Return to Video

Another Look at Comparative Advantage

  • 0:10 - 0:14
    - In our last video, Don Boudreaux
    used the simple example of Bob and Anne to
  • 0:14 - 0:19
    demonstrate comparative advantage. In the
    next two videos, we'll dive deeper into
  • 0:19 - 0:22
    comparative advantage and give you a
    homework question to test how well you're
  • 0:22 - 0:26
    doing in understanding the concept.
    Let's get going.
  • 0:30 - 0:34
    - Comparative advantage is the
    theory of trade. It explains why people
  • 0:34 - 0:40
    trade, and which good people should trade
    if they want to maximize their well being.
  • 0:40 - 0:45
    It's actually useful to understand
    comparative advantage to begin with a
  • 0:45 - 0:49
    false theory: a very plausible but
    incorrect theory of trade, namely the
  • 0:49 - 0:54
    theory of absolute advantage. So let's
    consider a simple model. Let's suppose
  • 0:54 - 0:58
    that labor is the only good used in
    production and that we can produce
  • 0:58 - 1:04
    computers or shirts. Let's suppose that
    in Mexico it takes 12 units of labor to
  • 1:05 - 1:08
    produce one computer. Again in Mexico,
  • 1:08 - 1:12
    it takes two units of labor
    to produce one shirt.
  • 1:12 - 1:15
    Now let's compare it with the United
    States. To make it simple, we'll suppose
  • 1:15 - 1:20
    in the United States it takes just one
    unit of labor to make one computer, and
  • 1:21 - 1:28
    one unit of labor to create one shirt.
    Now, from the absolute advantage theory of
  • 1:28 - 1:33
    trade, it should-- it may seem obvious
    that there in fact will-- be no trade here.
  • 1:33 - 1:39
    It may seem obvious that the United
    States will outcompete Mexico on all
  • 1:39 - 1:44
    margins. After all, the United States in
    this example is much more productive at
  • 1:44 - 1:48
    producing computers and also more
    productive at producing shirts than
  • 1:49 - 1:53
    Mexico. So this is a case where we might
    think, with the United States so much
  • 1:53 - 1:58
    better at producing both computers and
    shirts, that certainly there's no reason
  • 1:59 - 2:06
    for the United States to trade with
    Mexico, its less productive neighbor.
  • 2:06 - 2:12
    That's the theory of absolute advantage.
    It's very plausible; it's also very wrong.
  • 2:12 - 2:16
    To see why it's wrong, let's take another
    simple example. Here's a picture of Martha
  • 2:16 - 2:21
    Stewart ironing her shirt. Now, let's
    stipulate that Martha Stewart has an
  • 2:22 - 2:26
    absolute advantage in ironing. She has an
    advantage in ironing just like the United
  • 2:26 - 2:30
    States had an advantage in producing
    computers and shirts in the previous
  • 2:31 - 2:34
    example. In other words, we'll stipulate
    that Martha Stewart
  • 2:34 - 2:39
    can iron a shirt better and in
    less time than anyone else.
  • 2:39 - 2:43
    So if Martha Stewart has an
    absolute advantage in ironing
  • 2:43 - 2:50
    should Martha Stuart iron her own
    shirts? Of course the answer here is, no.
  • 2:50 - 2:56
    Why not? Well, every hour which Martha
    Stuart Spends ironing her shirts is an
  • 2:56 - 3:01
    hour she's not spending doing something
    else which is even more valuable, running
  • 3:02 - 3:07
    her own business for example, running her
    billion dollar business. And in fact in a
  • 3:07 - 3:12
    famous statement, Martha Stuart because
    she's very wise she said, "I don't always
  • 3:12 - 3:16
    do all of my own ironing, even though I
    wish that I could." Let's take a little
  • 3:17 - 3:21
    bit more detail about why it doesn't make
    sense for Martha Stuart to iron her own
  • 3:21 - 3:27
    shirts. The most important point to
    remember is that the important cause is
  • 3:27 - 3:32
    opportunity cost. So what is the
    opportunity cost to Martha Stewart of
  • 3:33 - 3:37
    spending an hour ironing her own shirts?
    Well, it could be thousands of dollars, at
  • 3:38 - 3:44
    least. Martha Stewart would be better off
    if she specializes in producing her
  • 3:44 - 3:49
    television show, and then she trades with
    someone else who has a lower opportunity
  • 3:49 - 3:54
    cost of ironing. It doesn't make sense for
    Martha Stewart to iron her own shirts
  • 3:55 - 3:59
    because the cost of her doing so is
    devoting her time to something where she's
  • 3:59 - 4:05
    even more valuable or she even better and
    that is producing her own television show.
  • 4:05 - 4:11
    So Martha Stewart has a comparative
    advantage in running her business, or to
  • 4:11 - 4:16
    put it slightly differently she has a
    comparative disadvantage in ironing. The
  • 4:16 - 4:22
    cost of her of ironing is very high
    precisely because she is so much more
  • 4:22 - 4:29
    productive at other tasks. So Martha
    Stewart wants to specialize in what she
  • 4:29 - 4:35
    is best at, in where she has a
    comparative advantage. Other people
  • 4:35 - 4:41
    are almost as good as her at ironing
    clothes, but they're not as good as her at
  • 4:41 - 4:44
    producing their own TV show. So that's why
    Martha Stewart shouldn't
  • 4:44 - 4:46
    iron her own shirts.
  • 4:47 - 4:52
    Let's go back now to our previous example
    of the United States and Mexico. So the
  • 4:52 - 4:56
    key to comparative advantage is
    understanding opportunity cost. So let's
  • 4:56 - 5:01
    take this previous figure we had from a
    previous slide and turn it into an
  • 5:01 - 5:06
    opportunity cost figure. So remember what
    this top figure tells us: it tells us for
  • 5:06 - 5:11
    example that in Mexico it takes 12 units
    of labor to produce one computer, and in
  • 5:11 - 5:16
    Mexico it takes two units of labor to
    produce one shirt and so forth. Okay, for
  • 5:16 - 5:19
    the United States, it just takes one unit
    of labor to produce either
  • 5:19 - 5:21
    a computer or a shirt.
  • 5:21 - 5:27
    Okay, now let's begin with an easy case.
    What's the opportunity cost of one
  • 5:28 - 5:34
    computer in the United States? In other
    words, to produce an additional computer
  • 5:34 - 5:39
    in the United States, what would we have
    to give up? Well, in order to get that
  • 5:39 - 5:43
    additional computer, we'd have to take
    labor from shirt production and move it
  • 5:43 - 5:48
    into computer production. In particular,
    we have to take one unit of labor from
  • 5:48 - 5:53
    shirt production and move it into computer
    production. That would get us one more
  • 5:53 - 5:59
    computer at the cost of one shirt. So the
    opportunity cost of one computer in the
  • 5:59 - 6:04
    United States is one shirt.
    What is the opportunity cost of a shirt?
  • 6:05 - 6:08
    Well, the opportunity cost of a shirt,
    what you're giving up to produce an extra
  • 6:08 - 6:16
    shirt, is one computer. Okay, slightly
    harder case, what's the opportunity cost
  • 6:16 - 6:23
    of one computer in Mexico? So in Mexico,
    in order to get an additional computer,
  • 6:23 - 6:28
    you'd have to transfer labor from shirt
    production into computer production. But
  • 6:28 - 6:32
    how many units of labor do you need to
    transfer? You need to transfer 12 units of
  • 6:32 - 6:37
    labor in order to get one computer. You're
    going to have to take 12 units of labor
  • 6:37 - 6:43
    from shirt production. That means how many
    fewer shirts? Since it takes two units of
  • 6:43 - 6:48
    labor to produce one shirt, and you've got
    to move 12 units of labor. It means that
  • 6:48 - 6:54
    the opportunity cost of one computer is
    six shirts. If you need an additional
  • 6:54 - 7:00
    computer, it's going to cost you six fewer
    shirts in order to get that computer.
  • 7:00 - 7:04
    Going the other way, in order to get an
    additional shirt, you're going to have to
  • 7:04 - 7:10
    give up one-sixth of a computer. Okay, so
    now we have our opportunity cost, and now
  • 7:10 - 7:15
    it's actually pretty simple because what
    the theory of comparative advantage says
  • 7:15 - 7:21
    is that you should produce, or you can
    produce at lowest cost. So who here has
  • 7:21 - 7:28
    the lowest cost of producing a computer?
    The lowest cost of producing a computer is
  • 7:28 - 7:33
    the United States. The United States is
    the low opportunity cost producer of
  • 7:33 - 7:43
    computers. Now, who is the low cost
    producer of shirts? Well, it's Mexico. In
  • 7:43 - 7:48
    Mexico, you're only giving up one-sixth of
    a computer to produce a shirt. In the
  • 7:48 - 7:52
    United States, you're giving up one
    computer to produce a shirt. So you'd much
  • 7:52 - 7:59
    rather produce shirts in Mexico where the
    opportunity cost is lower. Okay, what
  • 7:59 - 8:05
    we're learning here is that Mexico ought
    to specialize in computers because they're
  • 8:06 - 8:11
    the low cost producer of-- excuse me, in
    shirts because they're the low cost
  • 8:11 - 8:14
    producer of shirts. The United States
    ought to specialize more
  • 8:14 - 8:20
    towards computers because they're the low
    cost producer of computers. Let's look in
  • 8:20 - 8:24
    more detail. So I'm going to leave some of
    the details to you actually and some
  • 8:24 - 8:28
    homework questions which will go over in
    the future video.
  • 8:28 - 8:32
    So question one, let's supposed in Mexico
    and in the United States each have 24
  • 8:32 - 8:38
    units of labor, and that each devote 12
    units of labor to producing computers and
  • 8:38 - 8:43
    12 units of labor to producing shirts.
    That will be our base line scenario.
  • 8:43 - 8:47
    The question is, "What is total world
    production in this scenario?"
  • 8:47 - 8:49
    That's question one.
  • 8:49 - 8:55
    Question two, supposed that Mexico
    specializes in producing what it produces
  • 8:55 - 8:59
    at lowest opportunity cost, we just saw
    that was shirts and supposed that the U.S.
  • 8:59 - 9:05
    transfers two units of labor from shirts
    to producing what it produces at lowest
  • 9:05 - 9:12
    opportunity cost, that's computers. What
    it then is total world production?
  • 9:12 - 9:17
    Finally, can trade make both countries
    better off? Here what I'd like you to do
  • 9:17 - 9:23
    is give a concrete example of how many
    units have to be traded from where to
  • 9:23 - 9:27
    where in order to make both countries
    better off, if that in fact is possible.
  • 9:28 - 9:32
    So to help you along a little bit, I know
    that was a mouthful. Let's take a look at
  • 9:32 - 9:38
    this in terms of a diagram. To help you
    along, I want you to fill in these tables.
  • 9:38 - 9:43
    So our basic table from which you're going
    to draw the information is up here. If
  • 9:43 - 9:47
    both countries have 24 units of labor,
    half devoted to computers, half to shirts.
  • 9:47 - 9:52
    There's no trade so production is equal to
    consumption in this first example. What is
  • 9:52 - 9:54
    production going to be?
  • 9:54 - 9:58
    So Mexico, 12 units of labor with
    computers, 12 shirts. How many computers,
  • 9:58 - 10:00
    how many shirts? Same for the United
    States.
  • 10:00 - 10:05
    How many computers? How many shirts?
    What's total world production? Then
  • 10:05 - 10:09
    supposed we have specialization, what's
    production is going to be? So Mexico has
  • 10:09 - 10:14
    zero units of labor in computers, 24 in
    shirts. United States has 14 units of
  • 10:15 - 10:19
    labor in computers, 10 in shirts. What's
    production in each cases? What is the
  • 10:19 - 10:25
    total for the world? Then finally, can
    we-- with production, with specialization,
  • 10:25 - 10:31
    can we now find a way to have trade which
    make both countries better off? What's the
  • 10:32 - 10:36
    exact-- or what a exact price ratio with
    that trade will occur.
  • 10:36 - 10:40
    We'll take that up in an later video. Let
    me just finally give you some concluding
  • 10:41 - 10:42
    comments on comparative advantage.
  • 10:43 - 10:47
    I want to conclude with the caution but
    also a big picture of view of comparative
  • 10:47 - 10:51
    advantage. In the two country first in
    examples, I've been working with in order
  • 10:51 - 10:56
    to explain the theory. Everyone is made
    better off by trade. In larger examples,
  • 10:56 - 11:01
    trade will increase aggregate wealth, but
    some individuals can be made where it's
  • 11:01 - 11:06
    off. That should make perfect sense after
    all. If A and B have been trading, and
  • 11:06 - 11:11
    then because terrace cost fall or because
    transportation cost fall. If A starts
  • 11:11 - 11:16
    trading with C, then B maybe worse off,
    even though A, B and C together have
  • 11:16 - 11:20
    greater aggregate wealth. That's just a
    caution to keep in mind.
  • 11:20 - 11:25
    Now here's the big picture. Comparative
    advantage, it applies to people, to
  • 11:25 - 11:30
    groups, to countries, and sometimes called
    the law of association. It's not only a
  • 11:30 - 11:35
    beautiful theory. It's very positive and
    optimistic theory because it says that we
  • 11:35 - 11:41
    all have something to gain from trade. It
    says by working together, we can increase
  • 11:41 - 11:47
    total wealth. More over we can-- I like to
    phrase this in terms of a politically
  • 11:48 - 11:53
    correct slogan. "Diversity is strength",
    you've probably heard that slogan before.
  • 11:53 - 11:58
    What comparative advantage adds to this is
    that diversity and strength when combined
  • 11:58 - 12:04
    with trade, its trade which turns
    diversity into strength.
  • 12:04 - 12:07
    That's really the bottom line on
    comparative advantage.
  • 12:07 - 12:10
    We'll be saying more in future videos.
    Thanks.
  • 12:12 - 12:14
    - If you want to test
    yourself, click Practice Questions
  • 12:15 - 12:18
    or if you're ready to move on,
    just click Next Video.
Title:
Another Look at Comparative Advantage
Description:

Comparative advantage explains why people trade and what goods they should trade. To illustrate the concept of comparative advantage, we ask: Should Martha Stewart iron her own shirts? Even if Martha Stewart has an absolute advantage in ironing shirts, her opportunity cost is simply too high! We’ll go over the concepts of absolute advantage and opportunity cost in depth using more examples, too.
Ready to test your knowledge? We introduce several homework questions in this video and we’ll cover the answers in another video in this section.
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/comparative-advantage-definition-opportunity-cost#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/comparative-advantage-trade-homework

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
12:24

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions