
    to the external cost makes the private
    cost plus the tax, the total private cost,
  • 10:56 - 10:58
    equal to the social cost.
  • 10:58 - 11:03
    Let's remember how we can analyze a tax.
    Remember that one of the ways to analyze a
  • 11:03 - 11:09
    tax is to shift the supply curve up by the
    amount of the tax. So, if we impose a tax
  • 11:10 - 11:16
    on the suppliers equal to the external
    cost the supply curve will shift up until
  • 11:16 - 11:24
    the private cost plus the tax is equal to
    the social cost. In this case, we will now
  • 11:24 - 11:29
    have the efficient equilibrium will be the
    same as the market equilibrium. The market
  • 11:29 - 11:36
    will internalize the externality. All of
    the costs, private cost plus the tax equal
  • 11:36 - 11:41
    to the external cause will come to be
    reflected in the price, and because all of
  • 11:41 - 11:46
    the costs are reflected in the price
    consumers will buy the efficient quantity
  • 11:46 - 11:48
    of the good.
  • 11:48 - 11:54
    So, that's one way to handle an external
    cost problem. In the next couple of
  • 11:54 - 11:58
    lectures, we'll be talking about external
    benefits and we'll also illustrate some
  • 11:58 - 12:01
    other ways in which externalities can be
    handled
  • 12:01 - 12:07
    - [male] If you want to test yourself
    click Practice Questions. Or, if you're
  • 12:07 - 12:10
    ready to move on just click Next Video.
  • 12:10 - 12:12
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
An Introduction to Externalities
Description:

What are externalities and what are the different kinds of costs? And what does this have to do with the rise of “superbugs"? This video is an introduction to externalities, including the concepts of private cost, external cost, and social cost. Using the example of antibiotics and viruses, we take a look at how costs are passed along to different members of society beyond the producer and consumer. We’ll use a chart to illustrate how to calculate the effects of a Pigouvian tax, and we provide definitions for the other key terms that will be used throughout this video series.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/externalities-definition-pigovian-tax#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/flu-shot-positive-externalities-pigovian-subsidy

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
12:15

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions