Return to Video

The Balance of Industries and Creative Destruction

  • 0:00 - 0:06
    ♪[music]♪
  • 0:09 - 0:13
    - We turn now to the second of our
    invisible hand properties, the balance of
  • 0:13 - 0:23
    industries. We're also going to look at
    the gales of creative destruction.
  • 0:23 - 0:27
    Invisible hand property number one says
    that the production of any given quantity
  • 0:28 - 0:32
    of a good will be allocated across the
    firms in that industry in a way that
  • 0:33 - 0:39
    minimizes total costs. But the question is
    how much should be produced in each
  • 0:39 - 0:42
    industry? So invisible hand property
    number one says if we're going to be
  • 0:42 - 0:46
    producing 200 bushels of wheat that we
    could be rest assured that if we have a
  • 0:47 - 0:52
    competitive market, those 200 bushels will
    be allocated across the different firms in
  • 0:52 - 0:58
    a way that minimizes total industry cost.
    But should we be producing 200 bushels of
  • 0:58 - 1:04
    wheat or 500 or 1000? How should wheat be
    compared with corn or automobiles or
  • 1:04 - 1:11
    books? It's the second question about how
    the production of goods are balanced
  • 1:11 - 1:17
    across industries that invisible hand
    property number two is all about. In order
  • 1:17 - 1:22
    to maximize the value of resources, we
    want each industry to produce the right
  • 1:22 - 1:28
    quantity, not too much wheat and not too
    little wheat, but just the right amount.
  • 1:29 - 1:36
    And entry or exit is what ensures that
    labor and capital move across industries
  • 1:36 - 1:40
    so the production is optimally balanced
    and the greatest use is made of our
  • 1:41 - 1:46
    limited resources. And here to show this
    we actually don't need to use any more
  • 1:46 - 1:50
    techniques, we just need to sort of
    reinterpret some of the things which we've
  • 1:50 - 1:56
    already done. Let's take a look. Profit is
    the signal that allocates capital and
  • 1:56 - 2:03
    labor across industries in just such a way
    that maximizes total value. So remember,
  • 2:04 - 2:08
    if price is bigger than average cost that
    means that profits are above normal. Now
  • 2:08 - 2:13
    what does above normal profit mean?
    It means that the output of this industry
  • 2:13 - 2:18
    is worth more than the inputs.
    The profit signal is saying
  • 2:18 - 2:22
    we want more of this good.
    This good is worth more
  • 2:22 - 2:26
    than the labor and capital
    being used to create this good,
  • 2:26 - 2:32
    therefore produce more of it. So the
    profit signals and incentivizes capital
  • 2:32 - 2:39
    and labor to enter this industry, that is
    to move from a low value industry to a
  • 2:39 - 2:44
    high value industry. Similarly if price
    is less than average cost, that means
  • 2:45 - 2:49
    profits are below normal. That means that
    output in this industry is worth less than
  • 2:50 - 2:58
    the inputs. So the loss signal is saying
    we want less of this good. Loss signals
  • 2:58 - 3:04
    and incentivizes capital and labor to exit
    the industry, that is to move from a low
  • 3:05 - 3:12
    value industry where there are losses to a
    high or a higher value industry. Because
  • 3:12 - 3:19
    of this entering and exiting, the profit
    rate in all competitive industries tends
  • 3:19 - 3:25
    towards the same level and that is what
    balances production across all industries
  • 3:25 - 3:31
    to maximize the total value of production.
    If profit were higher in one industry than
  • 3:32 - 3:36
    in another, that says that the output of
    that industry is worth more, therefore we
  • 3:36 - 3:42
    should have more of that good. And that's
    exactly what the entry signal does and the
  • 3:42 - 3:48
    same thing is true for exit. Let's discuss
    some implications of following these
  • 3:48 - 3:52
    profit and loss signals. First,
    the elimination principle.
  • 3:52 - 3:58
    Above normal profits are eliminated
    by entry and below normal profits
  • 3:58 - 4:03
    are eliminated by exit. So resources
    are always tending to move
  • 4:03 - 4:06
    towards an increase
    in the value of production
  • 4:06 - 4:11
    and entrepreneurs here are key.
    It's entrepreneurs who move resources from
  • 4:11 - 4:18
    unprofitable industries towards profitable
    industries. Another implication of this is
  • 4:18 - 4:24
    that above normal profits are always
    temporary. To earn above normal profits,
  • 4:24 - 4:29
    you've got to do something different.
    You have to innovate.
  • 4:29 - 4:33
    Joseph Schumpeter, the great Austrian
    economist was very eloquent
  • 4:33 - 4:37
    on the importance of innovation
    in a capitalist economy.
  • 4:37 - 4:40
    He said in the textbooks
    we say what competition is. It's
  • 4:40 - 4:45
    all about pushing prices down to average
    cost and creating normal profits. But in
  • 4:45 - 4:50
    capitalist reality as distinguished from
    its textbook picture, the kind of
  • 4:51 - 4:55
    competition that counts is competition
    from the new commodity, the new
  • 4:55 - 5:00
    technology, the new source of supply, the
    new type of organization. Competition
  • 5:00 - 5:05
    which strikes not at the margins of the
    profits and the outputs of the existing
  • 5:05 - 5:12
    firms but at their very foundations and
    their very lives. This process of creative
  • 5:12 - 5:18
    destruction is the essential fact about
    capitalism. Great statement from Joseph
  • 5:18 - 5:25
    Schumpeter. Now the invisible hand is
    marvelous but it's not miraculous. The
  • 5:25 - 5:31
    invisible hand works when we have certain
    institutions. It doesn't always work. In
  • 5:31 - 5:37
    particular, the invisible hand will not
    work if prices do not accurately signal
  • 5:37 - 5:42
    cost and benefits. If prices don't
    accurately signal cost and benefits, we
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    won't get an optimal balance between
    industries. And later on when we come to
  • 5:46 - 5:52
    talk about externalities, we'll present
    certain situations when prices aren't
  • 5:52 - 5:58
    going to be signaling accurately. Second,
    the invisible hand works best when markets
  • 5:58 - 6:02
    are competitive. When markets are not
    competitive, when we have monopoly and
  • 6:03 - 6:07
    oligopoly, this isn't going to work as
    well and we'll be talking more about this
  • 6:07 - 6:10
    in future chapters but you can get the
    right idea by thinking about the
  • 6:10 - 6:18
    following. Monopolists and oligopolists
    will earn above normal profits but entry
  • 6:18 - 6:23
    won't push those profits down. That's why
    they're monopolists and oligopolists
  • 6:23 - 6:29
    because entry isn't working. Because those
    profits aren't pushed down, we'll have too
  • 6:29 - 6:34
    little of that profitable good produced.
    We'll be talking more about this
  • 6:35 - 6:40
    in future chapters. Again this is just a
    little bit of a reminder that the
  • 6:40 - 6:45
    invisible hand requires a certain set of
    institutions in order for it to work. So
  • 6:45 - 6:50
    just to summarize, invisible hand property
    one says that the P equals MC condition
  • 6:51 - 6:55
    results in the minimization of total
    industry costs. Invisible hand property
  • 6:55 - 7:01
    two is that entry and exits result in the
    best use of our limited resources. The
  • 7:02 - 7:07
    elimination principle says that above
    normal profits are temporary and indeed to
  • 7:07 - 7:11
    earn above normal profits a firm must
    innovate. And this is where the importance
  • 7:12 - 7:16
    of creative destruction for a capitalist
    economy comes from. If you really want to
  • 7:17 - 7:21
    profit a lot you've got to do something
    different. You've got to bring something
  • 7:21 - 7:24
    new to the table. You have to bring in
    innovation.
  • 7:24 - 7:29
    - [male voice] If you want to test
    yourself, click Practice Questions,
  • 7:29 - 7:36
    or if you're ready to move on,
    just click Next Video.
Title:
The Balance of Industries and Creative Destruction
Description:

Why are price signals and market competition so important to a market economy? When prices accurately signal costs and benefits and markets are competitive, the Invisible Hand ensures that costs are minimized and production is maximized. If these conditions aren’t met, market inefficiencies arise and the Invisible Hand cannot do its work. In this video, we show how two major processes, creative destruction and the elimination principle, work with the Invisible Hand to create a competitive marketplace that works for producers and consumers.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/creative-destruction-definition-elimination-principle#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/monopoly-profit-maximization-price-aids-medication

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
07:38

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions