Return to Video

Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve

  • 0:01 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:11
    - [Alex] Now that we know
    how to find the profit
  • 0:11 - 0:14
    maximization point,
    we're going to show
  • 0:14 - 0:19
    the amount of profit on the diagram
    using the average cost curve.
  • 0:24 - 0:25
    So as I said in the last lecture,
  • 0:25 - 0:28
    average cost is the cost
    per unit of output.
  • 0:28 - 0:33
    That is, average cost is
    total cost divided by Q.
  • 0:33 - 0:36
    Now remember also
    that total cost can be broken down
  • 0:36 - 0:39
    into fixed costs plus
    variable costs.
  • 0:39 - 0:43
    So we can also write average cost
    in a slightly longer format.
  • 0:43 - 0:46
    Average cost is equal
    to fixed cost divided by Q
  • 0:46 - 0:50
    plus the variable cost divided
    by Q, the units of output.
  • 0:50 - 0:54
    That's a little bit useful
    because we're able to see,
  • 0:54 - 0:57
    get some intuition, for the shape
    of a typical average cost curve.
  • 0:58 - 1:02
    Notice that the fixed costs
    don't change with Q.
  • 1:02 - 1:04
    That's why they're fixed.
  • 1:04 - 1:07
    So when Q is small -- this number,
  • 1:07 - 1:09
    suppose fixed cost is 100,
  • 1:09 - 1:12
    and Q is small -- then this number
    is going to be big
  • 1:12 - 1:14
    like 100 divided by 1.
  • 1:15 - 1:18
    As Q gets larger, however,
    this number --
  • 1:18 - 1:20
    fixed cost divided by Q --
    is going to get smaller,
  • 1:20 - 1:25
    So when Q is 10, this number
    100 divided by 10 becomes 10.
  • 1:26 - 1:29
    So it goes from 100,
    and it goes down, down, down, down,
  • 1:29 - 1:32
    get's lower and lower and lower
    all the time as you divide
  • 1:32 - 1:33
    by a bigger quantity.
  • 1:34 - 1:38
    On the other hand, the variable
    costs increase with quantity.
  • 1:38 - 1:42
    Moreover, what we saw
    with the marginal cost curve
  • 1:42 - 1:45
    is that at some point,
    your variable costs are going
  • 1:45 - 1:47
    to increase faster than quantity.
  • 1:47 - 1:51
    So what's going to happen is
    that this number at some point --
  • 1:51 - 1:53
    variable cost divided by quantity --
    is going to get bigger
  • 1:53 - 1:54
    and bigger and bigger.
  • 1:54 - 1:59
    So you have two things, one force
    is driving average cost down.
  • 1:59 - 2:02
    That's going to be particularly
    strong at the beginning.
  • 2:03 - 2:07
    Eventually, however,
    the second force here is going
  • 2:07 - 2:09
    to drive average cost up.
  • 2:10 - 2:12
    So that's going to be our typical
    shape of an average cost curve --
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    falling, reaches a minimum,
    and then rising.
  • 2:15 - 2:16
    So let's draw it like that.
  • 2:16 - 2:19
    Okay, here's our typical
    marginal cost curve,
  • 2:19 - 2:22
    and here is our marginal
    revenue curve, equal to price.
  • 2:23 - 2:26
    We know that the profit maximizing
    point is where marginal revenue
  • 2:26 - 2:28
    is equal to marginal cost.
  • 2:28 - 2:32
    Here is our average cost curve,
    and notice it has the shape
  • 2:32 - 2:35
    which I described --
    it starts off high, it falls,
  • 2:35 - 2:38
    reaches a minimum,
    and then goes right back up again.
  • 2:38 - 2:43
    Couple of other points to notice
    is that the minimum point,
  • 2:43 - 2:46
    the marginal cost curve goes
    through the minimum point
  • 2:46 - 2:48
    of the average cost curve.
  • 2:48 - 2:52
    Now that's just a mathematical fact,
    but let me give you some intuition.
  • 2:52 - 2:55
    Instead of cost, I want
    to talk about average grade
  • 2:55 - 2:57
    and marginal grade.
  • 2:57 - 3:02
    So suppose that your
    average grade is 80%.
  • 3:02 - 3:05
    You're doing really pretty good,
    but then on your next test
  • 3:05 - 3:08
    you only get 60% -- lower.
  • 3:08 - 3:11
    What is that going to do
    to your average?
  • 3:11 - 3:13
    Well, it's going to drive
    your average down.
  • 3:13 - 3:18
    Indeed whenever your marginal
    is below your average,
  • 3:18 - 3:20
    the average must be falling.
  • 3:20 - 3:24
    On the other hand, suppose
    that you're getting 80%,
  • 3:24 - 3:27
    and on your next test you get 90%.
  • 3:27 - 3:30
    Great, but what does
    that do to your average?
  • 3:30 - 3:32
    It drives your average up.
  • 3:32 - 3:36
    Indeed whenever your marginal
    is above the average,
  • 3:36 - 3:38
    the average must be rising.
  • 3:38 - 3:41
    Now suppose what happens
    when you're getting let's say 80%,
  • 3:41 - 3:45
    and on your next test,
    you also get 80%.
  • 3:45 - 3:49
    Well then your marginal is equal
    to your average grade,
  • 3:49 - 3:54
    and your average grade is flat --
    it doesn't change, it's flat.
  • 3:54 - 3:58
    But what is true for average
    and marginal grades is also true
  • 3:58 - 4:01
    for average cost and marginal cost.
  • 4:01 - 4:07
    Whenever the marginal cost is
    below the average,
  • 4:07 - 4:09
    the average is falling.
  • 4:09 - 4:12
    Whenever the marginal cost is
    above the average,
  • 4:12 - 4:14
    the average is rising.
  • 4:14 - 4:17
    And where marginal is
    just equal to average,
  • 4:17 - 4:18
    the average is flat.
  • 4:18 - 4:21
    In other words, we are
    at the minimum point
  • 4:21 - 4:23
    of the average cost curve.
  • 4:24 - 4:27
    Okay, now I said we could use
    the average cost curve
  • 4:27 - 4:29
    to figure out profit --
    show profit on the diagram.
  • 4:29 - 4:33
    We can do that with just
    a little bit of rearranging.
  • 4:33 - 4:36
    Remember that profit is equal
    to total revenue minus total cost
  • 4:36 - 4:40
    and total revenue is
    price times quantity -- P times Q.
  • 4:40 - 4:42
    We also know
    that average cost is equal
  • 4:42 - 4:45
    to total cost divided by quantity.
  • 4:45 - 4:49
    Let's just rearrange that
    to tell us that total cost is equal
  • 4:49 - 4:51
    to average cost times quantity.
  • 4:51 - 4:54
    So just take this one
    and multiply both sides by Q.
  • 4:55 - 5:00
    Let's now make these substitutions
    into our profit equation.
  • 5:00 - 5:04
    If we do that, then profit is equal
    to total revenue --
  • 5:04 - 5:06
    price times quantity --
    minus total cost --
  • 5:06 - 5:08
    average cost times quantity.
  • 5:08 - 5:12
    Now let's take Q out
    of both parts of this equation,
  • 5:12 - 5:17
    and we find that profit
    can also be written as price
  • 5:17 - 5:20
    minus average cost,
    all of that times quantity.
  • 5:21 - 5:23
    That's nice because we can find
  • 5:23 - 5:26
    all of these elements
    on our diagram.
  • 5:27 - 5:28
    Here's the price.
  • 5:28 - 5:32
    Here's the average cost
    at the profit maximizing quantity.
  • 5:33 - 5:35
    Let's just show that.
    There's the price.
  • 5:36 - 5:40
    There's the average cost
    at the profit maximizing quantity.
  • 5:40 - 5:44
    So profit at the profit
    maximizing quantity is
  • 5:44 - 5:47
    this green area right here --
  • 5:48 - 5:52
    price minus average cost
    times quantity.
  • 5:52 - 5:55
    So now we have a nice way
    of showing in a diagram
  • 5:55 - 5:57
    exactly how much profit is.
  • 5:58 - 6:00
    Let's use this tool some more.
  • 6:00 - 6:03
    Here's another example
    of the average cost curve in action.
  • 6:03 - 6:07
    Remember, I said that profit
    maximization doesn't necessarily
  • 6:07 - 6:09
    mean the firm is making
    a positive profit.
  • 6:10 - 6:13
    Sometimes the best you can do
    is to minimize your losses.
  • 6:13 - 6:15
    You may have to take a loss.
  • 6:15 - 6:19
    For example, suppose
    that the price is below $17.
  • 6:19 - 6:22
    That is, here's the market price,
    which is equal to the firm's
  • 6:22 - 6:24
    marginal revenue curve.
  • 6:24 - 6:26
    How does the firm profit maximize?
  • 6:26 - 6:29
    It chooses the quantity
    where marginal revenue is
  • 6:29 - 6:31
    equal to marginal cost.
  • 6:31 - 6:33
    In that case, this quantity is one.
  • 6:33 - 6:35
    Now what's the profit
    for the firm?
  • 6:35 - 6:40
    Well, as usual we measure
    profit as price minus
  • 6:40 - 6:43
    average cost times quantity.
  • 6:43 - 6:47
    But notice that price is
    below the average cost
  • 6:47 - 6:51
    at the profit maximizing
    quantity of one.
  • 6:51 - 6:56
    Since price is below average cost,
    this is a loss.
  • 6:56 - 6:58
    It's a negative quantity.
  • 6:58 - 7:06
    It is a loss. In fact, notice
    that the breakeven price is $17,
  • 7:06 - 7:09
    which is the minimum
    of the average cost curve.
  • 7:09 - 7:14
    In order to make a profit,
    the firm at least has to meet
  • 7:14 - 7:17
    the minimum of its
    average cost curve.
  • 7:17 - 7:21
    So at any price below $17,
    we'll be profit maximizing
  • 7:21 - 7:24
    at a point where price is equal
    to marginal cost,
  • 7:24 - 7:29
    and notice that all of these
    prices are below average cost.
  • 7:29 - 7:31
    So all of this area down here,
  • 7:31 - 7:36
    even the profit maximizing
    quantity, will mean a loss.
  • 7:36 - 7:41
    On the other hand, once we get
    above $17, above the minimum
  • 7:41 - 7:46
    of the average cost curve, then we
    can price equal to marginal cost.
  • 7:46 - 7:49
    We can choose the quantities such
    the price is equal to marginal cost.
  • 7:49 - 7:54
    That price will be above average
    cost, so we'll be taking a profit.
  • 7:55 - 7:59
    Therefore, $17, the minimum
    of the average cost curve,
  • 7:59 - 8:01
    is the breakeven point.
  • 8:02 - 8:04
    If the price is less
    than the minimum
  • 8:04 - 8:07
    of the average cost curve,
    we're going to be taking a loss.
  • 8:07 - 8:09
    If the price is bigger
    than the minimum
  • 8:09 - 8:12
    of the average cost curve,
    then we can make a profit.
  • 8:13 - 8:16
    So when should a firm enter
    or exit an industry?
  • 8:16 - 8:19
    In the long run, the firms will
    enter when price
  • 8:19 - 8:21
    is above average cost.
  • 8:21 - 8:24
    If price is somewhere
    above the average cost curve
  • 8:24 - 8:26
    then the firm can make
    a profit by entering,
  • 8:26 - 8:28
    and that's what firms want to do.
  • 8:28 - 8:30
    They want to find profit,
    so they will want to enter
  • 8:30 - 8:32
    wherever a profit is possible.
  • 8:32 - 8:36
    Firms will exit the industry
    when the price is below
  • 8:36 - 8:37
    the average cost curve.
  • 8:37 - 8:39
    Then they're going
    to be taking a loss,
  • 8:39 - 8:40
    and they're going to want to exit.
  • 8:40 - 8:44
    Finally, when the price is
    equal to the minimum
  • 8:44 - 8:47
    of the average cost --
    it's just equal to the bottom
  • 8:47 - 8:50
    of the average cost curve,
    profits are zero,
  • 8:50 - 8:51
    and there's no incentive
  • 8:51 - 8:54
    to either exit
    or enter the industry.
  • 8:54 - 8:57
    Now you might ask,
    why would firms remain
  • 8:57 - 8:59
    in an industry if profits are zero?
  • 8:59 - 9:03
    Zero profits, this is just
    a matter of terminology,
  • 9:03 - 9:07
    means that at the market price
    the firm is covering all
  • 9:07 - 9:11
    of its costs, including enough
    to pay labor and capital,
  • 9:11 - 9:13
    their ordinary opportunity cost.
  • 9:13 - 9:18
    So zero profits means
    everyone is being paid
  • 9:18 - 9:20
    enough to make them satisfied.
  • 9:20 - 9:24
    Zero profits, in other words,
    is what normal people mean
  • 9:24 - 9:25
    by normal profits.
  • 9:25 - 9:28
    So when an economist
    says zero profits
  • 9:28 - 9:30
    just substitute normal profits.
  • 9:30 - 9:33
    One more point
    about entry and exit.
  • 9:33 - 9:37
    It doesn't always make sense
    to exit an industry immediately
  • 9:37 - 9:39
    when price falls
    below average cost,
  • 9:39 - 9:43
    or to enter immediately
    when price is above average cost.
  • 9:43 - 9:48
    Why not? Well, there are
    also entry and exit costs.
  • 9:48 - 9:51
    For example, suppose
    that that the price of oil is
  • 9:51 - 9:55
    currently above the average
    cost of pumping oil,
  • 9:55 - 9:59
    if you've already got a well.
    Should you enter the industry?
  • 9:59 - 10:01
    Well, maybe not necessarily.
  • 10:01 - 10:05
    Because entry requires you
    to drill an oil well,
  • 10:05 - 10:09
    and drilling an oil well is
    a sunk cost -- literally in this case.
  • 10:09 - 10:14
    A sunk cost is a cost that once
    incurred can never be recovered.
  • 10:15 - 10:18
    So if you enter the industry
    and drill the oil well,
  • 10:18 - 10:22
    you don't get that money back
    when you later exit the industry.
  • 10:22 - 10:25
    What this means is you
    don't want to enter
  • 10:25 - 10:30
    unless you expect
    the price of oil to stay
  • 10:30 - 10:34
    above the minimum
    of the average cost curve
  • 10:34 - 10:39
    long enough so that you can
    also recover your entry costs.
  • 10:39 - 10:44
    So just because the price goes
    above the average cost a little bit,
  • 10:44 - 10:46
    you don't immediately
    want to jump into that industry.
  • 10:47 - 10:50
    You have to expect that
    that price is going to stay
  • 10:50 - 10:54
    above average cost
    long enough for you
  • 10:54 - 10:56
    to recover your entry costs.
  • 10:57 - 11:00
    For the same reasons,
    if there are exit costs --
  • 11:00 - 11:03
    for example, if you have
    to shutter up the well
  • 11:03 - 11:05
    or fill the well with cement
    when you exit the industry
  • 11:05 - 11:08
    as you do in the United States --
    then when price falls
  • 11:08 - 11:11
    below average cost,
    it may be best to weather
  • 11:11 - 11:15
    the storm at least
    for sometime before you exit.
  • 11:15 - 11:21
    Only if you expect the price
    of oil to stay below your minimum
  • 11:21 - 11:24
    of average cost
    for an extended period of time
  • 11:24 - 11:26
    will you want to exit the industry.
  • 11:27 - 11:30
    After all, if the price of oil falls
    below the average cost
  • 11:30 - 11:33
    just for a little bit,
    and then it goes back up,
  • 11:33 - 11:36
    the lifetime profits can
    still be possible.
  • 11:36 - 11:39
    So, entry and exit could be
    quite complicated
  • 11:39 - 11:41
    because you've got
    to be thinking
  • 11:41 - 11:45
    about the lifetime profits,
    not just your immediate profits.
  • 11:45 - 11:48
    However, the bottom line
    is pretty simple.
  • 11:48 - 11:52
    Firms seek profits,
    and they want to avoid losses.
  • 11:52 - 11:56
    As a result, firms will enter
    industries when the price is above
  • 11:56 - 11:59
    the average cost
    and they can make a profit,
  • 11:59 - 12:02
    and they will exit when the price
    is below the average cost.
  • 12:03 - 12:04
    Thanks.
  • 12:05 - 12:08
    - [Narrator] If you want to test
    yourself, click, "Practice Questions."
  • 12:08 - 12:12
    Or, if you're ready to move on,
    just click, "Next Video."
  • 12:13 - 12:15
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Maximizing Profit and the Average Cost Curve
Description:

Being able to predict your company’s profit is a very useful tool. In this video, we introduce the third concept you need to maximize profit — average cost. When looked at in conjunction with the marginal revenue and marginal cost, the average cost curve will show you how to accurately predict how much profit you can make!
The usefulness of these tools does not stop there. Sometimes, you can’t make a profit. You’ll have to take a loss. These tools can also show you how to minimize losses, and make decisions on whether a company should enter or exit an industry.
We also define terms such as zero profits and sunk costs in this video.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/profit-maximization-average-cost#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/supply-curve-increasing-cost-industry

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
12:18

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions