Return to Video

Perspective is everything | Rory Sutherland | TEDxAthens

  • 0:13 - 0:14
    What you have here
  • 0:14 - 0:17
    is an electronic cigarette.
  • 0:18 - 0:20
    It's something that's,
  • 0:20 - 0:22
    since it was invented a year or two ago,
  • 0:22 - 0:23
    has given me untold happiness.
  • 0:23 - 0:25
    (Laughter)
  • 0:25 - 0:27
    A little bit of it, I think,
    is the nicotine,
  • 0:27 - 0:29
    but there's something
    much bigger than that.
  • 0:29 - 0:34
    Which is ever since, in the U.K.,
    they banned smoking in public places,
  • 0:34 - 0:37
    I've never enjoyed
    a drinks party ever again.
  • 0:37 - 0:39
    (Laughter)
  • 0:39 - 0:42
    And the reason,
    I only worked out just the other day,
  • 0:42 - 0:44
    which is when you go to a drinks party
  • 0:44 - 0:47
    and you stand up
    and you hold a glass of red wine
  • 0:47 - 0:48
    and you talk endlessly to people,
  • 0:48 - 0:51
    you don't actually want to spend
    all the time talking.
  • 0:51 - 0:52
    It's really, really tiring.
  • 0:52 - 0:55
    Sometimes you just want
    to stand there silently,
  • 0:55 - 0:57
    alone with your thoughts.
  • 0:57 - 1:01
    Sometimes you just want to stand
    in the corner and stare out of the window.
  • 1:01 - 1:04
    Now the problem is, when you can't smoke,
  • 1:04 - 1:07
    if you stand and stare
    out of the window on your own,
  • 1:08 - 1:10
    you're an antisocial, friendless idiot.
  • 1:10 - 1:12
    (Laughter)
  • 1:12 - 1:16
    If you stand and stare out of the window
    on your own with a cigarette,
  • 1:16 - 1:18
    you're a fucking philosopher.
  • 1:18 - 1:20
    (Laughter)
  • 1:20 - 1:23
    (Applause)
  • 1:27 - 1:29
    So the power of reframing things
  • 1:31 - 1:34
    cannot be overstated.
  • 1:35 - 1:37
    What we have is exactly the same thing,
    the same activity,
  • 1:37 - 1:40
    but one of them makes you feel great
  • 1:40 - 1:43
    and the other one,
    with just a small change of posture,
  • 1:43 - 1:46
    makes you feel terrible.
  • 1:46 - 1:49
    And I think one of the problems
    with classical economics
  • 1:49 - 1:51
    is it's absolutely preoccupied
    with reality.
  • 1:51 - 1:56
    And reality isn't a particularly
    good guide to human happiness.
  • 1:56 - 1:58
    Why, for example,
  • 1:58 - 2:01
    are pensioners much happier
  • 2:01 - 2:03
    than the young unemployed?
  • 2:03 - 2:07
    Both of them, after all,
    are in exactly the same stage of life.
  • 2:07 - 2:10
    You both have too much time
    on your hands and not much money.
  • 2:10 - 2:13
    But pensioners are reportedly
    very, very happy,
  • 2:13 - 2:17
    whereas the unemployed are extraordinarily
    unhappy and depressed.
  • 2:17 - 2:20
    The reason, I think,
    is that the pensioners believe
  • 2:20 - 2:22
    they've chosen to be pensioners,
  • 2:22 - 2:26
    whereas the young unemployed
    feel it's been thrust upon them.
  • 2:26 - 2:29
    In England the upper middle classes
  • 2:29 - 2:31
    have actually solved
    this problem perfectly,
  • 2:31 - 2:33
    because they've re-branded unemployment.
  • 2:33 - 2:35
    If you're an upper-middle-class
    English person,
  • 2:35 - 2:38
    you call unemployment "a year off."
  • 2:38 - 2:40
    (Laughter)
  • 2:40 - 2:44
    And that's because having a son
    who's unemployed in Manchester
  • 2:44 - 2:45
    is really quite embarrassing,
  • 2:45 - 2:49
    but having a son
    who's unemployed in Thailand
  • 2:49 - 2:51
    is really viewed
    as quite an accomplishment.
  • 2:51 - 2:53
    (Laughter)
  • 2:53 - 2:55
    But actually the power
    to re-brand things -
  • 2:55 - 3:00
    to understand that actually
    our experiences, costs, things
  • 3:00 - 3:03
    don't actually much depend
    on what they really are,
  • 3:03 - 3:05
    but on how we view them -
  • 3:05 - 3:07
    I genuinely think can't be overstated.
  • 3:07 - 3:10
    There's an experiment
    I think Daniel Pink refers to
  • 3:10 - 3:13
    where you put two dogs in a box
  • 3:13 - 3:16
    and the box has an electric floor.
  • 3:18 - 3:22
    Every now and then an electric shock
    is applied to the floor,
  • 3:23 - 3:25
    which pains the dogs.
  • 3:26 - 3:30
    The only difference is one of the dogs
    has a small button in its half of the box.
  • 3:30 - 3:33
    And when it nuzzles the button,
    the electric shock stops.
  • 3:35 - 3:37
    The other dog doesn't have the button.
  • 3:37 - 3:41
    It's exposed to exactly the same level
    of pain as the dog in the first box,
  • 3:41 - 3:43
    but it has no control
    over the circumstances.
  • 3:45 - 3:48
    Generally the first dog
    can be relatively content.
  • 3:48 - 3:51
    The second dog lapses
    into complete depression.
  • 3:52 - 3:56
    The circumstances of our lives
    may actually matter less to our happiness
  • 3:56 - 4:00
    than the sense of control
    we feel over our lives.
  • 4:02 - 4:03
    It's an interesting question.
  • 4:03 - 4:07
    We ask the question -
    the whole debate in the Western world
  • 4:07 - 4:09
    is about the level of taxation.
  • 4:09 - 4:11
    But I think there's another debate
    to be asked,
  • 4:11 - 4:14
    which is the level of control
    we have over our tax money.
  • 4:15 - 4:19
    That what costs us 10 pounds
    in one context can be a curse.
  • 4:20 - 4:23
    What costs us 10 pounds
    in a different context
  • 4:23 - 4:25
    we may actually welcome.
  • 4:26 - 4:29
    You know, pay 20,000 pounds
    in tax toward health
  • 4:29 - 4:32
    and you're merely feeling a mug.
  • 4:32 - 4:35
    Pay 20,000 pounds to endow a hospital ward
  • 4:35 - 4:37
    and you're called a philanthropist.
  • 4:38 - 4:41
    I'm probably in the wrong country
    to talk about willingness to pay tax.
  • 4:41 - 4:43
    (Laughter)
  • 4:43 - 4:48
    So I'll give you one in return.
    How you frame things really matters.
  • 4:48 - 4:50
    Do you call it the bailout of Greece
  • 4:50 - 4:54
    or the bailout of a load of stupid banks
    which lent to Greece?
  • 4:55 - 4:57
    Because they are actually the same thing.
  • 4:57 - 4:59
    What you call them actually affects
  • 4:59 - 5:03
    how you react to them,
    viscerally and morally.
  • 5:03 - 5:06
    I think psychological value
    is great to be absolutely honest.
  • 5:06 - 5:09
    One of my great friends,
    a professor called Nick Chater,
  • 5:09 - 5:12
    who's the Professor of Decision Sciences
    in London,
  • 5:12 - 5:14
    believes that we should spend
    far less time
  • 5:14 - 5:16
    looking into humanity's hidden depths
  • 5:16 - 5:19
    and spend much more time
    exploring the hidden shallows.
  • 5:20 - 5:21
    I think that's true actually.
  • 5:21 - 5:24
    I think impressions have an insane effect
  • 5:24 - 5:26
    on what we think and what we do.
  • 5:27 - 5:30
    But what we don't have is a really good
    model of human psychology.
  • 5:30 - 5:32
    At least pre-Kahneman perhaps,
  • 5:32 - 5:35
    we didn't have a really good model
    of human psychology
  • 5:35 - 5:40
    to put alongside models of engineering,
    of neoclassical economics.
  • 5:40 - 5:44
    So people who believed in psychological
    solutions didn't have a model.
  • 5:44 - 5:46
    We didn't have a framework.
  • 5:46 - 5:49
    This is what Warren Buffett's
    business partner Charlie Munger calls
  • 5:49 - 5:51
    "a latticework
    on which to hang your ideas."
  • 5:52 - 5:55
    Engineers, economists,
    classical economists
  • 5:55 - 5:58
    all had a very, very robust
    existing latticework
  • 5:58 - 6:01
    on which practically every idea
    could be hung.
  • 6:01 - 6:04
    We merely have a collection
    of random individual insights
  • 6:04 - 6:07
    without an overall model.
  • 6:07 - 6:11
    And what that means
    is that in looking at solutions,
  • 6:11 - 6:14
    we've probably given too much priority
  • 6:14 - 6:18
    to what I call technical engineering
    solutions, Newtonian solutions,
  • 6:18 - 6:20
    and not nearly enough
    to the psychological ones.
  • 6:20 - 6:22
    You know my example of the Eurostar.
  • 6:22 - 6:25
    Six million pounds spent
    to reduce the journey time
  • 6:25 - 6:29
    between Paris and London
    by about 40 minutes.
  • 6:29 - 6:33
    For 0.01 percent of this money
    you could have put WiFi on the trains,
  • 6:33 - 6:36
    which wouldn't have reduced
    the duration of the journey,
  • 6:36 - 6:40
    but would have improved its enjoyment
    and its usefulness far more.
  • 6:41 - 6:43
    For maybe 10 percent of the money,
  • 6:43 - 6:46
    you could have paid all of the world's
    top male and female supermodels
  • 6:46 - 6:51
    to walk up and down the train handing out
    free Chateau Petrus to all the passengers.
  • 6:51 - 6:54
    You'd still have five [million] pounds
    in change,
  • 6:54 - 6:57
    and people would ask
    for the trains to be slowed down.
  • 6:57 - 6:59
    (Laughter)
  • 7:01 - 7:02
    Why were we not given the chance
  • 7:02 - 7:04
    to solve that problem psychologically?
  • 7:04 - 7:07
    I think it's because there's an imbalance,
    an asymmetry,
  • 7:08 - 7:12
    in the way we treat creative,
    emotionally-driven psychological ideas
  • 7:13 - 7:17
    versus the way we treat rational,
    numerical, spreadsheet-driven ideas.
  • 7:17 - 7:20
    If you're a creative person,
    I think quite rightly,
  • 7:20 - 7:22
    you have to share
    all your ideas for approval
  • 7:22 - 7:24
    with people much more rational than you.
  • 7:25 - 7:28
    You have to go in and you have to have
    a cost-benefit analysis,
  • 7:28 - 7:31
    a feasibility study,
    an ROI study and so forth.
  • 7:31 - 7:33
    And I think that's probably right.
  • 7:33 - 7:36
    But this does not apply
    the other way around.
  • 7:36 - 7:38
    People who have an existing framework,
  • 7:38 - 7:41
    an economic framework,
    an engineering framework,
  • 7:41 - 7:44
    feel that actually logic
    is its own answer.
  • 7:44 - 7:47
    What they don't say is,
    "Well the numbers all seem to add up,
  • 7:47 - 7:49
    but before I present this idea,
  • 7:49 - 7:51
    I'll go and show it
    to some really crazy people
  • 7:51 - 7:53
    to see if they can come up
    with something better."
  • 7:53 - 7:56
    And so we, artificially I think,
    prioritize
  • 7:56 - 8:00
    what I'd call mechanistic ideas
    over psychological ideas.
  • 8:00 - 8:02
    An example of a great psychological idea:
  • 8:02 - 8:05
    The single best improvement
    in passenger satisfaction
  • 8:05 - 8:08
    on the London Underground per pound spent
  • 8:08 - 8:12
    came when they didn't add any extra trains
    nor change the frequency of the trains,
  • 8:12 - 8:16
    they put dot matrix display boards
    on the platforms.
  • 8:17 - 8:18
    Because the nature of a wait
  • 8:18 - 8:22
    is not just dependent on its
    numerical quality, its duration,
  • 8:22 - 8:25
    but on the level of uncertainty
    you experience during that wait.
  • 8:25 - 8:28
    Waiting seven minutes for a train
    with a countdown clock
  • 8:28 - 8:30
    is less frustrating and irritating
  • 8:30 - 8:32
    than waiting four minutes, knuckle-biting
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    going, "When's this train
    going to damn well arrive?"
  • 8:36 - 8:38
    Here's a beautiful example
    of a psychological solution
  • 8:38 - 8:40
    deployed in Korea.
  • 8:40 - 8:43
    Red traffic lights have a countdown delay.
  • 8:43 - 8:46
    It's proven to reduce the accident rate
    in experiments.
  • 8:46 - 8:50
    Why? Because road rage,
    impatience and general irritation
  • 8:50 - 8:53
    are massively reduced
    when you can actually see
  • 8:53 - 8:55
    the time you have to wait.
  • 8:55 - 8:58
    In China, not really understanding
    the principle behind this,
  • 8:58 - 9:01
    they applied the same principle
    to green traffic lights.
  • 9:01 - 9:04
    (Laughter)
  • 9:05 - 9:06
    Which isn't a great idea.
  • 9:06 - 9:07
    You're 200 yards away,
  • 9:07 - 9:10
    you realize you've got five seconds to go,
    you floor it.
  • 9:10 - 9:13
    (Laughter)
  • 9:14 - 9:16
    The Koreans, very assiduously,
    did test both.
  • 9:16 - 9:19
    The accident rate goes down
    when you apply this to red traffic lights;
  • 9:19 - 9:22
    it goes up when you apply it
    to green traffic lights.
  • 9:22 - 9:25
    This is all I'm asking for really
    in human decision making,
  • 9:25 - 9:27
    is the consideration
    of these three things.
  • 9:27 - 9:30
    I'm not asking for the complete
    primacy of one over the other.
  • 9:30 - 9:32
    I'm merely saying
    that when you solve problems,
  • 9:32 - 9:35
    you should look
    at all three of these equally
  • 9:35 - 9:38
    and you should seek as far as possible
  • 9:38 - 9:41
    to find solutions which sit
    in the sweet spot in the middle.
  • 9:41 - 9:43
    If you actually look at a great business,
  • 9:43 - 9:47
    you'll nearly always see all of these
    three things coming into play.
  • 9:47 - 9:49
    Really, really successful businesses -
  • 9:49 - 9:52
    Google is a great,
    great technological success,
  • 9:52 - 9:55
    but it's also based
    on a very good psychological insight:
  • 9:56 - 9:59
    People believe something
    that only does one thing
  • 9:59 - 10:03
    is better at that thing than something
    that does that thing and something else.
  • 10:03 - 10:05
    It's an innate thing called goal dilution.
  • 10:05 - 10:08
    Ayelet Fishbach has written
    a paper about this.
  • 10:08 - 10:10
    Everybody else at the time of Google,
    more or less,
  • 10:10 - 10:12
    was trying to be a portal.
  • 10:12 - 10:13
    Yes, there's a search function,
  • 10:13 - 10:17
    but you also have weather,
    sports scores, bits of news.
  • 10:18 - 10:20
    Google understood
    that if you're just a search engine,
  • 10:20 - 10:23
    people assume you're a very,
    very good search engine.
  • 10:23 - 10:25
    All of you know this actually
  • 10:25 - 10:27
    from when you go in to buy a television.
  • 10:27 - 10:29
    And in the shabbier end
    of the row of flat screen TVs
  • 10:29 - 10:32
    you can see are these
    rather despised things
  • 10:32 - 10:35
    called combined TV and DVD players.
  • 10:35 - 10:39
    And we have no knowledge whatsoever
    of the quality of those things,
  • 10:39 - 10:42
    but we look at a combined TV
    and DVD player and we go, "Uck.
  • 10:42 - 10:46
    It's probably a bit of a crap telly
    and a bit rubbish as a DVD player."
  • 10:46 - 10:49
    So we walk out of the shops
    with one of each.
  • 10:49 - 10:54
    Google is as much a psychological success
    as it is a technological one.
  • 10:54 - 10:57
    I propose that we can use psychology
    to solve problems
  • 10:57 - 11:00
    that we didn't even realize
    were problems at all.
  • 11:00 - 11:03
    This is my suggestion for getting people
    to finish their course of antibiotics.
  • 11:03 - 11:05
    Don't give them 24 white pills.
  • 11:05 - 11:08
    Give them 18 white pills and six blue ones
  • 11:08 - 11:10
    and tell them to take
    the white pills first
  • 11:10 - 11:12
    and then take the blue ones.
  • 11:12 - 11:14
    It's called chunking.
  • 11:14 - 11:17
    The likelihood that people
    will get to the end is much greater
  • 11:17 - 11:19
    when there is a milestone
    somewhere in the middle.
  • 11:20 - 11:22
    One of the great mistakes,
    I think, of economics
  • 11:22 - 11:25
    is it fails to understand
    that what something is,
  • 11:25 - 11:28
    whether it's retirement,
    unemployment, cost,
  • 11:29 - 11:33
    is a function, not only of its amount,
    but also its meaning.
  • 11:33 - 11:36
    This is a toll crossing in Britain.
  • 11:37 - 11:40
    Quite often queues happen at the tolls.
  • 11:41 - 11:43
    Sometimes you get very,
    very severe queues.
  • 11:43 - 11:45
    You could apply the same principle
    actually, if you like,
  • 11:45 - 11:48
    to the security lanes in airports.
  • 11:48 - 11:49
    What would happen if you could actually
  • 11:49 - 11:52
    pay twice as much money
    to cross the bridge,
  • 11:52 - 11:54
    but go through a lane
    that's an express lane?
  • 11:54 - 11:56
    It's not an unreasonable thing to do.
  • 11:56 - 11:58
    It's an economically
    efficient thing to do.
  • 11:58 - 12:00
    Time means more to some people
    than others.
  • 12:00 - 12:03
    If you're trying to get
    to a job interview,
  • 12:03 - 12:07
    you'd patently pay a couple of pounds more
    to go through the fast lane.
  • 12:07 - 12:09
    If you're on the way
    to visit your mother in-law,
  • 12:09 - 12:12
    you'd probably prefer to stay on the left.
  • 12:14 - 12:18
    The only problem is if you introduce
    this economically efficient solution,
  • 12:18 - 12:19
    people hate it.
  • 12:19 - 12:23
    Because they think you're deliberately
    creating delays at the bridge
  • 12:23 - 12:24
    in order to maximize your revenue,
  • 12:24 - 12:28
    and "Why on earth should I pay
    to subsidize your incompetence?"
  • 12:28 - 12:31
    On the other hand,
    change the frame slightly
  • 12:31 - 12:33
    and create charitable yield management,
  • 12:33 - 12:36
    so the extra money you get goes
    not to the bridge company,
  • 12:36 - 12:38
    it goes to charity,
  • 12:38 - 12:41
    and the mental willingness
    to pay completely changes.
  • 12:42 - 12:45
    You have a relatively
    economically efficient solution,
  • 12:45 - 12:47
    but one that actually meets
    with public approval
  • 12:47 - 12:49
    and even a small degree of affection,
  • 12:49 - 12:52
    rather than being seen as bastardy.
  • 12:52 - 12:55
    So where economists
    make the fundamental mistake
  • 12:55 - 12:58
    is they think that money is money.
  • 12:58 - 13:03
    Actually my pain experienced
    in paying five pounds
  • 13:03 - 13:05
    is not just proportionate to the amount,
  • 13:05 - 13:07
    but where I think that money is going.
  • 13:07 - 13:10
    And I think understanding
    that could revolutionize tax policy.
  • 13:10 - 13:12
    It could revolutionize
    the public services.
  • 13:12 - 13:15
    It could really change
    things quite significantly.
  • 13:15 - 13:18
    Here's a guy you all need to study.
  • 13:18 - 13:20
    Anybody heard of him?
  • 13:20 - 13:23
    Good. One or two.
  • 13:23 - 13:24
    He's an Austrian school economist
  • 13:24 - 13:29
    who was first active in the first half
    of the 20th century in Vienna.
  • 13:29 - 13:32
    What was interesting
    about the Austrian school
  • 13:32 - 13:35
    is they actually grew up alongside Freud.
  • 13:35 - 13:38
    And so they're predominantly
    interested in psychology.
  • 13:38 - 13:42
    They believed that there was a discipline
    called praxeology,
  • 13:42 - 13:45
    which is a prior discipline
    to the study of economics.
  • 13:45 - 13:50
    Praxeology is the study of human choice,
    action and decision making.
  • 13:50 - 13:52
    I think they're right.
  • 13:52 - 13:54
    I think the danger
    we have in today's world
  • 13:54 - 13:55
    is we have the study of economics
  • 13:55 - 14:00
    considers itself to be a prior discipline
    to the study of human psychology.
  • 14:00 - 14:03
    But as Charlie Munger says,
    "If economics isn't behavioral,
  • 14:03 - 14:05
    I don't know what the hell is."
  • 14:05 - 14:11
    Von Mises, interestingly, believes
    economics is just a subset of psychology.
  • 14:11 - 14:13
    I think he just refers to economics as
  • 14:13 - 14:17
    "the study of human praxeology
    under conditions of scarcity."
  • 14:17 - 14:20
    But von Mises, among many other things,
  • 14:20 - 14:25
    I think uses an analogy which is probably
    the best justification and explanation
  • 14:25 - 14:29
    for the value of marketing,
    the value of perceived value
  • 14:29 - 14:33
    and the fact that we should actually
    treat it as being absolutely equivalent
  • 14:33 - 14:35
    to any other kind of value.
  • 14:35 - 14:37
    All of us - even those of us
    who work in marketing -
  • 14:37 - 14:39
    tend to think of value in two ways.
  • 14:39 - 14:40
    There's the real value,
  • 14:40 - 14:43
    which is when you make something
    in a factory and provide a service,
  • 14:43 - 14:45
    and then there's a kind of dubious value,
  • 14:45 - 14:48
    which you create by changing
    the way people look at things.
  • 14:48 - 14:50
    Von Mises completely rejected
    this distinction.
  • 14:50 - 14:52
    And he used this following analogy.
  • 14:52 - 14:57
    He referred actually to strange economists
    called the French Physiocrats,
  • 14:57 - 15:00
    who believed that the only true value
    was what you extracted from the land.
  • 15:00 - 15:03
    So if you're a shepherd
    or a quarryman or a farmer,
  • 15:03 - 15:05
    you created true value.
  • 15:05 - 15:08
    If however, you bought
    some wool from the shepherd
  • 15:08 - 15:10
    and charged a premium
    for converting it into a hat,
  • 15:10 - 15:13
    you weren't actually creating value,
  • 15:13 - 15:15
    you were exploiting the shepherd.
  • 15:15 - 15:19
    Now von Mises said that modern economists
    make exactly the same mistake
  • 15:19 - 15:21
    with regard to advertising and marketing.
  • 15:21 - 15:23
    He says, if you run a restaurant,
  • 15:23 - 15:25
    there is no healthy distinction to be made
  • 15:25 - 15:28
    between the value you create
    by cooking the food
  • 15:28 - 15:31
    and the value you create
    by sweeping the floor.
  • 15:31 - 15:33
    One of them creates, perhaps,
    the primary product -
  • 15:33 - 15:35
    the thing we think we're paying for -
  • 15:35 - 15:37
    the other one creates a context
  • 15:37 - 15:40
    within which we can enjoy
    and appreciate that product.
  • 15:40 - 15:43
    And the idea that one of them should
    actually have priority over the other
  • 15:43 - 15:44
    is fundamentally wrong.
  • 15:44 - 15:46
    Try this quick thought experiment.
  • 15:46 - 15:49
    Imagine a restaurant
    that serves Michelin-starred food,
  • 15:49 - 15:52
    but actually where
    the restaurant smells of sewage
  • 15:52 - 15:54
    and there's human feces on the floor.
  • 15:55 - 15:58
    The best thing you can do there
    to create value
  • 15:58 - 16:01
    is not actually to improve
    the food still further,
  • 16:01 - 16:04
    it's to get rid of the smell
    and clean up the floor.
  • 16:05 - 16:08
    And it's vital we understand this.
  • 16:08 - 16:10
    If that seems like some strange,
    abstruse thing,
  • 16:10 - 16:15
    in the U.K., the post office
    had a 98 percent success rate
  • 16:15 - 16:18
    at delivering first-class mail
    the next day.
  • 16:18 - 16:19
    They decided this wasn't good enough
  • 16:19 - 16:22
    and they wanted to get it up to 99.
  • 16:23 - 16:26
    The effort to do that
    almost broke the organization.
  • 16:27 - 16:29
    If at the same time you'd gone
    and asked people,
  • 16:29 - 16:32
    "What percentage of first-class mail
    arrives the next day?"
  • 16:32 - 16:36
    the average, or the modal answer
    would have been 50 to 60 percent.
  • 16:37 - 16:40
    Now if your perception
    is much worse than your reality,
  • 16:40 - 16:43
    what on earth are you doing
    trying to change the reality?
  • 16:43 - 16:46
    That's like trying to improve
    the food in a restaurant that stinks.
  • 16:48 - 16:49
    What you need to do
  • 16:49 - 16:51
    is first of all tell people
  • 16:51 - 16:55
    that 98 percent of mail gets there
    the next day, first-class mail.
  • 16:55 - 16:57
    That's pretty good.
  • 16:57 - 17:00
    I would argue, in Britain there's
    a much better frame of reference,
  • 17:00 - 17:01
    which is to tell people
  • 17:01 - 17:03
    that more first-class mail
    arrives the next day
  • 17:03 - 17:05
    in the U.K. than in Germany.
  • 17:05 - 17:09
    Because generally in Britain if you want
    to make us happy about something,
  • 17:09 - 17:11
    just tell us we do it better
    than the Germans.
  • 17:11 - 17:12
    (Laughter)
  • 17:12 - 17:14
    (Applause)
  • 17:15 - 17:18
    Choose your frame of reference
    and the perceived value
  • 17:18 - 17:21
    and therefore the actual value
    is completely transformed.
  • 17:21 - 17:23
    It has to be said of the Germans
  • 17:23 - 17:26
    that the Germans and the French
    are doing a brilliant job
  • 17:26 - 17:28
    of creating a united Europe.
  • 17:28 - 17:30
    The only thing they didn't expect
    is they're uniting Europe
  • 17:30 - 17:33
    through a shared mild hatred
    of the French and Germans.
  • 17:33 - 17:36
    But I'm British,
    that's the way we like it.
  • 17:38 - 17:41
    What you also notice is that
    in any case our perception is leaky.
  • 17:41 - 17:44
    We can't tell the difference
    between the quality of the food
  • 17:44 - 17:46
    and the environment
    in which we consume it.
  • 17:46 - 17:48
    All of you will have seen this phenomenon
  • 17:48 - 17:50
    if you have your car washed or valeted.
  • 17:51 - 17:54
    When you drive away,
    your car feels as if it drives better.
  • 17:56 - 17:57
    And the reason for this,
  • 17:57 - 18:00
    unless my car valet
    mysteriously is changing the oil
  • 18:00 - 18:03
    and performing work which
    I'm not paying him for and I'm unaware of,
  • 18:03 - 18:05
    is because perception
    is in any case leaky.
  • 18:05 - 18:09
    Analgesics that are branded
    are more effective at reducing pain
  • 18:09 - 18:11
    than analgesics that are not branded.
  • 18:11 - 18:14
    I don't just mean through
    reported pain reduction,
  • 18:14 - 18:15
    actual measured pain reduction.
  • 18:15 - 18:20
    And so perception actually
    is leaky in any case.
  • 18:21 - 18:24
    So if you do something
    that's perceptually bad in one respect,
  • 18:24 - 18:25
    you can damage the other.
  • 18:25 - 18:27
    I'll end very quicky
  • 18:27 - 18:30
    with something without which
    you'd never be happy for me to miss
  • 18:30 - 18:32
    which is the perfect demonstration
  • 18:32 - 18:35
    of creating economically
    fairly sustainable value,
  • 18:35 - 18:37
    through doing nothing to the product,
  • 18:37 - 18:40
    and everything to the way
    in which it's consumed and perceived.
  • 18:40 - 18:44
    (Video) Man:
    Shreddies are supposed to be square.
  • 18:44 - 18:48
    Woman: Have any of these
    diamond shapes gone out?
  • 18:49 - 18:51
    [Diamond Shreddies]
    Woman: New Diamond Shreddies cereal
  • 18:51 - 18:55
    Same 100% Whole Grain Wheat
    in a delicious diamond shape.
  • 18:56 - 18:59
    Rory Sutherland: Very finally,
    here's the poster campaign.
  • 18:59 - 19:01
    (Laughter)
  • 19:01 - 19:04
    (Applause)
  • 19:09 - 19:12
    Some Canadians are inherently
    very conservative,
  • 19:12 - 19:15
    and were very annoyed that their
    square Shreddies had been taken away.
  • 19:15 - 19:18
    It was kind of a new-coat
    marketing moment.
  • 19:18 - 19:21
    So after long thought and deliberation,
  • 19:21 - 19:22
    they arrived at a compromise.
  • 19:22 - 19:24
    Thank you very much.
  • 19:24 - 19:26
    (Applause)
Title:
Perspective is everything | Rory Sutherland | TEDxAthens
Description:

The circumstances of our lives may matter less than how we see them, says Rory Sutherland. At TEDxAthens, he makes a compelling case for how reframing is the key to happiness.

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
closed TED
Project:
TEDxTalks
Duration:
19:33
  • Hello.
    I would like to draw your attention to the existing TED.com transcription and translation.
    http://www.amara.org/en/videos/B2EY76mtmMZc/en/426/?tab=subtitles
    I am really nobody and am not sure about how TED OTP community should address already transcribed/translated talks for TEDx talks.
    Would you like to join our conversation at https://www.facebook.com/groups/ITranslateTEDTalks/permalink/10151729886961472/ .

English subtitles

Revisions