1 00:00:00,000 --> 00:00:05,676 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:08,886 --> 00:00:11,557 - [Alex] In a competitive market, we know that price is equal 3 00:00:11,557 --> 00:00:13,933 to marginal cost and equilibrium. 4 00:00:13,933 --> 00:00:16,767 In a market with a monopoly, we now know the price 5 00:00:16,767 --> 00:00:19,506 will be greater than marginal cost. 6 00:00:19,506 --> 00:00:23,292 But how much greater? What determines the markup? 7 00:00:23,292 --> 00:00:24,854 What we're going to show in this talk 8 00:00:24,854 --> 00:00:27,525 is that the monopoly markup depends upon 9 00:00:27,525 --> 00:00:29,741 the elasticity of demand. 10 00:00:34,647 --> 00:00:38,141 Okay, let's do a very brief review where we ended up last time. 11 00:00:38,345 --> 00:00:41,160 Everything on this diagram should now be familiar. 12 00:00:41,160 --> 00:00:43,325 We know how to find the marginal revenue curve 13 00:00:43,325 --> 00:00:45,568 as a curve starting out on the vertical axis 14 00:00:45,568 --> 00:00:47,100 at the same point as the demand curve 15 00:00:47,100 --> 00:00:48,579 with twice the slope. 16 00:00:48,579 --> 00:00:50,855 We know that the profit maximizing quantity is found 17 00:00:50,855 --> 00:00:53,357 where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. 18 00:00:53,357 --> 00:00:56,642 And we know that we read the profit maximizing price 19 00:00:56,642 --> 00:00:59,662 as the highest price that people are willing to pay 20 00:00:59,662 --> 00:01:03,154 per unit for that quantity, in this case that's $12.50. 21 00:01:03,606 --> 00:01:07,009 The monopoly markup is the difference between price 22 00:01:07,009 --> 00:01:08,690 and marginal cost. 23 00:01:08,984 --> 00:01:10,797 We know that in a competitive market, 24 00:01:10,797 --> 00:01:12,773 price would be equal to marginal cost. 25 00:01:12,773 --> 00:01:15,915 Here in equilibrium we have price is much greater 26 00:01:15,915 --> 00:01:18,729 than marginal cost, that's a monopoly markup. 27 00:01:18,729 --> 00:01:21,733 And we can also read off this diagram, 28 00:01:22,233 --> 00:01:26,010 total profits for the monopolist which are above normal profits. 29 00:01:26,010 --> 00:01:29,420 And profits are the difference between price and average cost 30 00:01:29,420 --> 00:01:32,181 times the quantity, which is this shaded area. 31 00:01:32,181 --> 00:01:34,268 Okay, that's a review. 32 00:01:34,268 --> 00:01:39,082 Now let's give some intuition for what determines the size 33 00:01:39,082 --> 00:01:41,302 of the monopoly markup. 34 00:01:43,184 --> 00:01:46,269 For intuition, let's go to our case of a pharmaceutical. 35 00:01:46,269 --> 00:01:50,078 Two effects are going to increase the monopoly markup in this case. 36 00:01:50,078 --> 00:01:52,980 First, the "you can't take it with you" effect. 37 00:01:52,980 --> 00:01:55,477 Namely, people with serious illnesses 38 00:01:55,477 --> 00:01:59,599 are going to be relatively insensitive to the price 39 00:01:59,599 --> 00:02:01,732 of life saving medicine. 40 00:02:01,732 --> 00:02:04,359 You can't take it with you so may as well spend all you have 41 00:02:04,359 --> 00:02:05,823 trying to save your life. 42 00:02:05,823 --> 00:02:09,242 If the price of a life saving medicine goes up, 43 00:02:09,242 --> 00:02:13,886 the quantity demanded isn't going to go down very much. 44 00:02:14,698 --> 00:02:18,114 Since the customers are insensitive to the price, 45 00:02:18,114 --> 00:02:21,285 the monopolist is going to say, "Hey, I can increase the price 46 00:02:21,285 --> 00:02:24,490 and they're still going to buy, so I should increase the price. 47 00:02:24,490 --> 00:02:28,080 It would be profit maximizing for me to increase the price." 48 00:02:28,972 --> 00:02:32,368 Another effect, the "other people's money" effect. 49 00:02:32,368 --> 00:02:34,783 If somebody else is paying for the medicine, 50 00:02:34,783 --> 00:02:38,201 the user, the consumer is going to be less sensitive to the price. 51 00:02:38,201 --> 00:02:40,927 And we know for pharmaceuticals often the insurance company 52 00:02:40,927 --> 00:02:43,612 or Medicaid or Medicare or a government program, 53 00:02:43,612 --> 00:02:45,669 they're going to be paying for the pharmaceutical, 54 00:02:45,669 --> 00:02:48,971 so that the person who is demanding the pharmaceutical -- 55 00:02:48,971 --> 00:02:50,494 they're not paying the price. 56 00:02:50,494 --> 00:02:53,579 So even when the price goes up they're still going to ask 57 00:02:53,579 --> 00:02:56,004 for the pharmaceutical -- the quantity demanded 58 00:02:56,004 --> 00:02:58,198 isn't going to go down very much. 59 00:02:58,429 --> 00:03:00,186 So the conclusion here 60 00:03:00,186 --> 00:03:05,493 is that the less sensitive quantity demanded is to price, 61 00:03:05,493 --> 00:03:07,963 the higher the markup is going to be. 62 00:03:07,963 --> 00:03:09,867 If people aren't sensitive to the price, 63 00:03:09,867 --> 00:03:13,121 the monopolist is going to say, "Great. I can jack up the price 64 00:03:13,121 --> 00:03:16,703 and still sell almost as much as I did before." 65 00:03:17,277 --> 00:03:21,678 In other words, the more inelastic the demand curve, 66 00:03:21,678 --> 00:03:24,957 the higher the markup, and that's our basic lesson. 67 00:03:25,945 --> 00:03:29,016 Now that we have the intuition, let's test it with some diagrams, 68 00:03:29,016 --> 00:03:30,242 some demand curves. 69 00:03:30,242 --> 00:03:31,616 We have two demand curves. 70 00:03:31,616 --> 00:03:34,266 Which is more elastic, the demand curve on the right 71 00:03:34,266 --> 00:03:36,038 or on the left? 72 00:03:36,798 --> 00:03:40,593 The demand curve on the left is more elastic. 73 00:03:41,022 --> 00:03:44,974 The demand curve on the right is more inelastic. 74 00:03:44,974 --> 00:03:49,668 So going by our intuition, we should expect a low markup 75 00:03:49,668 --> 00:03:53,382 on the left and a high markup on the right. 76 00:03:54,124 --> 00:03:56,436 We know how to find the profit maximizing prices 77 00:03:56,436 --> 00:03:58,725 and quantities so let's do that. 78 00:03:58,725 --> 00:04:00,773 First, starting on the left. 79 00:04:00,773 --> 00:04:03,041 What we see is that when the demand curve 80 00:04:03,041 --> 00:04:07,845 is relatively elastic, we get a small markup of price 81 00:04:07,845 --> 00:04:09,949 over marginal cost. 82 00:04:09,949 --> 00:04:11,952 What about on the right? 83 00:04:11,952 --> 00:04:15,886 Well now we have a relatively inelastic demand curve 84 00:04:15,886 --> 00:04:20,400 and what we see is that price rises well above marginal cost. 85 00:04:20,400 --> 00:04:22,468 We have a relatively inelastic demand 86 00:04:22,468 --> 00:04:25,129 and we get a big markup. 87 00:04:25,129 --> 00:04:30,356 Notice the marginal cost for these two markets is the same. 88 00:04:30,715 --> 00:04:34,708 What differs is that the demand curve over here on the right 89 00:04:34,708 --> 00:04:36,507 is more inelastic. 90 00:04:36,507 --> 00:04:40,957 Remember the logic: the monopolist sees the consumers 91 00:04:40,957 --> 00:04:43,355 are insensitive to price. 92 00:04:43,355 --> 00:04:46,509 So it knows that if it raises price, 93 00:04:46,509 --> 00:04:50,029 the quantity demanded will fall by only a little. 94 00:04:50,039 --> 00:04:52,847 Therefore, an increase in price will increase 95 00:04:52,847 --> 00:04:55,639 the monopolist's profits, that's what it wants, 96 00:04:55,639 --> 00:04:58,191 so the monopolist will increase the price 97 00:04:58,191 --> 00:05:01,571 and you get a big markup of price over marginal cost. 98 00:05:02,035 --> 00:05:05,849 Remember also that for a competitive firm, 99 00:05:05,849 --> 00:05:10,377 the demand for its product is perfectly elastic 100 00:05:10,377 --> 00:05:13,676 and in that case price is equal to marginal cost. 101 00:05:13,676 --> 00:05:14,835 So it makes sense 102 00:05:14,835 --> 00:05:17,638 that the more elastic the demand curve is 103 00:05:17,638 --> 00:05:21,013 for a monopolist, the closer the pricing decision 104 00:05:21,013 --> 00:05:24,298 of the monopolist is to that of a competitive firm. 105 00:05:24,704 --> 00:05:26,519 So when the demand curve for the monopolist 106 00:05:26,519 --> 00:05:30,165 is relatively elastic, price is going to be close 107 00:05:30,165 --> 00:05:31,674 to marginal cost. 108 00:05:31,674 --> 00:05:34,830 The more elastic the demand curve gets 109 00:05:34,830 --> 00:05:36,360 for the monopolist, 110 00:05:36,360 --> 00:05:40,822 the closer the monopolist's profit maximizing output is 111 00:05:40,822 --> 00:05:42,609 to that of a competitive firm. 112 00:05:42,609 --> 00:05:44,832 Price gets closer to marginal cost. 113 00:05:44,832 --> 00:05:45,999 Okay, very good. 114 00:05:45,999 --> 00:05:49,769 Again remember, big lesson, the more inelastic demand, 115 00:05:49,769 --> 00:05:51,441 the bigger the markup. 116 00:05:51,904 --> 00:05:54,913 Let's now try to see if we can use our theory 117 00:05:54,913 --> 00:05:57,096 to solve a pricing puzzle. 118 00:05:57,375 --> 00:06:00,147 I recently looked at some flights on American Airlines 119 00:06:00,147 --> 00:06:03,656 and what I found was that a flight from Washington to Dallas 120 00:06:03,656 --> 00:06:08,878 was more expensive than a flight from Washington to San Francisco. 121 00:06:09,108 --> 00:06:11,654 Now, there's two things which are puzzling about that. 122 00:06:11,654 --> 00:06:15,792 First, San Francisco is obviously much farther from Washington 123 00:06:15,792 --> 00:06:18,048 than is Dallas, so you'd expect the cost, 124 00:06:18,048 --> 00:06:20,718 fuel cost and so forth, to be higher. 125 00:06:21,129 --> 00:06:25,412 Second, the puzzle is even deeper because the flight from Washington 126 00:06:25,412 --> 00:06:29,006 to San Francisco ran through Dallas. 127 00:06:29,367 --> 00:06:32,993 In fact, the Washington to Dallas segment 128 00:06:32,993 --> 00:06:35,433 of the Washington to San Francisco flight 129 00:06:35,433 --> 00:06:40,188 was exactly the same flight as the Washington to Dallas flight. 130 00:06:41,022 --> 00:06:44,074 So why would one segment of the Washington 131 00:06:44,074 --> 00:06:47,428 to San Francisco flight be more expensive 132 00:06:47,428 --> 00:06:49,182 than the entire flight? 133 00:06:50,234 --> 00:06:53,652 The answer requires knowing something about how airlines 134 00:06:53,652 --> 00:06:55,535 are structured in the United States. 135 00:06:56,127 --> 00:06:58,770 Most of the airlines have a hub airport, 136 00:06:58,770 --> 00:07:00,722 often near the center of the country, 137 00:07:00,722 --> 00:07:03,288 that's dominated by one particular airline. 138 00:07:03,606 --> 00:07:06,228 In the case of American Airlines, it's Dallas. 139 00:07:06,228 --> 00:07:08,090 In the case of United, it's Chicago. 140 00:07:08,090 --> 00:07:12,166 Northwest dominates Minnesota, St. Paul, and so forth. 141 00:07:12,172 --> 00:07:15,083 What this means is that if you want to fly to Dallas 142 00:07:15,083 --> 00:07:18,440 at a convenient time, you're much more likely to find 143 00:07:18,440 --> 00:07:22,660 a good flight on American Airlines than on another airline. 144 00:07:22,660 --> 00:07:25,152 And if you want to fly to Minneapolis, St. Paul, 145 00:07:25,152 --> 00:07:26,819 it's going to be much more convenient 146 00:07:26,819 --> 00:07:29,179 to fly Northwest and so forth. 147 00:07:29,477 --> 00:07:33,540 Okay, does that give you any ideas about solving the puzzle? 148 00:07:34,717 --> 00:07:37,499 Think about someone flying from Washington to Dallas, 149 00:07:37,499 --> 00:07:39,644 what options do they have? 150 00:07:39,644 --> 00:07:42,726 Not many. There are few substitutes. 151 00:07:42,726 --> 00:07:47,274 And few substitutes means inelastic demand. 152 00:07:48,307 --> 00:07:51,666 Now think about someone flying from Washington to San Francisco. 153 00:07:51,666 --> 00:07:55,222 What options do they have? Well, they have lots. 154 00:07:55,222 --> 00:07:59,350 They could fly through Chicago or they could fly through Denver 155 00:07:59,350 --> 00:08:03,104 or Minneapolis, St. Paul or they could fly direct. 156 00:08:03,104 --> 00:08:06,081 There are many more good options of flying 157 00:08:06,081 --> 00:08:09,330 from Washington to San Francisco, since San Francisco 158 00:08:09,330 --> 00:08:11,572 isn't a hub city. 159 00:08:12,207 --> 00:08:13,486 So what do we see? 160 00:08:13,486 --> 00:08:16,419 Well, we see that the demand for the Washington 161 00:08:16,419 --> 00:08:20,108 to San Francisco flight is going to be relatively elastic 162 00:08:20,108 --> 00:08:22,632 and the demand for the Washington to Dallas flight 163 00:08:22,632 --> 00:08:25,016 is relatively inelastic. 164 00:08:25,016 --> 00:08:29,378 And what our theory tells us is that with the elastic demand, 165 00:08:29,378 --> 00:08:31,569 we get a low markup. 166 00:08:31,569 --> 00:08:35,513 With the inelastic demand, we get a high markup. 167 00:08:35,513 --> 00:08:37,775 So the theory is completely consistent 168 00:08:37,775 --> 00:08:40,896 with this pricing puzzle and it explains the puzzle. 169 00:08:42,028 --> 00:08:43,660 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 170 00:08:43,660 --> 00:08:45,781 click "Practice Questions." 171 00:08:45,781 --> 00:08:49,592 Or if you're ready to move on, just click "Next Video." 172 00:08:49,592 --> 00:08:53,802 ♪ [music] ♪