1 00:00:00,000 --> 00:00:05,178 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:09,214 --> 00:00:11,193 - [Alex] In our final talk in monopoly, 3 00:00:11,193 --> 00:00:13,509 we're going to discuss the costs of monopoly, 4 00:00:13,509 --> 00:00:16,458 but also the potential benefits. 5 00:00:21,201 --> 00:00:24,633 The major costs of monopoly is that compared to competition, 6 00:00:24,633 --> 00:00:26,494 monopoly is inefficient. 7 00:00:26,494 --> 00:00:30,367 It leads to a loss in the gains from trade or a deadweight loss. 8 00:00:30,367 --> 00:00:32,762 Let's remind ourselves about the gains from trade 9 00:00:32,762 --> 00:00:35,352 under competition and then we can compare 10 00:00:35,352 --> 00:00:36,765 with monopoly. 11 00:00:36,765 --> 00:00:39,232 Here we'll simplify with a flat supply curve, 12 00:00:39,232 --> 00:00:41,409 a constant cost industry. 13 00:00:41,409 --> 00:00:44,684 In this case the total gains from trade go to consumers 14 00:00:44,684 --> 00:00:46,923 in this blue area right here. 15 00:00:46,923 --> 00:00:49,873 Now let's see what the total gains from trade or total welfare 16 00:00:49,873 --> 00:00:51,476 is under monopoly. 17 00:00:51,476 --> 00:00:54,006 We choose exactly the same demand curve 18 00:00:54,006 --> 00:00:56,691 and the same constant cost curve. 19 00:00:56,691 --> 00:01:00,891 We find the profit maximizing price and quantity in the usual way. 20 00:01:01,674 --> 00:01:05,669 Consumers, not surprisingly, get less under monopoly 21 00:01:05,669 --> 00:01:07,677 since the price is higher. 22 00:01:08,004 --> 00:01:13,276 Now some of what the consumers lose is transferred to the monopolist 23 00:01:13,276 --> 00:01:16,917 in terms of profit, and as far as an economist is concerned, 24 00:01:16,917 --> 00:01:19,738 at least someone is getting these gains from trade. 25 00:01:19,754 --> 00:01:21,848 So the transfer is neutral. 26 00:01:22,780 --> 00:01:26,581 What's bad however, is that total welfare falls 27 00:01:26,581 --> 00:01:30,362 under monopoly because no one gets this area, 28 00:01:30,362 --> 00:01:32,303 the deadweight loss. 29 00:01:32,303 --> 00:01:36,562 These are trades that from a social point of view are beneficial. 30 00:01:36,562 --> 00:01:41,562 The demanders are willing to pay more than what would be the cost 31 00:01:41,562 --> 00:01:43,503 of producing these goods. 32 00:01:44,291 --> 00:01:47,227 These trades, however, don't happen. 33 00:01:47,970 --> 00:01:50,892 Even though they're socially beneficial they don't happen 34 00:01:50,892 --> 00:01:55,193 because they aren't profitable, they aren't privately beneficial. 35 00:01:55,570 --> 00:01:57,718 Think of a movie theater that is half empty. 36 00:01:58,107 --> 00:02:00,577 Surely there are some people out there who would value 37 00:02:00,577 --> 00:02:04,816 watching the movie at more than its marginal cost, about zero. 38 00:02:05,244 --> 00:02:08,411 So why doesn't the movie theater lower the price to these people? 39 00:02:09,091 --> 00:02:13,446 Because to do so it would have to lower the price to everyone 40 00:02:13,446 --> 00:02:15,964 and that would reduce total profits. 41 00:02:16,815 --> 00:02:18,841 So the basic lesson is this. 42 00:02:20,437 --> 00:02:23,440 Consumers buy a good so long as the value to them 43 00:02:23,440 --> 00:02:25,168 exceeds the price. 44 00:02:25,422 --> 00:02:28,542 Under competition, price is equal to marginal cost, 45 00:02:28,975 --> 00:02:33,006 so consumers will buy every unit such that the value to them 46 00:02:33,006 --> 00:02:35,741 is a greater than the marginal cost. 47 00:02:36,198 --> 00:02:37,894 That's efficient. 48 00:02:37,894 --> 00:02:41,423 Under monopoly, consumers also buy so long as the value 49 00:02:41,423 --> 00:02:45,478 to them is greater than the price, but since price is greater 50 00:02:45,478 --> 00:02:49,964 than marginal cost, we get too few units produced. 51 00:02:50,379 --> 00:02:52,742 We get a loss in the gains from trade. 52 00:02:53,757 --> 00:02:55,658 Let's remind ourselves what deadweight loss 53 00:02:55,658 --> 00:02:57,406 looks like in practice. 54 00:02:57,406 --> 00:03:00,828 GSK prices Combivir at $12.50 per pill. 55 00:03:01,150 --> 00:03:03,764 The marginal cost is 50 cents. 56 00:03:03,764 --> 00:03:08,312 The deadweight loss is the value of the trades that do not occur 57 00:03:08,312 --> 00:03:11,226 because price is greater than marginal cost. 58 00:03:11,226 --> 00:03:14,770 Some people would be willing and able to pay $10 per pill 59 00:03:14,770 --> 00:03:19,086 or $4, or even $1 per pill and those prices 60 00:03:19,086 --> 00:03:23,104 would more than cover the cost of producing those pills. 61 00:03:23,799 --> 00:03:25,902 But those trades don't occur 62 00:03:25,902 --> 00:03:29,108 because they aren't profitable to GSK. 63 00:03:29,479 --> 00:03:33,648 Many monopolies around the world are born of government corruption. 64 00:03:33,648 --> 00:03:37,034 In Indonesia, Tommy Suharto, the president's son, 65 00:03:37,034 --> 00:03:40,643 was given the highly profitable clove monopoly. 66 00:03:40,643 --> 00:03:42,263 He used the profits from that monopoly 67 00:03:42,263 --> 00:03:43,852 to buy Lamborghini. 68 00:03:43,852 --> 00:03:47,460 Not a Lamborghini -- he bought the entire company. 69 00:03:47,951 --> 00:03:50,805 These kinds of monopolies are unredeemed. 70 00:03:50,805 --> 00:03:53,674 They have costs and no social benefits at all. 71 00:03:54,722 --> 00:03:58,557 Some monopolies however, do have countervailing benefits. 72 00:03:59,025 --> 00:04:01,881 Consider what would happen if the U.S. eliminated patents 73 00:04:01,881 --> 00:04:03,628 for pharmaceuticals. 74 00:04:03,628 --> 00:04:06,349 Competition, it's true, would drive down the price 75 00:04:06,349 --> 00:04:10,932 of existing drugs to marginal cost, as happens today 76 00:04:10,932 --> 00:04:14,691 as soon as patents expire, usually within 10 to 15 years 77 00:04:14,691 --> 00:04:17,142 after the drug first enters the market. 78 00:04:17,699 --> 00:04:20,841 But it costs about a billion dollars 79 00:04:20,841 --> 00:04:24,822 to bring the average new drug to market in the United States, 80 00:04:24,822 --> 00:04:29,269 and R&D costs are not included in marginal cost. 81 00:04:29,902 --> 00:04:33,477 As the saying goes, it costs about a billion dollars 82 00:04:33,477 --> 00:04:38,331 to create the first pill, 50 cents to create the second pill. 83 00:04:39,066 --> 00:04:42,813 50 cents is the marginal cost, the cost of an additional pill, 84 00:04:42,813 --> 00:04:45,121 but to bring that first pill to market costs 85 00:04:45,121 --> 00:04:47,355 about a billion dollars. 86 00:04:47,741 --> 00:04:52,096 If price were quickly pushed down to marginal cost, 87 00:04:52,096 --> 00:04:56,062 firms would not be able to recover their R&D costs, 88 00:04:56,397 --> 00:04:59,278 and the result would be fewer new drugs. 89 00:05:00,469 --> 00:05:03,611 Once the drug is created, the patent, the monopoly, 90 00:05:03,611 --> 00:05:06,896 creates inefficiency, we get too few units produced. 91 00:05:07,353 --> 00:05:10,816 But the patent increases the incentive to produce 92 00:05:10,816 --> 00:05:12,988 the new drugs in the first place. 93 00:05:13,474 --> 00:05:14,937 So there's a trade-off. 94 00:05:15,163 --> 00:05:17,876 More monopoly reduces static efficiency, 95 00:05:17,876 --> 00:05:20,415 the quantity produced, but can increase 96 00:05:20,415 --> 00:05:25,057 dynamic efficiency, the incentive to do research and development. 97 00:05:26,908 --> 00:05:29,327 This trade-off applies to other goods 98 00:05:29,327 --> 00:05:32,087 with high development cost, not just pharmaceuticals. 99 00:05:32,464 --> 00:05:35,385 Information goods, goods like music, movies, 100 00:05:35,385 --> 00:05:37,953 computer programs, new chemicals, new materials, 101 00:05:37,953 --> 00:05:39,450 new technologies. 102 00:05:39,450 --> 00:05:42,254 These typically have high development costs 103 00:05:42,254 --> 00:05:44,852 and low marginal cost of production. 104 00:05:44,852 --> 00:05:48,179 And that suggests there may be possible benefits to patent 105 00:05:48,179 --> 00:05:50,260 or copyright protection. 106 00:05:50,666 --> 00:05:54,353 More generally for these types of goods there's a policy trade-off 107 00:05:54,353 --> 00:05:56,797 which we always want to keep in mind. 108 00:05:56,797 --> 00:06:01,657 That is lower prices today may generate fewer new ideas 109 00:06:01,657 --> 00:06:03,390 in the future. 110 00:06:05,166 --> 00:06:08,301 Nobel prize winning economic historian, Douglas North, 111 00:06:08,301 --> 00:06:11,916 for example, has argued, "The failure to develop 112 00:06:11,916 --> 00:06:14,407 systematic property rights in innovation 113 00:06:14,407 --> 00:06:17,654 up until fairly modern times was a major source 114 00:06:17,654 --> 00:06:20,726 of the slow pace of technological change." 115 00:06:21,726 --> 00:06:24,889 Is there a better way of navigating this trade-off? 116 00:06:24,965 --> 00:06:26,462 Perhaps. 117 00:06:26,462 --> 00:06:29,877 Suppose that the government bought up a pharmaceutical patent 118 00:06:29,877 --> 00:06:34,423 for its total monopoly profits and then they ripped the patent up. 119 00:06:34,985 --> 00:06:38,568 Competitors would enter and drive the price of the drug 120 00:06:38,568 --> 00:06:40,951 down to marginal cost, thus we would have 121 00:06:40,951 --> 00:06:42,676 static efficiency. 122 00:06:42,676 --> 00:06:44,625 At the same time, since the government 123 00:06:44,625 --> 00:06:47,841 was paying firms their monopoly profits, 124 00:06:47,841 --> 00:06:50,658 we would still have lots of incentive to do research 125 00:06:50,658 --> 00:06:53,425 and development -- dynamic efficiency. 126 00:06:53,425 --> 00:06:55,887 Thus we could have the best of all worlds. 127 00:06:55,887 --> 00:06:58,923 Of course, there may be some downsides as well. 128 00:06:58,923 --> 00:07:01,441 Higher taxes to pay for the patent also have 129 00:07:01,441 --> 00:07:03,890 their own deadweight loss, and it might be difficult 130 00:07:03,890 --> 00:07:06,840 to say exactly how much a patent is worth. 131 00:07:07,113 --> 00:07:09,346 And there could be possible corruption. 132 00:07:09,346 --> 00:07:11,964 Nevertheless, this is an idea we're thinking about, 133 00:07:11,964 --> 00:07:14,240 and perhaps worth experimenting with. 134 00:07:15,277 --> 00:07:18,172 Prizes are another way of navigating the trade-off. 135 00:07:18,500 --> 00:07:21,086 As with patent buyouts, the idea is that a firm 136 00:07:21,086 --> 00:07:24,227 is offered up front its R&D costs. 137 00:07:24,330 --> 00:07:27,129 But the government only pays the firm 138 00:07:27,129 --> 00:07:29,270 if it achieves a certain goal. 139 00:07:29,270 --> 00:07:31,894 And if that goal is achieved, the technology goes 140 00:07:31,894 --> 00:07:35,017 into the public domain and could be used by anyone. 141 00:07:35,512 --> 00:07:38,055 SpaceShipOne, for example, won $10 million 142 00:07:38,055 --> 00:07:41,741 for being the first privately developed manned rocket 143 00:07:41,741 --> 00:07:43,660 capable of reaching space and returning 144 00:07:43,660 --> 00:07:45,573 in a short period of time. 145 00:07:45,573 --> 00:07:47,908 And prizes are being used more often. 146 00:07:47,908 --> 00:07:50,187 The government set up a prize for better light bulbs, 147 00:07:50,187 --> 00:07:53,014 for example, and that worked quite well. 148 00:07:53,680 --> 00:07:56,556 There's also a third way of navigating the trade-off. 149 00:07:57,103 --> 00:08:01,036 You may have noticed, for example, that so far we've assumed 150 00:08:01,036 --> 00:08:03,553 that the monopolist must charge the same price 151 00:08:03,553 --> 00:08:05,016 to everyone. 152 00:08:05,016 --> 00:08:07,207 Is this necessarily true? 153 00:08:07,207 --> 00:08:09,151 In some cases, the monopolist can charge 154 00:08:09,151 --> 00:08:11,321 different prices to different people -- 155 00:08:11,321 --> 00:08:13,378 price discrimination. 156 00:08:13,378 --> 00:08:16,406 As we'll see in the next chapter and set of lectures, 157 00:08:16,406 --> 00:08:20,138 price discrimination explains a lot about how products are priced 158 00:08:20,138 --> 00:08:22,884 and it also has some costs and some benefits 159 00:08:22,884 --> 00:08:24,842 which we'll be discussing. 160 00:08:24,842 --> 00:08:26,455 See you then, thanks. 161 00:08:27,587 --> 00:08:29,252 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 162 00:08:29,252 --> 00:08:31,389 click "Practice Questions." 163 00:08:31,389 --> 00:08:34,794 Or if you're ready to move on, just click "Next Video." 164 00:08:34,794 --> 00:08:38,733 ♪ [music] ♪