Return to Video

The Monopoly Markup

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:13
    - [Alex] In a competitive market, we know that
    price is equal to marginal cost and
  • 0:13 - 0:17
    equilibrium. In a market where the
    monopoly we now know that price will be
  • 0:17 - 0:23
    greater than marginal cost. But how much
    greater? What determines the markup? What
  • 0:23 - 0:28
    we're going to show in this talk is that
    the monopoly markup depends upon the
  • 0:28 - 0:38
    elasticity of demand. Okay, let's do a
    very brief review where we ended up last
  • 0:38 - 0:42
    time. Everything on this diagram should
    now be familiar. We know how to find the
  • 0:42 - 0:46
    marginal revenue curve as a curve starting
    out on the vertical axis at the same point
  • 0:46 - 0:50
    as the demand curve with twice the slope.
    We know that the profit maximizing
  • 0:50 - 0:54
    quantity is found where marginal revenue
    is equal to marginal cost. And we know
  • 0:54 - 0:59
    that we read the profit maximizing price
    as the highest price that people are
  • 0:59 - 1:04
    willing to pay per unit for that quantity,
    in this case that's $12.50. The monopoly
  • 1:04 - 1:10
    markup is the difference between price and
    marginal cost. We know that in a
  • 1:10 - 1:14
    competitive market, price would be equal to
    marginal cost. Here in equilibrium we have
  • 1:14 - 1:19
    price is much greater than marginal cost,
    that's a monopoly markup. And we can also
  • 1:20 - 1:25
    read off this diagram, total profits for
    the monopolist which are above normal
  • 1:25 - 1:30
    profits. And profits are the difference
    between price and average cost times the
  • 1:30 - 1:35
    quantity, which is this shaded area. Okay,
    that's a review. Now let's give some
  • 1:35 - 1:44
    intuition for what determines the size of
    the monopoly markup. For intuition, let's
  • 1:44 - 1:48
    go to our case of a pharmaceutical. Two
    effects are going to increase the monopoly
  • 1:49 - 1:54
    markup in this case. First, the "you can't
    take it with you" effect. Namely, people
  • 1:54 - 2:00
    with serious illnesses are going to be
    relatively insensitive to the price of
  • 2:00 - 2:04
    life saving medicine. You can't take it
    with you so may as well spend all you have
  • 2:04 - 2:08
    trying to save your life.
    If the price of a life saving medicine
  • 2:08 - 2:16
    goes up, the quantity demanded isn't going
    to go down very much. Since the customers
  • 2:16 - 2:20
    are insensitive to the price, the
    monopolist is going to say, "Hey, I can
  • 2:20 - 2:24
    increase the price and they're still going
    to buy, so I should increase the price. It
  • 2:25 - 2:30
    would be profit maximizing for me to
    increase the price. " Another effect, the
  • 2:30 - 2:35
    "other people's money" effect. If somebody
    else is paying for the medicine, the user,
  • 2:36 - 2:39
    the consumer is going to be less sensitive
    to the price. And we know for
  • 2:39 - 2:43
    pharmaceuticals often the insurance
    company or Medicaid or Medicare or a
  • 2:43 - 2:47
    government program, they're going to be
    paying for the pharmaceutical, so that the
  • 2:47 - 2:51
    person who is demanding the pharmaceutical
    they're not paying the price. So even when
  • 2:51 - 2:55
    the price goes up they're still going to
    ask for the pharmaceutical, the quantity
  • 2:55 - 3:02
    demanded isn't going to go down very much.
    So the conclusion here is that the less
  • 3:02 - 3:08
    sensitive quantity demanded is to price,
    the higher the markup is going to be. If
  • 3:08 - 3:12
    people aren't sensitive to the price the
    monopolist is going to say, "Great. I can
  • 3:12 - 3:19
    jack up the price and still sell almost as
    much as I did before." In other words, the
  • 3:19 - 3:26
    more inelastic the demand curve the higher
    the markup, and that's our basic lesson.
  • 3:26 - 3:30
    Now that we have the intuition, let's test
    it with some diagrams, some demand curves.
  • 3:30 - 3:34
    We have two demand curves. Which is more
    elastic, the demand curve on the right or
  • 3:34 - 3:43
    on the left? The demand curve on the left
    is more elastic. The demand curve on the right
  • 3:43 - 3:50
    is more inelastic. So going by our
    intuition we should expect a low markup on
  • 3:50 - 3:56
    the left and a high markup on the right.
    We know how to find the profit maximizing
  • 3:56 - 4:01
    prices and quantities so let's do that.
    First, starting on the left.
  • 4:01 - 4:06
    What we see is that when the demand curve
    is relatively elastic we get a small
  • 4:07 - 4:13
    markup of price over marginal cost. What
    about on the right? Well now we have a
  • 4:13 - 4:19
    relatively inelastic demand curve and what
    we see is that price rises well above
  • 4:19 - 4:25
    marginal cost. We have a relatively
    inelastic demand and we get a big markup.
  • 4:25 - 4:32
    Notice the marginal cost for these two
    markets is the same. What differs is that
  • 4:32 - 4:38
    the demand curve over here on the right is
    more inelastic. Remember the logic: the
  • 4:38 - 4:45
    monopolist sees the consumers are
    insensitive to price. So it knows that if
  • 4:45 - 4:51
    it raises price, the quantity demanded will
    fall by only a little. Therefore, an
  • 4:51 - 4:56
    increase in price will increase the
    monopolist's profits, that's what it wants
  • 4:56 - 5:00
    so the monopolist will increase the price
    and you get a big markup of price over
  • 5:00 - 5:07
    marginal cost. Remember also that for a
    competitive firm, the demand for its
  • 5:07 - 5:14
    product is perfectly elastic and in that
    case price is equal to marginal cost. So
  • 5:14 - 5:19
    it makes sense that the more elastic the
    demand curve is for a monopolist, the
  • 5:19 - 5:24
    closer the pricing decision of the
    monopolist is to that of a competitive
  • 5:24 - 5:29
    firm. So when the demand curve for the
    monopolist is relatively elastic, price is
  • 5:29 - 5:35
    going to be close to marginal cost. The
    more elastic the demand curve gets for the
  • 5:35 - 5:42
    monopolist, the closer the monopolist's
    profit maximizing output is to that of a
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    competitive firm. Price gets closer to
    marginal cost. Okay, very good. Again
  • 5:46 - 5:52
    remember, big lesson, the more inelastic
    demand, the bigger the markup. Let's now
  • 5:52 - 5:58
    try to see if we can use our theory to
    solve a pricing puzzle. I recently looked
  • 5:58 - 6:02
    at some flights on American Airlines and
    what I found was that a flight from
  • 6:02 - 6:08
    Washington to Dallas was more expensive
    than a flight from Washington to San
  • 6:08 - 6:11
    Francisco.
    Now, there's two things which are puzzling
  • 6:11 - 6:16
    about that. First, San Francisco if
    obviously much farther from Washington
  • 6:16 - 6:21
    than is Dallas, so you'd expect that cost,
    fuel cost and so forth, to be higher.
  • 6:21 - 6:26
    Second, the puzzle is even deeper because
    the flight from Washington to San
  • 6:26 - 6:33
    Francisco ran through Dallas. In fact, the
    Washington to Dallas segment of the
  • 6:33 - 6:39
    Washington to San Francisco flight was
    exactly the same flight as the Washington
  • 6:39 - 6:46
    to Dallas flight. So why would one segment
    of the Washington to San Francisco flight
  • 6:46 - 6:53
    be more expensive than the entire flight?
    The answer requires knowing something
  • 6:53 - 6:57
    about how airlines are structured in the
    United States. Most of the airlines have a
  • 6:58 - 7:03
    hub airport, often near the center of the
    country, that's dominated by one particular
  • 7:03 - 7:07
    airline. In case of American Airlines,
    it's Dallas. In the case of United, it's
  • 7:07 - 7:13
    Chicago. Northwest dominates Minnesota,
    St. Paul, and so forth. What this means is
  • 7:13 - 7:18
    that if you want to fly to Dallas at a
    convenient time, you're much more likely
  • 7:18 - 7:23
    to find a good flight on American Airlines
    than on another airline. And if you want
  • 7:23 - 7:27
    to fly to Minneapolis, St. Paul, it's going
    to be much more convenient to fly
  • 7:27 - 7:33
    Northwest and so forth. Okay, does that
    give you any ideas about solving the
  • 7:33 - 7:38
    puzzle? Think about someone flying from
    Washington to Dallas, what options do they
  • 7:39 - 7:47
    have? Not many. There are few substitutes.
    And few substitutes means inelastic
  • 7:47 - 7:52
    demand. Now think about someone flying
    from Washington to San Francisco. What
  • 7:52 - 7:58
    options do they have? Well, they have
    lots. They could fly through Chicago or
  • 7:58 - 8:02
    they could fly through Denver or
    Minneapolis, St. Paul or they could fly
  • 8:02 - 8:06
    direct.
    There are many more good options of flying
  • 8:06 - 8:13
    from Washington to San Francisco since San
    Francisco isn't a hub city. So what do we
  • 8:13 - 8:18
    see? Well, we see that the demand for the
    Washington to San Francisco flight is
  • 8:18 - 8:23
    going to be relatively elastic and the
    demand for the Washington to Dallas flight
  • 8:23 - 8:29
    is relatively inelastic. And what our
    theory tells us is that with the elastic
  • 8:29 - 8:36
    demand, we get a low markup. With the
    inelastic demand, we get a high markup. So
  • 8:36 - 8:39
    the theory is completely consistent with
    this pricing puzzle
  • 8:39 - 8:42
    and it explains the puzzle.
  • 8:42 - 8:47
    - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,
    click "Practice Questions." Or if you're
  • 8:47 - 8:51
    ready to move on, just click "Next Video."
Title:
The Monopoly Markup
Description:

Ever wonder why pharmaceuticals are so expensive? In this video, we show how low elasticity of demand results in monopoly markups. This is especially the case with goods that involve the “you can’t take it with you” effect (for example, people with serious medical conditions are relatively insensitive to the price of life-saving drugs) and the “other people’s money” effect (if third parties pay for the medicine, people are less sensitive to price).

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/monopoly-markup-elasticity#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/costs-benefits-monopoly-pharmaceutical-companies

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
08:55

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions